Urbanization and Growth
By Michael Spence (Editor), Patricia Clarke Annez (Editor) and Robert M. Buckley (Editor)
()
About this ebook
Related to Urbanization and Growth
Public Policy For You
American Government 101: From the Continental Congress to the Iowa Caucus, Everything You Need to Know About US Politics Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Poverty, by America Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Project 2025: Exposing the Radical Agenda -The Hidden Dangers of Project 2025 for Everyday Americans Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Project 2025: Blueprint for America's Future Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5The Price We Pay: What Broke American Health Care--and How to Fix It Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5"Trickle Down Theory" and "Tax Cuts for the Rich" Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Art of War Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Evicted: Poverty and Profit in the American City Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Dumbing Us Down - 25th Anniversary Edition: The Hidden Curriculum of Compulsory Schooling Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Bowling Alone: Revised and Updated: The Collapse and Revival of American Community Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Dreamland: The True Tale of America's Opiate Epidemic Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Everyone Who Is Gone Is Here: The United States, Central America, and the Making of a Crisis Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Madness of Crowds: Gender, Race and Identity Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Chasing the Scream: The Inspiration for the Feature Film "The United States vs. Billie Holiday" Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5No Visible Bruises: What We Don’t Know About Domestic Violence Can Kill Us Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Power Broker: Robert Moses and the Fall of New York Rating: 1 out of 5 stars1/5Who Is Government?: The Untold Story of Public Service Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Social Security 101: From Medicare to Spousal Benefits, an Essential Primer on Government Retirement Aid Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Affluent Society Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Capital in the Twenty-First Century Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Upswing: How America Came Together a Century Ago and How We Can Do It Again Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5A City on Mars: Can we settle space, should we settle space, and have we really thought this through? Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5On War: With linked Table of Contents Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Light of the Mind, Light of the World: Illuminating Science Through Faith Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsLove Your Enemies: How Decent People Can Save America from the Culture of Contempt Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Battle for the American Mind: Uprooting a Century of Miseducation Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Sum of Us: What Racism Costs Everyone and How We Can Prosper Together Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Echo Machine: How Right-Wing Extremism Created a Post-Truth America Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratings
Reviews for Urbanization and Growth
0 ratings0 reviews
Book preview
Urbanization and Growth - Michael Spence
Title
Urbanization and Growth
Commission on Growth and Development
Title
Urbanization and Growth
Edited by Michael Spence, Patricia Clarke Annez,
and Robert M. Buckley
Contributions by
Michael Spence
Patricia Clarke Annez and Robert M. Buckley
Richard Arnott
Gilles Duranton
Dwight M. Jaffee
Sukkoo Kim
John M. Quigley
Anthony J. Venables
COMMISSION ON GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT
Copyright
© 2009 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development /
The World Bank
On behalf of the Commission on Growth and Development
1818 H Street NW
Washington, DC 20433
Telephone: 202-473-1000
All rights reserved
1 2 3 4 12 11 10 09
This volume is a product of the Commission on Growth and Development, which is sponsored by the following organizations:
Australian Agency for International Development (AusAID)
Dutch Ministry of Foreign Affairs
Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency (SIDA)
U.K. Department of International Development (DFID)
The William and Flora Hewlett Foundation
The World Bank Group
The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed herein do not necessarily reflect the views of the sponsoring organizations or the governments they represent.
The sponsoring organizations do not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of the sponsoring organizations concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.
All queries on rights and licenses, including subsidiary rights, should be addressed to the Office of the Publisher, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2422; e-mail: [email protected].
ISBN: 978-0-8213-7573-0
eISBN: 978-0-8213-7574-7
DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-7573-0
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Urbanization and growth / edited by Michael Spence, Patricia Clarke Annez, and Robert M. Buckley.
p. cm.
Includes bibliographical references and index.
ISBN 978-0-8213-7573-0 — ISBN 978-0-8213-7574-7 (electronic)
1. Urban economics. 2. Urbanization—Economic aspects. 3. Cities and towns—Growth. I. Spence, Michael. II. Annez, Patricia Clarke. III.
Buckley, Robert M.
HT321.U338 2008
330.9173'2—dc22
2008044060
Cover design: Naylor Design
Contents
Contents
Preface
Preface
The Commission on Growth and Development was established in April 2006 as a response to two insights: we do not talk about growth enough, and when we do, we speak with too much confidence. Too often, people overlook economic growth when thinking about how to tackle the world's most pressing problems, such as poverty, illiteracy, income inequality, unemployment, and pollution. At the same time, our understanding of economic growth is less definitive than commonly thought—even though advice is often given to developing countries with great confidence. Consequently, the Commission's mandate is to take stock of the state of theoretical and empirical knowledge on economic growth with a view to drawing implications for policy for the current and next generation of policy makers.
