0% found this document useful (0 votes)
78 views10 pages

The Keynesian Multiplier and The Pigou Effect Unde PDF

This document summarizes a working paper that presents a simple macroeconomic model to analyze the effects of public expenditure on output and the "Keynesian multiplier". The model considers substitution between private and public consumption goods. Key findings include: 1) The Keynesian multiplier depends on the degree of substitution between private and public goods, and is lower when public expenditure is financed by deficits rather than taxes. 2) Expressed in terms of elasticities, the Keynesian multiplier is always less than one, meaning a 1% increase in spending increases output by less than 1%. 3) The "Pigou effect" of price decreases on real wealth, similarly expressed in elasticities, is also less than

Uploaded by

Jennidumais
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
78 views10 pages

The Keynesian Multiplier and The Pigou Effect Unde PDF

This document summarizes a working paper that presents a simple macroeconomic model to analyze the effects of public expenditure on output and the "Keynesian multiplier". The model considers substitution between private and public consumption goods. Key findings include: 1) The Keynesian multiplier depends on the degree of substitution between private and public goods, and is lower when public expenditure is financed by deficits rather than taxes. 2) Expressed in terms of elasticities, the Keynesian multiplier is always less than one, meaning a 1% increase in spending increases output by less than 1%. 3) The "Pigou effect" of price decreases on real wealth, similarly expressed in elasticities, is also less than

Uploaded by

Jennidumais
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 10

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/227353283

The Keynesian Multiplier and the Pigou Effect Under Substitution between
Private and Public Consumption

Article  in  SSRN Electronic Journal · July 2010


DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2690287 · Source: RePEc

CITATIONS READS

0 84

1 author:

Luis C. Corchon
University Carlos III de Madrid
160 PUBLICATIONS   930 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Dominant strategies in Contests View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Luis C. Corchon on 19 November 2018.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Working Paper 09-64 Departamento de Economía
Economic Series (39) Universidad Carlos III de Madrid
September 2009 Calle Madrid, 126
28903 Getafe (Spain)
Fax (34) 916249875

THE KEYNESIAN MULTIPLIER AND THE PIGOU


EFFECT UNDER SUBSTITUTION BETWEEN PRIVATE
AND PUBLIC CONSUMPTION*
Luis C. Corchón
Departament of Economics
Universidad Carlos III

First version April 21th 2009. This version September 9th 2009.

Abstract
In this paper we present a fixprice model in which private and public consumption show
some degree of substitution. We offer formulae for the Keynesian multiplier which
depend on this degree of substitution. We also show that there is a Pigou effect and that,
sometimes, this effect is larger than the Keynesian multiplier.

*
The author acknowledges comments from Alberto Alonso and financial support from
SEJ2005-06167/ECON.
1. INTRODUCTION

Current economic events have fueled a lively discussion about the best way
to …ght unemployment. This paper is an attempt to discuss this issue in a
simple static macroeconomic model in which:

1. Agents maximize utility subject to budget constraint and given prices.


2. Goods and money markets clear but, for exogenous reasons that are not
discussed in this paper, the labor market does not clear.1

Our model is very stylized: There is only one input, labor, which produces
a consumption good under constant returns to scale. The latter assumption
simpli…es the supply side of the economy by making supply in…nitely elastic
and together with our assumption of perfect competition implies that there are
no pro…ts. Since neither the responsiveness of supply to demand nor the distri-
bution of income are at the stake in current discussions this is not a harmful as-
sumption. Money is the only asset and it is demanded because it is an argument
in the utility function. This choice of modelling is dictated by simplicity, see
Blanchard and Fischer (1989). The government obtains all revenue on a linear
income tax again an assumption brought about by simplicity. Finally, monetary
wages are given.2 Thus, important considerations for the understanding of the
crisis such as productivity growth, capital/investment, indirect taxation, mo-
nopolistic competition, stock market and increasing/decreasing returns to scale
are outside the scope of this paper.
Following an idea of Bailey (1971), see also Barro (1981), we consider the
possible substitution between private and public consumption. For instance
if publicly built schools are as good as privately built schools, an increase in
the former should have some e¤ect on the private demand of the latter. Or if
the government runs a de…cit, the citizens may feel that this de…cit, sooner or
later, will fall on them.3 Thus in our model the utility of the representative
consumer is a function of two variables. On the one hand, a linear combination
of the privately and the publicly provided consumption good with weights 1
and a 2 [0; 1]. On the other hand on money and the budget surplus of the
government with weights 1 and b 2 [0; 1]. If a = 0, the consumer feels that
the publicly provided good, say bridges, is not related to the privately provided
good, say, beef. If a = 1, the consumer takes the publicly provided consumption
good, say public health care, as a perfect substitute for the privately provided
consumption good, say private health care. If b = 0, the consumer feels that the
debt (resp. surplus) incurred by the government will not be paid (resp. received)
by her, because it will be paid (resp. received) in a distant future or by a future
1 For a possible explanation of why wages do not adjust supply and demand of labor see

Bewley (1999).
2 Our model falls into the …xprice literature pioneered by Barro and Grossman (1976),

Benassy (1975), Drèze (1975), Malinvaud (1977) and Younès (1975). See Silvestre (1982) for
a general view on this literature.
3 This is the issue behind the "Ricardian equivalence".

