Journal of Physics: Conference Series
PAPER • OPEN ACCESS
Mathematical Model: The Long-Term Effects of Defense Expenditure on
Economic Growth and the Criticism
To cite this article: Posma Sariguna Johnson Kennedy et al 2018 J. Phys.: Conf. Ser. 1114 012118
View the article online for updates and enhancements.
This content was downloaded from IP address 36.71.233.13 on 19/03/2020 at 07:26
WMA-Mathcomtech 2018 IOP Publishing
IOP Conf. Series: Journal of Physics: Conf. Series 1114 (2018)
1234567890 ‘’“” 012118 doi:10.1088/1742-6596/1114/1/012118
Mathematical Model: The Long-Term Effects of Defense
Expenditure on Economic Growth and the Criticism
Posma Sariguna Johnson Kennedy1*, Suzanna Josephine L.Tobing1, Rutman
Lumbantoruan1, Emma Tampubolon1 and Adolf Bastian Heatubun2
1
Faculty of Economic and Business, Universitas Kristen Indonesia, Jakarta, Indonesia
2
Universitas Pattimura, Maluku, Indonesia
*
[email protected]
Abstract. This paper aims to form a mathematical model that can explain the influence of
national defense budget on the economy through economic growth. The research method is by
literature review from the work of economists in making the production function model that
can bring defense expenditure into the economic growth model. The model is two-sector
economic model, established to look at the effects of defense spending and the economy. The
model of Ram based on the neoclassical production function approach. The externality effect
of the military and non-military sectors is different, so, they are included in the production
function separately.
1. Introduction
According to Cornes & Sandler, the activities of the government will affect the production capacity of
the private sector though not reflected in prices of competitive markets. This externality, for example,
can be formed from infrastructure activities, training, education, nutrition improvement, and other
activities that can increase the human resources an. When activities of one sector can increase output
from other sectors, there is a positive externalities, as well as if the opposite occurs. [1]
To see the effect of national defense on the economy over in the long term, it is approached
through an analysis of the supply side or production side. The effect of defense spending on economic
output are through the availability of its production factors, whether labor, capital and physical capital,
as well as technologies that simultaneously affect potential economic output.
Based on a formal model framework, a mathematical model would like to look at the effect of
defense spending on economic growth. Although in reality the relationship is very complex, but we
make a mathematical simplification through economic growth model. In general, this study aims to
form a mathematical model that can explain the influence of national defense budget on the economy
through economic growth. The research method is by literature review from the work of economists in
making the production function model that can bring defense expenditure into the economic growth
model.
One approach that commonly used in research on the relationship between defense spending and
economic growth is the neoclassical production function approach, by reviewing the supply-side
description through aggregate output changes [2]. It is also described by Ram [3], Biswas & Ram [4],
Content from this work may be used under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 licence. Any further distribution
of this work must maintain attribution to the author(s) and the title of the work, journal citation and DOI.
Published under licence by IOP Publishing Ltd 1
WMA-Mathcomtech 2018 IOP Publishing
IOP Conf. Series: Journal of Physics: Conf. Series 1114 (2018)
1234567890 ‘’“” 012118 doi:10.1088/1742-6596/1114/1/012118
Atesoglu and Mueller [5], Mintz & Huang [6][7], and Ward & Davis [8] and Heo [2]. This theory is
widely used because it is constructed from a consistent theory structure.[9]
This theory assumes that real output per capita and capital stock growth will remain in a constant
level over a period of time despite short-term fluctuations. It is also assumed that an increase in labor
and capital input at the steady level will also increase the aggregate output at a steady level. [10] Then
the change from the aggregate output will be explained through changes in capital and labor.
