Unit 9 Theory of Monopoly: Structure
Unit 9 Theory of Monopoly: Structure
Structure
9.0 Objectives
9.1 Introduction
9.2 Causes of Monopoly
9.3 Denla~ldand Marginal Revenue Curve under Monopoly
9.4 Pricing and Output Decisions under Monopoly
9.5 Long Run Equilibrium of a Monopoly Firm
9.6 Some Questions Regarding the Behaviour of a Monopolist
9.6.1 Does a Monopolist Always Make Profits?
9.6.2 Does a Monopolist Always Benefit from a Price Rise?
9.6.3 Does a Monopolist have a Unique Supply Curve?
9.6.4 Does a Monopolist Produce With Optimum Scale of Plant?
9.6.5 1s Monopoly Compatible With Falling or Constant Marginal Cost'?
9.6.6 Is Monopoly an Inefficient 'Type of Market Structure?
9.7 Price Discri~ninationunder Monopoly
9.7.1 Degree of Price Discrimination
9.7.2 Conditions for Price Discrimination
9.7.3 Equilibrium under Price Discrimination
9.8 Equilibrium Price and Output ofa Public Monopoly
9.8. I Marginal-cost Pricing
9.8.2 Average-cost Pricing
9.8.3 A Note on Mark-up Pricing
9.9 Let Us Sum Up
9.10 Key Words
9.1 1 Some llsefi~lBooks
9.12 Hints and Answers to Check Your Progress Exercises
9.0 OBJECTIVES
An earlier unit (Unit 8) has already covered pricing and output decisions in one
extreme foun of market, that is, perfect competition. In this unit. s s t ~ ~ of
d ysuch
decisions is taken up in another extreme form ofmarket, that is, in monopoly. where
there is only a single seller.
Allelegoing through the unit, you should be able to:
define monopoly:
describe the causes why ~llonopoliesemerge;
discuss the demand and the cost conditions, and the pricing and o~tputdecisions
under monopoly;
explain the short-run and the long-nln equilibrium of a monopoly tirm:
'l'hcury of Monopoly
I
describe various features and pricing techniques of apublic monopoly.
9.1 JNTRODUCTION
In general, monopoly is said to exist if there is one and only one seller Qroducer)
of aproduct for which there is no close substitutes; this single seller is unaffected
by the prices and outputs of other products sold in the economy. The stress in
this definition is on absence of close substitutes. To understand this remember
that one can often find substitutes, for goods and services. For example, if one
i wants to travel by train. Indian Railway is the only option available. In that sense,
I Indian Railways is a monopoly concern. However, there are other modes of
transport, such as roadways and airlines to travel from one place to another.
t
Substitutes to Indian Railways are available but close substitutesare lacking. Thus.
Indian Railways meet our definition of monopoly. The followingconditions prevail
in monopoly market:
a) There is only one seller (i.e., producer) in the market but there are large number
of buyers.
b) The product of the seller may be homogeneous, or, there may be differentiated
products but without close substitutes. When close substitutes are not
available, it imp1ies that the cross-elasticity of demand between the product
of a i~lonopolistand products of other firms is very low.
c) There is no free entry to the market. Entry may be restricted by the natural
factors such as control of raw materials, by legal and institutional factors such
as patent rights or by technological factors such as the eflicienisy of large scale
production.
If all these conditions are met simultaneously, the market structure is referred to as
monopoly. The monopoly. like the perfect competition, is more or less, an
hypothetical situation because some of the above conditions may not be met in
practice.
- - -- - - - -
Fig. 9.1 shows inverse relationship between price o f a commodity and its quantity
demanded. The monopolist alone constitutes the entire industry. Therefore,
her demand curve coincides with the industry demand curve, that i s , i t i s
downwards sloping. I n other words, a monopolist can sell larger quantities at
relatively lower prices only. Also note that as price falls from OF to OE, the
marginal revenue declines from OF to OH But, EH =2EF. Therefore, M R falls
twice as sharply as AR.
Theory of Monopol?
