Example: Homogeneous Divisible Goods
Example: Homogeneous Divisible Goods
Consumption is separated from production, logically, because two different economic agents
are involved. In the first case consumption is by the primary individual; in the second case, a
producer might make something that he would not consume himself. Therefore, different
motivations and abilities are involved. The models that make up consumer theory are used to
represent prospectively observable demand patterns for an individual buyer on the hypothesis
of constrained optimization. Prominent variables used to explain the rate at which the good is
purchased (demanded) are the price per unit of that good, prices of related goods, and wealth of
the consumer.
The law of demand states that the rate of consumption falls as the price of the good rises, even
when the consumer is monetarily compensated for the effect of the higher price; this is called
the substitution effect. As the price of a good rises, consumers will substitute away from that
good, choosing more of other alternatives. If no compensation for the price rise occurs, as is
usual, then the decline in overall purchasing power due to the price rise leads, for most goods,
to a further decline in the quantity demanded; this is called the income effect.
In addition, as the wealth of the individual rises, demand for most products increases, shifting
the demand curve higher at all possible prices.
The consumption set C – the set of all bundles that the consumer could conceivably
consume.
A preference relation over the bundles of C. This preference relation can be described as an
ordinal utility function, describing the utility that the consumer derives from each bundle.
An initial endowment, which is a bundle from C that the consumer initially holds. The
consumer can sell all or some of his initial bundle in the given prices, and can buy another
bundle in the given prices. He has to decide which bundle to buy, under the given prices and
budget, in order to maximize his utility.
Consider an economy with two types of homogeneous divisible goods, traditionally called X and
Y.
The consumption set is , i.e. the set of all pairs where and . Each
bundle contains a non-negative quantity of good X and a non-negative quantity of good Y.
A typical price system assigns a price to each type of good, such that the cost of bundle
is .
A typical initial endowment is just a fixed income, which along with the prices implies a
budget constraint. The consumer can choose any point on or below the budget constraint line
BC In the diagram. This line is downward sloped and linear since it represents the boundary of
the inequality . In other words, the amount spent on both goods
together is less than or equal to the income of the consumer.
The consumer will choose the indifference curve with the highest utility that is attainable within
his budget constraint. Every point on indifference curve I3 is outside his budget constraint so
the best that he can do is the single point on I2 where the latter is tangent to his budget
constraint. He will purchase X* of good X and Y* of good Y.
Indifference curve analysis begins with the utility function. The utility function is treated as an
index of utility.[1] All that is necessary is that the utility index change as more preferred bundles
are consumed.
Indifference curves are typically numbered with the number increasing as more preferred
bundles are consumed. The numbers have no cardinal significance; for example if three
indifference curves are labeled 1, 4, and 16 respectively that means nothing more than the
bundles "on" indifference curve 4 are more preferred than the bundles "on" indifference curve 1.
Income effect and price effect deal with how the change in price of a commodity changes the
consumption of the good. The theory of consumer choice examines the trade-offs and
decisions people make in their role as consumers as prices and their income changes.
Example: land
The consumption set is , i.e. the set of all subsets of L (all land parcels).
A typical preference relation in this universe can be represented by a utility function which
assigns, to each land parcel, its total "fertility" (the total amount of grain that can be grown in
that land).
A typical price system assigns a price to each land parcel, based on its area.
A typical initial endowment is either a fixed income, or an initial parcel which the consumer
can sell and buy another parcel.[2]
The indifference curves and budget constraint can be used to predict the effect of changes to
the budget constraint. The graph below shows the effect of a price increase for good Y. If the
price of Y increases, the budget constraint will pivot from BC2 to BC1. Notice that because the
price of X does not change, the consumer can still buy the same amount of X if he or she
chooses to buy only good X. On the other hand, if the consumer chooses to buy only good Y, he
or she will be able to buy less of good Y because its price has increased.
To maximize the utility with the reduced budget constraint, BC1, the consumer will re-allocate
consumption to reach the highest available indifference curve which BC1 is tangent to. As
shown on the diagram below, that curve is I1, and therefore the amount of good Y bought will
shift from Y2 to Y1, and the amount of good X bought to shift from X2 to X1. The opposite effect
will occur if the price of Y decreases causing the shift from BC2 to BC3, and I2 to I3.
If these curves are plotted for many different prices of good Y, a demand curve for good Y can
be constructed. The diagram below shows the demand curve for good Y as its price varies.
Alternatively, if the price for good Y is fixed and the price for good X is varied, a demand curve
for good X can be constructed.
Income effect
Income effect
Main article: Income effect
Another important item that can change is the money income of the consumer. The income
effect is the phenomenon observed through changes in purchasing power. It reveals the change
in quantity demanded brought by a change in real income. Graphically, as long as the prices
remain constant, changing income will create a parallel shift of the budget constraint.
Increasing the income will shift the budget constraint right since more of both can be bought,
and decreasing income will shift it left.