To help assess the state of knowledge, the Commission invited leading academics and policy makers from around the world to a series of 12 workshops, held in 2007 and 2008 in Washington, D.C., New York, and New Haven, and commissioned a series of thematic papers. These papers reviewed areas such as monetary and fiscal policy, climate change, inequality, growth, and urbanization—the subject of this volume. In addition, 25 case studies were commissioned to explore the dynamics of growth in specific countries. Each presentation benefited from comments by members of the Commission and other workshop participants from the worlds of policy, theory, and practice.
The workshops turned out to be intense and lively affairs, lasting up to three days. It became clear that experts do not always agree, even on issues that are central to growth. The Commission had no wish to disguise or gloss over these uncertainties and differences. It did not want to present a false confidence in its conclusions, beyond that justified by the evidence. Researchers do not always know the correct model
that would explain the world they observe; and even if they know the factors that matter, they cannot always measure them convincingly.
While researchers will continue to improve our knowledge of the world, policy makers cannot wait for scholars to satisfy all of their doubts or resolve their differences. Decisions must be made with only partial knowledge of the world. One consequence is that most policy decisions, however well-informed, take on the character of experiments, which yield useful information about the way the world works, even if they do not always turn out the way policy makers hoped. It is as well to recognize this fact, if only so that policy makers can be quick to spot failures and learn from mistakes.
The workshops on cities and housing were held in March and May 2007. We were immensely fortunate to benefit from the wisdom and insights of outstanding researchers and experienced practitioners. We are grateful to all of the participants, who are listed below. The remainder of this preface is not an exhaustive summary of the workshops or the chapters in this volume. It instead replays some highlights of the discussion and presents some of the ideas that shaped the conclusions of the Commission's final report, The Growth Report: Strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive Development.
Productivity and Cities
Structural change is a key driver of rapid growth: countries diversify into new industries, firms learn new things, people move to new locations. Anything that slows this structural change is also likely to slow growth. Because urbanization is one of the most important enabling parallel processes in rapid growth, making it work well is critical.
Deciding whether urbanization causes growth or growth causes urbanization is very difficult, and largely beside the point. We know of no countries that either achieved high incomes or rapid growth without substantial urbanization, often quite rapid. There is a robust relationship between urbanization and per capita income: nearly all countries become at least 50 percent urbanized before reaching middle-income status, and all high-income countries are 70–80 percent urbanized. In all known cases of high and sustained growth, urban manufacturing and services led the process, while increases in agricultural productivity freed up the labor force that moved to the cities and manned the factories. In the high-growth cases that we examined in the Growth Commission, the average productivity of a worker in manufacturing or services is on the order of three to five times that of a worker in traditional sectors, and sometimes much more.
Urbanization deserves attention not to the detriment of improving agricultural productivity and rural livelihoods, but as a complement to such measures. Improving agricultural incomes is very important for reducing poverty among the large numbers of people living in the rural areas of poor countries today. Still, no amount of growth in the rural sector is going to match the productivity increase that is caused by people moving across that boundary into high-productivity employment.
Urbanization's contribution to growth comes from two sources: the difference between rural and urban productivity levels and more rapid productivity change in cities. In the early decades of development, when the majority of the population is still rural, the jump from rural to urban employment makes a big contribution to growth. As cities grow larger, the second effect—faster gains in urban productivity—begins to dominate, as it operates on a larger base.
For these reasons, making urbanization work well is something that countries that want to grow quickly must learn to do. There are two important parts of making it work. The first challenge is to foster the growth of high-productivity activities that benefit from agglomeration and scale economies in developing country cities. The second involves managing the likely side effects of the economic success of cities—congestion, regional inequality, and high prices of land and housing. Meeting this second challenge is essential for mitigating the divisive impacts of successful economic growth and spreading the benefits of higher economic productivity widely.
Why is productivity higher in cities? Why, in other words, is proximity a source of efficiency? The cost of transport is one obvious reason why economic activity might cluster around a harbor or crossroads. Infrastructure and other public services are also cheaper to provide to densely packed populations. City dwellers may also benefit from knowledge spillovers: some theories predict that the aggregate gains from schooling are greater than the (sum of the) returns to individuals, implying that people learn a lot from each other without paying for it.