Let us recapitulate the relationshipamong average revenue (AR), marginal revenue
(MR) and elasticity (e), namely, MR=AR - AR / e = AR( 1 - 1 / e ). If e > 1, as
we lower the price, total revenue increases. Since marginal revenue is the addition
to total revenue, it follows that marginal revenue must be positive. If, on the other
hand. total revenue falls with lower price, e < d and marginal revenue must be
negative. If e = 1, total revenue does not change with a change in price, marginal
revenue must be zero. Thus, we can say that, when MR > 0, then e > 1; when
MR=O, then e = 1. and when MR < 0, then e < 1. This is shown in the Fig. 9.2.
Fig. 9.2
Fig. 9.2: Restates relationship between AR, MRand elasticity of demand. Recall that
elasticity at any point on the demand curve is the ratio of its lower segment to
the upper. Also note that when elasticity is unity, MRdrops down to zero. If
point E is on the demand curve AB, then over the range EB, e <I,at E, e = I and
over EA, e > 1.
Fig. 9.3
I I
0 X Quantity
Fig.9.3 shows short run equilibrium of the monopolist firm. The usual ~ p d i t i o n of
equilibrium, rising M C cuts MR from below applies to the monopolist as well.
However, this firm is able to charge the highest price that the consumer may be
willing to pay. The level of output is determined at OX, the point that coincides
with the ordinate of the point of intersection of MR and M C curves. At illis level
of output, the maximum price that consumers are willing to pay is OP and the
monopolist charges this very price to masimise his profits.
Fig. 9.3 depicts average revenue (AR) and marginal revenue (MR) curves, average
total cost curve (SRAC) and marginal cost curve (SRMC) respectively. The
equilibrium occurs at pokt E where both the conditions ofequilibrium. i.e. MR
equals SRMC and SRMC intersects MR from below are met. l'he equilibrium
output and price are OX and OP. This shows that price is greater than average
costs, and so a profit is being made. It also tells that profits are being maximised.
since MC and MR are equal. If output were to increase beyond OX. the addition
to total cost would be greater than the additions to total revenue. resulting in a .
decrea~eof profit. If output were less than OX, the additions to total revenue
would be greater than the addition to total cost and profit would increase by
expanding output. So, profits are maximised at OX and are shown by the rectangle
PABC in the Fig. 9.3 above.
...................................................................................................................
What are the conditions that might give rise to a monopoly?
#
...................................................................................................................
The demandcurve facing a n~onopolistis downward sloping, Explain.
Draw a linear demand curve and its associated marginal revenue curve. State
the formula that relates marginal revenue, price and elasticity of demand, and
explain how the curves illustrate the relationship identified by the formula.
...................................................................................................................
C
~-~
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
8) Discuss the determinationof price and output of a monopoly firm in the long-
ml.
Fiz. 9.4 shows a situation where the monopoly firm may be forced to toleratesome 'loss'
in theshort r h . I t will continue to produce so long as AR> AVC. If demand
curveslides lower, the firm will be forced toshut down even in the short run. If,
in the long run, the firm is able to adjust its plant to the size o f the market
demand, well and good. Otherwise, it has no option but to quit.
In such a situation, a monopoly firm will go out of the business in the long-run unless Theory O T Monopoly
0 X Quantity
Fig. 9.5: Shows a special case where MC =AC =constant. The monopolists equilibrium
is still at point E where MC cuts MR from below. 'The firm produces OX output
and sells it at O P ( = AR) price.
Fig.9.6: There are two prices, the competitive price, PCand the monopolist's price,
P,,. The loss ofconsumer's surplus attributable to the higher monopoly price
is the sum of rectangular area, PmAEIAPcand the triangle EIE2A.But gain to
the monopolist isconfined to the rectangle only. The consumer 's loss equal to
the triangle referred to above is 'dead weight loss'. Also note that the consumer
is worse off in one more sense : she has to remain contented with a smaller
quantity under monopoly than was available in perfect competition.
T h e o r y of Monopol!
I
How far can a monopolist go on charging different prices for the same product?
What is the limit? The-degree of price discrimination sets the limits within which
a monopolists can charge different prices. We can distinguish between 3 degrees
of price discrimination. Look into the following discussion in this regard.