In neoclassical growth theory, explains that is no channel of government spending that affects long-
term economic growth.[11] The simplest model in shaping the economic model is to form the
assumption of a closed economy and a production sector, where output is a homogeneous good that
can be consumed at once invested. Investment produces new physical capital, and the capital
depreciates at a constant rate. Households and firms are considered joint units (which have input and
manage technologies that transform inputs to output), the market is neglected. The current output
produced at time t (Y) is affected by the production function of capital (K) and labor (L) depending on
the time (t) to reflect the effects of technological development, described as follows Y (t) = F [K (t), L
(t), t]. [12]
However, many assumptions are developed in modeling to include government expenditures with
the approach of the neoclassical production function. Government defense expenditure and its overall
impact on growth can be analyzed in the context of dividing the economy into several sectors, not just
one sector. These sectors form externalities that affect other sectors. The assumptions that divide
macroeconomic into two sectors, government and non-government (private) are preceded by Ram [3],
Biswas and Ram [4], based on the idea of non-export-export model by Feder [13].
2. Method
One common approach used to look at the effect of defense spending and economic growth is the
neoclassical production function approach. That is by reviewing the supply-side description through
the aggregate output changes.[2][14]
Antonakis argues that, it is important to build models by dividing the economy into sectors aimed
at capturing the impact of military spending on growth, although not reviewing the influence of other
macro variables. Thus the overall influence of military spending on growth is analyzed in the context
of dividing the economy into several sectors, in which sectors form externalities that affect other
sectors.[15]
The two-sector economic model established to look at the effects of defense spending and the
economy is a model of Ram based on the neoclassical production function approach built by Feder and
Deninsons. [3] Feder writes that aggregate growth is related to changes in capital and labor through a
certain or underlying production function.[13] He built a two-sector production function model,
consisting of export and non-export sectors. Deninson's source-of-growth model uses a supply-side
description of aggregate output change, which explains aggregate growth in its changes to capital and
labor.[16] Based on their views Feder, Deninson, and Ram built a model of two sectors also by
comprising the government sector and the private sector. In the development of defense economics,
the Feder-Ram model is widely used in explaining the relationship between military budget and
economic growth from the supply side.
The two-sector model built by Ram is the military output sector (M, government) and civil output
sector (C, private sector). Both sectors use labor (L) and capital (K), while the production function of
the military will exert external effects on production from the private sector. [3] The aggregate
production function of the output of the economic sectors is given by the following functions:
M M ( Lm , K m )
C C ( Lc , K c ) M c( Lc , K c ) C ( Lc , K c , M )
(1)
2
WMA-Mathcomtech 2018 IOP Publishing
IOP Conf. Series: Journal of Physics: Conf. Series 1114 (2018)
1234567890 ‘’“” 012118 doi:10.1088/1742-6596/1114/1/012118
Limitations of endowment factors are as follows:
L is Li
K is K i S m, c
(2)
And the national income is:
Y CM
(3)
The sum of these "butter" and "guns" can only be understood if their value is in monetary output
compared to the quantity output. It would be better to be formed in the normalization of prices, as
follows:
Y Pc .Cr.( Lc , K c ) Pm .Mr.( Lm , K m )
(4)
where Pm and Pc are constant unitary units of money prices associated with the output quantity of
Mr. and Cr. From this model can be formed marginal products of both labor (ML, CL) and capital (MK,
CK) which can be made proportionally between sectors, is a derivative of the production function of
inputs, namely:
ML MK
1
CL CK
(5)
The notations in equation (5), CM show the external effects of military output to the private sector,
and denote the relative factor productivity difference between the two sectors. If CM 0 and/or 0,
an increase in military output will cause a large growth rate of total Y output, from the sum of M and
C, using the given production function L and K.
Equation (5) is equivalent to:
Pm .MrL Pm .MrK
1
Pc .CrL Pc .CrK
(6)
Equation (6) shows the comparison between the productivity of marginal factors between different
production depending on the prices used on sectoral outputs.
Differentiation of (3), (1), and (2) forms the econometric speech of the growth equation, as follows:
C .L
Y L L C K . C M M
I M
Y Y 1 Y
(7)
where the dot notation indicates the rate of change in proportion or growth rate. I/Y and M/Y are
notations of the ratio of investment and military spending to total output. While I = dK which is a net
investment.