In addition to understanding what happens within cities, it is important to grasp what unfolds between them, and between cities and the rural hinterland. Urbanization can pose challenges that extend far beyond a mayor's jurisdiction. The migration from the countryside to the cities may, for example, be uncomfortably quick for people already living in cities, who face sharper competition for common, limited resources. Accommodating these pressures requires investments in infrastructure, often in public goods, which, in turn, tests government's capacity to mobilize new public resources and to shift the balance of spending towards cities. The economic success of cities may result in glaring income gaps between them and the rural hinterland, while making a new economic elite more visible to low-income groups flocking to urban areas. The agglomeration economies that make cities productive usually involve externalities or spillovers. Newcomers to cities impose costs that others must bear, and create benefits that others may capture. These externalities create a bias for an established city that makes it hard for secondary cities to grow, even if it would be more efficient to do so. Such growing pains
may be part and parcel of the modernization process. But to sustain rapid growth, policy makers need to contain the social and political tensions they create.
Primacy
—the dominance of one city over all others—is one example. In developing countries, one city (such as Dhaka, Jakarta, Bangkok, or São Paulo) often outstrips the others. Governments often feel obliged to even things out. Should they do so? On the one hand, robust empirical evidence shows that productivity increases with the size of cities. On the other, some empirical evidence suggests that excessive primacy
may reduce overall growth. Precisely how it does so is not clear, however. Nor is it clear that governments can or should act on this result. This issue sparked considerable discussion in the workshops and remains unsettled among scholars. It may, in any case, be easier to cope with the congestion (and other costs) of large cities than to divert the geography of growth away from one city and toward its rivals. Ideally, we would know much more about when cities become too large to accommodate further growth and how to counteract excessive city size effectively.
Financing Urbanization
Economies rarely grow without their cities growing. But urbanization has its dark side.
According to a UN survey, the vast majority of policy makers resist urbanization rather than welcome it. They would prefer to stem the urban tide and see people return to rural areas. This disaffection with urbanization reflects more than just nostalgia for simpler times. Rapid urbanization brings about real social and political headaches, such as overcrowding, concentrated squalor, crime, street violence, and the quick transmission of disease. Urbanization is probably inevitable and ultimately desirable. The question is not how to stop it, but how to reap its benefits without paying too high a cost.
Infrastructure and public services are part of the answer, and possibly the whole answer. According to some estimates, $40 trillion of infrastructure spending is required to meet the needs of cities in developing countries. Where is that money going to come from? Devising means of financing such vast expenditures is probably the biggest challenge for urbanization policy in developing countries.
The economic benefits of cities are often reflected in property prices. It should therefore be possible for the government to capture a share of these benefits by taxing land or property. It could then spend the proceeds on the infrastructure required to offset some of the costs of cities, such as congestion. Economists find the idea appealing. But local government officials think property taxes are a big headache in practice, and they have not proven to be a rich source of investment finance.
Property taxes are cumbersome, costly to administer, and highly unpopular everywhere. In developing countries, the challenges multiply. The administrative and political demands of property taxes are particularly illsuited to local governments still building their technical capacity and credibility with the public. In many developing countries, the property market is underdeveloped and overregulated. Large tracts of land languish in public hands. Private transactions are underreported because they are heavily taxed. Rents may be controlled, depressing the value of the real estate. In the absence of reliable market prices, officials must arrive at their own estimation of property values, a job that demands some skill and leaves ample discretion. This discretion in turn opens the door to corruption. Besides, it takes time to raise a significant sum from property and land taxes. In countries with a history of exploitative landlords, heavy property taxes will be strongly resisted. Many properties in rapidly growing cities are informal and unserviced, leaving them out of the tax net. Lastly, property taxes are typically designed to generate a steady stream of income reflecting the flow of benefits to property owners. Financing lumpy
infrastructure investments with a property tax thus requires the additional hurdle of tapping financial markets, which are usually in an embryonic state when rapid urbanization takes hold. Over the long run, property taxes will likely become a mainstay of local taxation in developing countries as they are in the developed world. But in a transitional phase, these taxes must be supplemented by creative and perhaps unorthodox approaches to urban finance, including some methods used historically in developed countries.
Some countries have raised money by capturing land asset values in transactions with the private sector, be they leases, sales, developer's exactions, or betterment levies. In a fast-growing economy, these transactions can be lucrative, raising large multiples of the sums available from other budgetary sources. In places like Hong Kong, China, the terms of a lease have been tweaked and adjusted to help shape a city, without the heavy-handedness of zoning. Economies and regions around the world—ranging from China; Hong Kong, China; and Singapore to Egypt; South Africa; India; Chile; and the rapidly growing jurisdictions in the western United States—have raised substantial sums to finance infrastructure using these techniques.