1
generation. If b = 1, the consumer takes the government debt (resp. surplus)
as an immediate decrease (resp. increase) in her wealth. b can be interpreted
as the percentage of the current de…cit paid by the current generation. Similar
preferences have been considered by Heijdra, Ligthart and van der Ploeg (1998)
in the framework of Monopolistic Competition and by Linnemann and Schabert
(2003) in a New Keynesian model. Our main results are:

1. When the increase in public expenditure is …nanced entirely by taxes or


b = 1, i.e. the de…cit is discounted as an immediate reduction in wealth,
the Keynesian multiplier is 1 a. When publicly and privately provided
consumption goods are not related (a = 0) this is the well-known result
that the multiplier of the balanced budget is one.
2. When the increase in public expenditure is …nanced by a de…cit the mul-
tiplier is decreasing in both a and b. When the goods o¤ered by the
government and the private sector are not related (a = b = 0) we obtain
a formula that is identical to the textbook Keynesian multiplier.
3. When written in terms of elasticities, instead of the usual formulation of a
ratio of increments, the Keynesian multiplier is always smaller than one.
This means that an increase in public expenditure of x% increases total
output in less than x%.
4. The Pigou e¤ect, namely the e¤ect on real wealth of a decrease in prices,
in terms of elasticities is, also, smaller than one. When the increase in
public expenditure is …nanced entirely by taxes or a = b = 1 the elasticity
associated with the Pigou e¤ect is larger than the elasticity of the Key-
nesian multiplier. If a = b = 0 the Keynesian multiplier is larger than its
Pigouvian counterpart for "reasonable" values of the parameters.

2. THE MODEL

There are two goods consumed with prices denoted by p and 1. The second
good will be called money from now on. There is an input, labor, whose price
is denoted by !. Good 1 is produced under constant returns to scale and units
are chosen such that the marginal cost of this good is !. Assuming that the
economy is perfectly competitive,

p = !: (1)

The government raises funds by a tax on income (I) with a constant tax rate t,
and buys goods 1 and 2 in quantities G and S. While G is positive, S can be
positive (surplus) or negative (de…cit). The government budget constraint is

pG + S = tI: (2)

2
There is a representative consumer with preferences representable by a Cobb-
Douglas utility function

U = A(x + aG) (M + bS)1

where x is the consumption of good 1, M is the consumption of money, A > 0,


2 (0; 1) and a; b 2 [0; 1]. When a = b = 1 the consumer considers that G and
S are perfect substitutes of private consumption and wealth. When a = b = 0
the consumer does not take into consideration G and S. This may be because
she considers public expenditure as a total waste (like certain public works) and
that the debt arising from the de…cit will paid in a distant future, perhaps by
a di¤erent generation. Another interpretation of a = 0 is that the government
produces a di¤erent good (bridges) whose price, by taking units, can also be
taken as !. This good a¤ects A making the consumer better o¤ but it does not
a¤ect her consumption choices. Compare with Heijdra, Ligthart and van der
Ploeg (1998) equation (1) and Linnemann and Schabert (2003) equation (2).
The representative consumer has endowments of labor and money of L and
M respectively. Her budget constraint is

px + M = I(1 t): (3)

Adding (2) and (3), we get that pG + S + px + M = I. Since pro…ts are zero and
wages are obtained producing G or x, income is de…ned as I = !G + !x + M .
Taking into account (1); the last two equalities imply that S + M = M . Thus,
when the public sector runs a surplus (S > 0), M < M . A public sector de…cit
(S < 0) implies M > M :
From utility maximization at given prices and income, demand functions are

(I(1 t) + bS)
x = (1 )aG, (4)
p
M = (1 )(I(1 t) + apG) bS (5)

2. 1. Market Clearing Equilibrium

In a market-clearing equilibrium all markets clear. Denoting the variable,


say, z in a market-clearing equilibrium as z C (C for clearing) we have that

xC + G = L: (6)
IC = !C L + M . (7)

Notice that the real GDP of our economy is xC + G which, given our choice of
units, is just L. From (4), (6) and (7) prices and wages in a market-clearing
equilibrium are
(M S(1 b))
pC = ! C = : (8)
(1 )(L G(1 a))

3
Thus prices and wages increase with the money supply, the de…cit (unless b = 1)
and the public expenditure (unless a = 1) and decrease with the labor supply.
From (6) consumption of good 1 in a market-clearing equilibrium is

xC = L G (9)

Thus, consumption of good 1 increases with resources and decreases with public
expenditure in a one-by-one basis independently of the parameter a.