Depending on the indifference curves, as income increases, the amount purchased of a good
can either increase, decrease or stay the same. In the diagram below, good Y is a normal good
since the amount purchased increased as the budget constraint shifted from BC1 to the higher
income BC2. Good X is an inferior good since the amount bought decreased as the income
increases.
is the change in the demand for good 1 when we change income from to , holding the price of
good 1 fixed at :
Every price change can be decomposed into an income effect and a substitution effect; the
price effect is the sum of substitution and income effects.
The substitution effect is the change in demands resulting from a price change that alters the
slope of the budget constraint but leaves the consumer on the same indifference curve. In other
words, it illustrates the consumer's new consumption basket after the price change while being
compensated as to allow the consumer to be as happy as he or she was previously. By this
effect, the consumer is posited to substitute toward the good that becomes comparatively less
expensive. In the illustration below this corresponds to an imaginary budget constraint denoted
SC being tangent to the indifference curve I1. Then the income effect from the rise in
purchasing power from a price fall reinforces the substitution effect. If the good is an inferior
good, then the income effect will offset in some degree the substitution effect. If the income
effect for an inferior good is sufficiently strong, the consumer will buy less of the good when it
becomes less expensive, a Giffen good (commonly believed to be a rarity).
The substitution effect, , is the change in the amount demanded for when the price of
good falls from to (represented by the budget constraint shifting from BC1 to BC2
and thus increasing purchasing power) and, at the same time, the money income falls from
to to keep the consumer at the same level of utility on :
The substitution effect increases the amount demanded of good from to in the
diagram. In the example shown, the income effect of the fall in partly offsets the
substitution effect as the amount demanded of in the absence of an offsetting income
change ends up at thus the income effect from the rise in purchasing power due to the
price drop is that the quantity demanded of goes from to . The total effect of the
price drop on quantity demanded is the sum of the substitution effect and the income effect.
Assumptions
The behavioral assumption of the consumer theory proposed herein is that all consumers seek
to maximize utility. In the mainstream economics tradition, this activity of maximizing utility has
been deemed as the "rational" behavior of decision makers. More specifically, in the eyes of
economists, all consumers seek to maximize a utility function subject to a budgetary
constraint.[3] In other words, economists assume that consumers will always choose the "best"
bundle of goods they can afford.[4] Consumer theory is therefore based around the problem of
generate refutable hypotheses about the nature of consumer demand from this behavioral
postulate.[3]
In order to reason from the central postulate towards a useful model of consumer choice, it is
necessary to make additional assumptions about the certain preferences that consumers
employ when selecting their preferred "bundle" of goods. These are relatively strict, allowing for
the model to generate more useful hypotheses with regard to consumer behaviour than weaker
assumptions, which would allow any empirical data to be explained in terms of stupidity,
ignorance, or some other factor, and hence would not be able to generate any predictions about
future demand at all.[3] For the most part, however, they represent statements which would only
be contradicted if a consumer was acting in (what was widely regarded as) a strange manner.[5]
In this vein, the modern form of consumer choice theory assumes:
Note the assumptions do not guarantee that the demand curve will be negatively sloped. A
positively sloped curve is not inconsistent with the assumptions.[8]
Use value
In Marx's critique of political economy, any labor-product has a value and a use value, and if it is
traded as a commodity in markets, it additionally has an exchange value, most often expressed
as a money-price.[9] Marx acknowledges that commodities being traded also have a general
utility, implied by the fact that people want them, but he argues that this by itself tells us nothing
about the specific character of the economy in which they are produced and sold.
Labor-leisure tradeoff
Main article: Backward bending supply curve of labour
One can also use consumer theory to analyze a consumer's choice between leisure and labor.
Leisure is considered one good (often put on the horizontal axis) and consumption is
considered the other good. Since a consumer has a finite amount of time, he must make a
choice between leisure (which earns no income for consumption) and labor (which does earn
income for consumption).
The previous model of consumer choice theory is applicable with only slight modifications.
First, the total amount of time that an individual has to allocate is known as his "time
endowment", and is often denoted as T. The amount an individual allocates to labor (denoted L)
and leisure (l) is constrained by T such that
A person's consumption is the amount of labor they choose multiplied by the amount they are
paid per hour of labor (their wage, often denoted w). Thus, the amount that a person consumes
is:
From this labor-leisure tradeoff model, the substitution effect and income effect from various
changes caused by welfare benefits, labor taxation, or tax credits can be analyzed.
See also
Convex preferences
Consumer sovereignty
Indifference curves
Microeconomics
Opportunity cost
Producer theory – the dual of consumer theory
References
2. ^ Berliant, M.; Raa, T. T. (1988). "A foundation of location theory: Consumer preferences and
demand". Journal of Economic Theory. 44 (2): 336. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(88)90008-7 .
Böhm, Volker; Haller, Hans (1987). "Demand theory". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of
Economics. 1. pp. 785–92.
Binger; Hoffman (1998). Microeconomics with Calculus (2nd ed.). Addison Wesley. pp. 141–
43.