Using equation (1) and the constant elasticity of C to M equation (5) can be changed in the form
of:
I
Y ( L ) M .M
M
Y 1 Y
(8)
Where :
dY dL
Y , L , M
dM , M ,
CM C K , C L .L
Y L M
Y M Y
(9)
The difference in (7) with (8) is that in equation (7) hypothesis testing is possible only if the
variables CM and are zero. However this would cause the coefficient of (M/Y) to be zero thus
reducing the estimate of the standard growth equation. Using equation (8), we can be estimated
3
WMA-Mathcomtech 2018 IOP Publishing
IOP Conf. Series: Journal of Physics: Conf. Series 1114 (2018)
1234567890 ‘’“” 012118 doi:10.1088/1742-6596/1114/1/012118
separately to identify separately from the "externality effect" CM and the "marginal factor productivity
differential effect" .
3. Result and Discussions
Much debate has emerged against the defense-growth model that begins with the Feder-Ram model.
Some experts provide support, such as Deger and Sen that characterize the externality model of Feder-
Biswas-Ram as "a splendid empirical workhorse to investigate the impact of military expenditure on
growth."[17] Mintz and Stevenson (1995) seen using formal justification to include military
expenditure as explanatory variables in growth regression analysis with single-equation growth
analysis, based on neoclassical growth theory as its foundation.[18] Or, Biswas and Ram state, at least
stands out well on the framework of neoclassical production functions.[4] His famous approach is the
emergence of a direct link from the theoretical model to the econometric specification.
However, many critics say that Ram's study does not include other independent variables that also
affect economic growth. From the Keynesians see that neoclassical approach is not able to answer the
problem in the short term, especially if there are shocks encountered. Full economic conditions are
only limited to long-term models that are difficult to implement in reality.
But Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel said formation of the model faced many inaccuracies. Feder-
Ram model that notation of differences in factor of marginal productivity between sectors, as in the
following:
ML MK
1
CL CK
(10)
actually gives some wrong interpretations. In empirical literature, non-zero is generally interpreted to
reflect a situation in which one sector is more efficient or less productive in its factor users than
others.[19]
For example, Ward et al estimates a negative sign for Taiwan which can be inferred "that in
comparison to the civil sector, the military sector is realized more inefficiently".[20] Antonakis[15]
and Atesoglu and Mueller[5] write something similar: "Without a strong competitive pressure that
leads to ... efficiency in the management and use of resources, it can be argued that marginal
productivity factors are much lower in the defense sector". Such interpretations do not conform to a
recognized model of theory.
Another argument that the approach to capture some of the behavior of off-the-production
functions is not appropriate. The derivation of the empirical growth equation:
C .L
Y L L C K .
I M
M M
Y Y 1 Y
(11)
is specific to a certain level which is not different for intra-sectoral organizations. The model was built
incapable to calculate the intra-oriental organizational inefficiency. The next question is whether the
migration of a resource that raises real GDP is what the social really wants can not be answered
without knowing where the relative P price is used in an adequate Y calculation that reflects the social
marginal rate of substitution, the exchange of M for C. If that is the case, the non-zero reflects the
situation of the product mix in a large economy and the allocation of inter-sectoral factors in
eeconomy as a whole is inefficient. There is not much we can do to convert inputs into outputs in
individual sectors. In theoretically, there are many econometric problems in estimating the Feder-Ram
model. In the Feder-Ram equation where econometrically it can be derived as:
I M
Y 1 L 2 3 M 4 .M
Y Y
(12)
4
WMA-Mathcomtech 2018 IOP Publishing
IOP Conf. Series: Journal of Physics: Conf. Series 1114 (2018)
1234567890 ‘’“” 012118 doi:10.1088/1742-6596/1114/1/012118
It can not be indicated which is a variable and which serves as a parameter. This equation treats
capital (as a form of influence) is asymmetric, and it is clear that CL.L/Y chills as a constant 1 , CK.I/Y
compilation is divided as a parameter and a variable, 2 .I/Y. It is not clear from where error origin and
why it is treated as white noise.