2.2. Non Clearing Equilibrium

In a no clearing labor market equilibrium, non clearing for short, the supply
of labor exceeds the demand of labor denoted by LN . All other markets clear.
Let us denote the variables in such an equilibrium by the superscript N (N for
non clearing). Thus,

LN = xN + G. (10)
pN = !N : (11)

Now the income of the consumer is determined by the actual production, namely

I N = ! N (xN + G) + M : (12)

Taking into account (11) and (4) we have that

(I N (1
t) + bS)
xN = (1 )aG: (13)
!N
Plugging (12) and (2) in (13) and using (10) we have that

(M S(1 b))
xN = aG (14)
! N (1 )
(M S(1 b))
LN = + G(1 a) (15)
! N (1 )

From (15) we see that L > LN i¤

(M S(1 b))
!N > = !C (16)
(1 )(L G(1 a))
Thus it can be said that, in this model, unemployment arises because wages are
too high.4 This is just a wat of saying that our model embodies a Pigou e¤ect
where a decrease in prices may increase GDP.
Let us make a simple calibration exercise. Despite the fact that, as noticed
in the introduction, our economy has very stylized features, this exercise might
throw some light on our model. In order to obtain possible values for the
N N
parameters, divide both sides of (15) by the GDP, LN . We interpret L M! as
4 The same happens in the venerable IS-LM model.

4
the velocity of money and we will denote this magnitude by v. De…ning g LGN
S
and s LN
= t g as, respectively, the fractions of public expenditure and
de…cit in GDP, (15) yields
1
(1 )(1 g(1 a)) = ( s(1 b)): (17)
v
From (13) we interpret as the marginal propensity to consume. Letting
= :8; g 2 [:3; :5] and s 2 [ :03; :05] in (17) we see that depending on the
values of a and b, v ranges between 4 and 13: 333, not very di¤erent from what
is shown in real data. Notice that (17) implies that if g and s are constant the
velocity of money is constant too.

3. THE KEYNESIAN MULTIPLIER

Recall that the government can not choose S; G and t simultaneously. Equa-
tion (15) involves the de…cit and public expenditure, so it is the appropriate
equation to work with when the strategies of the government are these two vari-
ables. Thus in this case, the tax rate is adjusted to satisfy (2). In this case we
see that the Keynesian multiplier is

@LN
=1 a (18)
@G
which in the best case scenario (i.e. when public consumption does not a¤ect
the private consumption or a = 0) is one and in the extreme case in which
public and private consumption are perfect substitutes it is zero. The former
corresponds to the well-known result that the multiplier with a balanced budget
is one. Writing the multiplier in terms of elasticities we have that

@LN G
= (1 a)g < 1:
@G LN
Suppose now that the strategies of the government are t and G. In this
case the de…cit (or surplus) takes the toll of the adjustment. After lengthy
calculations we obtain that
M
!N
(1 (1 b)t) + G(a a b + 1)
LN = (19)
(1 ) + (1 b)t

Now the Keynesian multiplier is

@LN a(1 )+1 b


= : (20)
@G (1 ) + (1 b)t

Notice that, as intuition suggests, the larger a the smaller the value of the
1
multiplier. In the extreme case in which a = b = 0 the multiplier is 1 (1 t)
which, interpreting again as the marginal propensity to consume, is just the

5
textbook Keynesian multiplier. But when b = 1, i.e. when the e¤ect of debt
is fully anticipated, the multiplier is, again, 1 a, never larger than one. Our
expressions (18) and (20) generalize those obtained by Bailey (1971), Chapter
9, Table 1 for the limiting cases where a and b are either 0 or 1.
Again writing the multiplier in terms of elasticity

@LN G ( a(1 ) + 1 b )pN G


= < 1: (21)
@G LN M (1 (1 b)t) + pN G( a(1 )+1 b )

4. THE PIGOU EFFECT

The …xprice model is an interesting scenario to study the so called "Pigou


e¤ect" in which a decrease in prices/wages increases employment via increases
in real wealth.5 Let us consider …rst the case in which the de…cit is constant.
In this case, from (15) the multiplier associated with the Pigou e¤ect is:

@LN (M (1 b)S)
= : (22)
@pN (1 )(pN )2

Writing the previous expression in terms of elasticities,

@LN pN (M (1 b)S)
= =1 g(1 a): (23)
@pN LN (M (1 b)S) + (1 )pN G(1 a)

Clearly, the elasticity associated with the Keynesian multiplier is larger than
the elasticity associated with the Pigouvian multiplier i¤

2g(1 a) > 1: (24)


Even in the most favorable case for the Keynesian multiplier, i.e. a = 0, the
inequality (24) requires that the ratio public expenditure/GDP be larger than a
half. So if the de…cit is constant, we should expect better results on employment
from a pro-competitive policy which facilitates price decreases rather than from
public expenditure.
Suppose now that the strategies of the government are t and G. In this case
the Pigouvian multiplier is

@LN M (1 (1 b)t)
= . (25)
@pN ((1 ) + (1 b)t)(! N )2

Writing the Pigou multiplier in terms of elasticities, we have that

@LN pN M (1 (1 b)t)
= < 1: (26)
@pN LN M (1 (1 b)t) + pN G(a a b + 1)
5 The current crisis has caused a moderate de‡iation in many countries. Thus, prices

decreased in Great Britain .4% in March 2009 and .1% in Spain in the same period.

6
From (21) and (26) we obtain that the elasticity associated with the Keynesian
multiplier is larger than the elasticity associated with the Pigouvian multiplier
i¤ ( a(1 ) + 1 b )pN G > M (1 (1 b)t), or

( a(1 )+1 b )gv > (1 (1 b)t) (27)

In this case the comparison is ambiguous. If a = b = 1 the Pigouvian multiplier


is larger than its Keynesian counterpart. If a = b = 0 the Keynesian multiplier
is larger than its Pigouvian counterpart if and only if gv > (1 t). This
inequality holds for the kind of values of g; v and considered in the simple
calibration exercise performed at the end of Section 4.

5. CONCLUSIONS

In this paper we have presented a simple …xprice model in which public and
private consumption might be substitutes. We have shown that the value of the
multiplier depends on this degree of substitution. In particular when de…cits
are fully incorporated into wealth we get a "Ricardian Equivalence" result, see
Benassy (2007) for a similar result in a di¤erent framework. We also have
shown that the Pigou e¤ect exists in our …xprice model and that, sometimes, it
is stronger than the Keynesian multiplier. This is, of course, not an argument
against public expenditure as a means of increasing employment. But it raises
the point that, sometimes, a policy of de‡ation may have even better results
in terms of increasing employment. The latter policy was considered dangerous
by Keynes ([1936], Chapter 19) because of its e¤ects on price expectations. We
plan to study this question more carefully in a subsequent paper.

REFERENCES

Bailey, Martin J. (1971). National Income and the Price Level: A Study in
Macroeconomic Theory. 2d ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Barro, Robert J. (1981). "Output E¤ects of Government Purchases". The
Journal of Political Economy, 89, 6, 1086-1121.
Barro, Robert J. and Herschel I. Grossman (1976). Money, Employment and
In‡ation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Benassy, Jean-Pascal (1975). “Neo-Keynesian disequilibrium theory in a
monetary economy”. Review of Economic Studies 42, 503–23.
Benassy, Jean-Pascal (2007). "Ricardian equivalence and the intertemporal
Keynesian multiplier". Economics Letters, 94, 1, 118-123.
Bewley, Truman F. (1999). Why Wages Don’t Fall during a Recession. Cam-
bridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Blachard, Olivier J. and Stanley Fischer (1989). Lectures on Macroeco-
nomics. MIT Press
Drèze, Jacques (1975). “Existence of an exchange equilibrium under price
rigidities”. International Economic Review 16, 301–20.

7
Heijdra, B., J. E. Ligthart and F. van der Ploeg (1998). "Fiscal Policy,
Distortionary Taxation, and Direct Crowding Out under Monopolistic Compe-
tition". Oxford Economic Papers 50, 79-88.
Keynes, J. M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and
Money. London: Macmillan.
Linnemann, L. and A. Schabert (2003). "Can …scal spending stimulate pri-
vate consumption?". Economic Letters 82, 173-179.
Malinvaud, Edmond (1977). The Theory of Unemployment Reconsidered.
Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Silvestre, Joaquim (1982). Fixprice analysis in exchange economies. Journal
of Economic Theory, 26, 28-58
Younès, Yves (1975). “On the role of money in the process of exchange and
the existence of a non-Walrasian equilibrium”. Review of Economic Studies 42,
489–501.

View publication stats

You might also like