There are disadvantages. Asset transactions are inherently limited and should be used for investments rather than recurring costs. Leasing transactions may help shape the city, but long-term leases may also make it difficult to change land-use patterns. There is the potential for abuse and corruption in large one-time transactions involving valuable tracts of urban land. But whatever the relative merits of selling land, leasing it, or taxing property, the alternatives may be worse. In many developing country cities, for example, governments administer large tracts of underused land. This acreage is not put to the best use the market can find for it. Nor does it typically yield the government much revenue. It is a good way to squander a precious asset.
Capturing land asset values is lucrative and fraught with risks. It can reduce the need for central budgetary support that has usually been required for financing major urban infrastructure improvements. But land asset–based finance also needs a supporting framework and supervision from higher levels of government. Whatever specific techniques are deployed, it is unrealistic to expect cities to go it alone
for financing the infrastructure transformation that is needed to make urbanization work.
Urbanization and Regional Inequalities
The economist Simon Kuznets hypothesized that as countries grow richer, inequality would first rise, then fall, tracing out the so-called Kuznets curve.
The curve has a spatial equivalent: the income gap between urban and rural areas first widens, then narrows. In the United States, for example, regional inequality rose from 1820 to 1940, but declined thereafter. Whether developing economies will repeat this pattern remains to be seen. China took a conscious decision to tolerate inequality in its quest for growth. We will let some regions and some people get rich first,
Deng Xiaoping famously said.
Some urban labor markets cope better than others with the influx of new labor. In the United States, mass immigration was accompanied by rising real wages from 1820. Immigrants from Europe and elsewhere found work in an expanding manufacturing sector that offered plentiful unskilled jobs. With the advent of mechanization in the 1920s, the demand for skills rose. But by that time, American high schools were turning out educated workers and policy makers had partially closed the door to immigration. The important conclusion is that if labor-intensive manufacturing is growing, economies can absorb migrants from the fields or foreign countries relatively easily.
In many developing country cities, most jobs, including those for new migrants, are in the informal sector of the economy. Although informal employment is on the rise in many countries, rich and poor, we know relatively little about the productivity of this sector or the mobility of workers from informal employment to formal jobs. However, research in Africa indicates that informal work in the cities is more productive than agricultural labor, even if it is considerably less productive than formal employment. In Ghana, for example, the differential between informal work in the cities and agricultural work was estimated at 2:1. Few of the workers in the informal sector seemed to escape into formal jobs. But perhaps their children will make the leap. We need further research to find out.
Urbanization also has implications for the position of women. In the United States, it was mostly men who migrated in waves to factory jobs in the cities. But this pattern is not universal. In China, for example, early migrants to the cities were often women. This remains true today in those industries that require refined motor skills. In the long run, cities promote growth, and growth enfranchises women. As incomes rise and female education improves, women have fewer children and enjoy higher rates of employment.
There was considerable discussion of whether government intervention could reduce spatial inequalities, and which policies actually succeed. Policy makers often feel obliged to reduce spatial disparities. But many of these efforts to promote some regions over others did not achieve much. Heavy investments in U.S. highways and targeted regional interventions in the EU may have facilitated convergence. But poorer countries face tighter budget constraints and fewer options. Central governments should probably devote their efforts to helping people move from lagging areas to prospering ones, rather than spending large sums on remote infrastructure that may be underused. Yet very difficult choices arise when regional income inequalities coincide with other social divisions such as ethnicity or religion. In such circumstances, fostering a sense of regional balance may become critical to national cohesion, and policy research thus far offers little firm guidance on how to do this.
Housing and Land Markets
As people move to cities in large numbers, the demand for housing and serviced land in urban areas expands rapidly. Unfortunately, the market rarely meets this demand affordably. Ill-conceived planning laws and building standards coupled with insufficient public finance for infrastructure mean that supply responds sluggishly. As a result, the price of land and housing rises beyond the reach of poor people. Even in desperately poor countries such as Bangladesh, big-city land prices can be comparable to prices in industrialized nations.
The Republic of Korea provides one example of a dramatic effort to raise supply. By the late 1980s, the cost of housing had far outpaced GDP. The ratio of house prices to income reached 13:1, as compared with 3:1 in the United States. The government stepped in. Overnight, 25 percent of the country's land was declared urban,
clearing the way for real estate development, compared with 5 percent before. In addition, 2 million homes were added to the housing stock over seven to eight years. Today, Korea's house-price-to-income ratio is about 3.5:1.