First Degree Price Discrimination
Discrimination of the first degree definesthe maximum possible limit of a monopolist
in charging different prices for the same product. By setting the price accordingly,
the monopolist extracts from each consumer the entire amount of consumer
surplus. For this reason, first degree discrimination is also called perfect
discrimination.
Second Degree Price Discrimination
In case of second degree of price discrimination, the monopoly firm sells
to the consumer a block of output at one price and additional block of output at
a different price. In this way, the monopolist captures a part of the consumers'
surpluses, but not all of them. The schedules of rates charged by public utilities
provide examples of second-degree discrimination. Observe the rates you pay
for electricity and water supply. Cl~argesare in different slab rates. Such structures
come close to the underlying idea behind second degree price discrimination.
Third Degree Price Discrimination
Third-degreeprice discrimination means that the monopolist divides customers
into two or more groups, charging a different price to each group of customers.
Each class is treated as aseparate market. This is the most common type of
price discrimination and form the subject matter of study in the following pages.
Thus if e l is greater than e,, then P, mu& be less than P2in order to maintain the
equality between the two sides of the above expression. So, the price is higher in
the market which has less-elastic demand. However, the above result hold good
subject to the following conditions:
a) that the coefficient of elasticity of demand is greater than one in both the
markets, and
b) it is profitable to sell in both the market, that is, marginal revenue in both the
market is greater than marginal cost.
-
Fig. 9.7: Panel I of the figure AR, = D, and MR, curves in the market A. The corresponding
curves for market Bareshown in panel 11. Notice that demand'curve in market B
is moreelastic of the two. The third panel shows aggregate demand curve D =Dl
+ D2and aggregate marginal revenue curve associated with D. The marginal
cost curveof the firm, MC cuts theMR at point E and therefore, firms total output
is OQ in panel Ill. The firm equates marginal revenue in each market to this
equilibrium level of MC = MR = Q E . Thus, it sells OQ, and OQ2quantities in
markets Aand B respectively. The prices in two markets are OPA and OPB .The
market A, where elasticity of demand is lower, pays a higher price compared to
market B.
To illaximise her profits. the price discriminating inonoplist has to take two decisions:
a) How much total output to produce?
b) How much to sell in each ~narketand at what price?
l'he equilibrium level output oftlie price discriminating monopolist is at point where
MC equals aggregate MR. Since elasticities in two market segments are
different, her profit are maximised if MR, = MR2= MR = MC. The producer
charges less price in ~narketwhere demand is more elastic.
Check Your Progress 2
I ) What is pricediscrimination ?
t The purpose of this note is to s11our that a\ erage cost principle and marginal
i analysis ~ o u l gived the same long-run profit maximisation solution. The setting of
the price on the basis of the average cost principles incorporates an estinlation of
the elasticity of demand in the long-run eqi~illbrium.Recall that the necessary
f
condition for profit masimisation is MC = MR. It has all-eady been proved that MR
= P (1 -1le). Given that b1C' > 0. MR must be positive for protit maximisation.
This i~mpliese> I . I'rovided that AVC is constant over the relevant range ofoutput.
thdt is. AVC = MC. For ecluilibrium, AVC = MR, that is, AVC = P (1-lle) =
I'((e-l)/e). In other words. P = AVC{e/(e-1)). Given that e >I. we may write
e/(e- 1 ) ) = ( l +ki. \z here k >O. Therefore, P = AVC ( 1+k). where k is the gross
profit margin. I'or e ~ a m p l e .i f the lirm sets a 20 per cent of AVC as its profit
margin, we have ( I +k) = I ( t ) 0.20 = (e/(e-I ) ) . TIIL~s, tlie elasticity of demand
is 6. Setting a gross profit margin is equivalent to estimating the price elasticity of
demand and applying marginulist analysis. So when the businessman establishes
a mark-up on average costs, he is guessing at the coefficient of price elasticity of
demand.
Check Your Progress 3
...................................................................................................................
2) Write a short note on mark-up pricing.
A\,cn~gcCost Pricing : I'olicy under which the price covers average cost of
production.
9.12 HINTSIANSWERSTOCHECKYOUR
PROGRESS EXERCISES
C'hecli Your l'rogrcss I