The case of Singapore is also revealing. Singapore's government controlled the land and maintained a near monopoly over house-building. Quite exceptionally, the government could also control migration since the borders of the city and the nation coincided. In contrast to Eastern Europe, where unresponsive state monopolies produced low-quality, high-cost housing, Singapore's public housing was standardized and cheap. Its heavy housing subsidies served both social and economic ends. They brought an end to squalid slums and defused ethnic strife. They also ensured the wage competitiveness of workers in Singapore's small, open economy, which had pinned its hopes on foreign investment and exporting success.
The success of Singapore's housing subsidies is more the exception than the rule, however, and they carried significant risks. Its provident fund, a mandatory saving scheme, was heavily invested in real estate. If Singapore had ever suffered a housing downturn, the consequences might have been disastrous. Fortunately, the economy thrived and home prices did not tumble. Subsidies for housing can become a political necessity, but they are also costly and hard to confine to the poor. Certainly, they should not be seen as a substitute for serious efforts to expand supply, including the supply of public services that often constrain efficient land use. Only a greater supply of serviced land and housing can lower costs, because it helps to solve the problem at its root as well as contain the fiscal burden of subsidies. In Mexico, for example, an upfront subsidy was combined with efforts to provide better infrastructure and security of tenure, allowing households to make investments in their home on their own.
Mortgages can improve households' ability to buy decent housing. But finance relaxes demand constraints only. Unless it is accompanied by measures to increase supply, better finance may result in overshooting prices. This volatility can jeopardize macroeconomic stability. In a typical pattern, strong income growth leads to a rapid increase in housing demand. An injection of liquidity from some source, often overseas, may help overstimu-late the market, leading to overoptimism and a dangerous concentration of wealth in real estate. This leaves buyers and bankers dangerously exposed when the bubble bursts, as illustrated by Thailand and Hong Kong, China, in 1997, Shanghai in 2003, and recently in the United States. In Sweden, the relaxation of mortgage-lending regulation left banks overexposed to a housing bubble and very vulnerable in the face of an economic contraction.
Concluding Remarks
Rapid and sustained growth entails rapid and sustained urbanization. But, if mishandled, the growth of cities poses problems that can derail growth. Developing countries must accomplish in a few decades what today's industrialized countries achieved over a century or more. Policy makers are, as the Growth Report puts it, navigating uncharted waters with a set of incomplete, sometimes inaccurate, maps.
Their task is made no easier by the data at their disposal. Several speakers at the workshop noted that data on housing and real estate markets in developing countries are woeful, much worse than figures on agriculture, for example. This impedes intelligent consideration of policies. Better data could support stronger research on urban economics, finance, and the real estate market, which has been relatively neglected in developing countries. It is our hope that this volume will help people understand the role of urbanization in growth and tackle the formidable challenges it poses.
Workshop Participants
Workshop Participants
Abdel-Rahman, Hesham, University of New Orleans
Alm, James, Georgia State University
Angel, Solly, New York University
Annez, Patricia Clarke, World Bank
Arnott, Richard, Boston College
Asabere, Paul, Fox School of Business and Management, Temple University
Bertaud, Alain, Independent Consultant
Bosworth, Barry, The Brookings Institution
Brueckner, Jan, University of California at Irvine
Buckley, Robert, Rockefeller Foundation
Chiquier, Loic, World Bank
Cho, Man, The Korea Development Institute (KDI) School
Deichmann, Uwe, World Bank
De Mello, Luiz, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)
Duranton, Gilles, University of Toronto
Durlauf, Steven, University of Wisconsin-Madison
Eldhagen, Erik, Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency (SIDA)
Freire, Maria Emilia, World Bank
Green, Richard, George Washington University
Hannah, Lawrence, World Bank
Hegedüs, József, Metropolitan Research Institute, Budapest, Hungary
Henderson, Vernon, Brown University
Hesse, Heiko, World Bank
Hwang, Min, George Washington University
Jaffee, Dwight M., University of California, Berkeley
Kalarickal, Jerry, World Bank
Kharas, Homi, Wolfensohn Center for Development, The Brookings Institution
Kim, Sukkoo, Washington University in St. Louis
Laszek, Jacek, Central Bank of Poland
Leamer, Edward, University of California-Los Angeles
Leipziger, Danny, Growth Commission Vice Chair, World Bank
Logan, John, Brown University
Malpezzi, Steve, University of Wisconsin-Madison
Mulas, Alberto, Sociedad Hipotecaria Federal (SHF), Mexico City
Nowak, Dorota, World Bank
Olsen, Edgar, University of Virginia
Peterson, George, The Urban Institute
Quigley, John, University of California, Berkeley
Rivlin, Alice M., The Brookings Institution
Singh, Smita, William and Flora Hewlett Foundation
Sheppard, Stephen, Williams College
Spence, Michael, Growth Commission Chair, Stanford University
Sridhar, Shri S., National Housing Bank, Government of India
Stephens, Mark, The University of York, United Kingdom
Thalwitz, Margret, Global Partnership Program, World Bank
Sir Dwight Venner, Commissioner, Governor, Eastern Caribbean Central Bank
Van den Noord, Paul, European Commission
Van Order, Robert, University of Michigan
Villani, Kevin E., San Diego State University
Whitehead, Christine, London School of Economics
Wong, Grace, University of Pennsylvania
Wu, Weiping, Virginia Commonwealth University
Yezer, Anthony, George Washington University
Yusuf, Shahid, World Bank
Zagha, Roberto, World Bank
Chapter Summaries
Chapter Summaries
In Chapter 1, Annez and Buckley set the context for the rest of the book. They discuss the broad macro relationships between growth and urbanization as well as some of the well-documented microeconomic findings that underpin these linkages. Despite the clear link between cities and growth, policy makers and the development community are often ambivalent about urbanization (although attitudes differ considerably by region and country). The chapter concludes that the policy debate needs to change the question. Instead of asking whether to promote urbanization or curtail it, the debate should consider how to support the structural shifts that urbanization makes necessary.
In Chapter 2, Anthony Venables examines globalization through the lens of economic geography. The chapter argues that cumulative causation processes are fundamental to understanding growth and development. Such processes derive from spatially concentrated increasing returns to scale, including thick-market effects, knowledge spillovers, sectoral and urban clustering, and self-reinforcing improvements in physical and social infrastructure. These sources of agglomeration have been extensively analyzed in the economic geography literature. They imply that spatial unevenness in economic activity and incomes is an equilibrium outcome. Growth tends to be lumpy,
with some sectors in some countries growing fast while other countries lag. The policy challenge is to lift potential new centers of economic activity to the point where they can reap the advantages of increasing returns and cumulative causation.
Chapter 3, authored by Gilles Duranton, develops a consistent framework for considering the effects of urbanization and cities on productivity and economic growth in developing countries. There is strong evidence that cities bolster productive efficiency in developing countries, just as they do in developed economies. Regarding whether cities promote self-sustained growth, the evidence is suggestive but ultimately inconclusive. These findings imply that the traditional agenda of aiming to raise within-city efficiency should be continued. Furthermore, reducing the obstacles to the reallocation of factors across cities is also desirable.
In Chapter 4, John Quigley discusses the insights from the burgeoning theoretical and empirical literature on urban agglomeration. He reviews the linkages between urbanization and economic development and articulates the relationship between urban density and potential increases in productivity—through specialization, complementarities in production, through the diffusion of knowledge and mimicry, and simply through size and scale. The factors limiting the efficient sizes of cities are analyzed. The chapter reviews empirical knowledge—from underdeveloped countries as well as high-income industrial societies—about the importance and magnitudes of these productivity gains. The analysis documents the close link between gains in economic efficiency and the urbanization of populations in most parts of the world.
Chapter 5, by Sukkoo Kim, examines the question of spatial inequality in the growth process. Spatial inequality is an important feature of many developing countries that seems to increase with economic growth and development. At the same time, there seems to be little consensus on the causes of spatial inequality or on a list of effective policy instruments that may foster or reduce spatial inequality. This chapter examines the theoretical and empirical literature on spatial inequality to learn what we know and do not know about the causes of spatial inequality, to investigate what policies may or may not ameliorate spatial inequality, and to determine whether policy makers can identify and implement policies that promote or reduce spatial inequality.
The next two chapters turn to housing issues. Urbanization and growth bring a new set of forces into play in real estate markets. Oftentimes the result is rapid increases in housing costs, which have both social and political implications. The economic case for intervention in housing markets may be weak, but most governments face considerable pressure to do something about housing to make it more affordable for the middle class and to rid cities of unsightly and unhealthy slums. Choosing the policy response wisely is an important element