We see the example, Wijeweera & Webb [21] examined the economic growth for Sri Lanka using
the Feder-Ram usage model [22], Atesoglu Model [23] and Halicioglu [24]. In the Feder-Ram model
the results showed t-statistics for each major coefficient (L and K) were positive, but not statistically
significant in the experiments included for military-controlled operations (M). Since wages are
insignificant it can not be censored whether or not pngelpangin positively affects economic growth in
Sri Lanka. Not only are the coefficients sttistically insignificant, but R 2 is also very low which means
that the model is not strong enough to get out of the economy. All this leaves doubt on the Feder-Ram
model to see the relationship between space and economic growth in the case of Sri Lanka.[21]
4. Conclusion
The Feder-Ram model of economic growth is very broad by people where its limitations are tried to be
overcome by various circles of economist.
Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel criticize by stating that there is no solid basis and econometric
reason for using this Feder-Ram model. As for the various simultaneous problems by creating a
growth rate of the same dimensions, when the combination of the military is constant, the net output
will determine the movement of the military. The multicolinearity between the two final forms yields a
large standard error and the estimated inaccuracy (not appropriate forecast) of the parameters of the
externalities. The model is static, there is no lagged regressors or dependent variables, which pose a
major problem in time-series in cross-section.[19]
The next model of Feder-Ram was developed by Mintz & Huang with some modifications. Mintz
& Huang, argued that the externality effect of the military and non-military sectors is different.
Therefore, the effects of externalities of the military public sector, the non-military public sector, and
the private sector are included in the production function separately.[25]
Acknowledgments
This research was conducted, thanks to simlibtamas research grant given by Ministry of Research,
Technology and Higher Education of Indonesia, Coordination of Private Higher Education Region III
(Kopertis III) in Fiscal Year 2018, Research Institutions and Community Service of Universitas
Kristen Indonesia (LPPM UKI) and Faculty of Economics and Business of Universitas Kristen
Indonesia.
References
[1] Cornes, Richard & Todd Sandler. (1986). The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club
Goods. Cambridge : Cambridge University Press.
[2] Heo, Uk. (1998) “Modeling The Defense-Growth Relationship Around The Globe”. Journal of
Conflict Resolution, Vol. 42 : 637-57.
[3] Ram, Rati. (1986) “Government Size and Economic Growth: A New Framework and some
Evidence from Cross-Section and Time-Series Data”, American Economic Review, Vol.76 (1) :
191-203.
[4] Biswas, B. & Ram, R. (1986). “Military Expenditures and Economic Growth in Less Developed
Countries: An Augmented Model and Further Evidence”, Economic Development and Cultural
Change, Vol. 34.
[5] Atesoglu, H. Sonmez & Mueller, J. Michael. (1990). “Defence Spending and Economic
Growth”, Defence Economics, Vol. 2(1) : 19-27.
5
WMA-Mathcomtech 2018 IOP Publishing
IOP Conf. Series: Journal of Physics: Conf. Series 1114 (2018)
1234567890 ‘’“” 012118 doi:10.1088/1742-6596/1114/1/012118
[6] Mintz, Alex & Huang, Chi. (1990) “Defence Expenditures, Economic Growth and the Peace
Dividend”, American Political Science Review, Vol. 84 (4) : 1283-1293.
[7] Mintz, Alex & Huang, Chi. (1991) “Guns versus Butter : The Indirect Link”. American Journal
of Political Science, Vol. 35 (3) : 738-57.
[8] Ward, M.D; Davis, D.R (1992) “Sizing up the Peace Dividend: Economic growth and military
spending in the US, 1948-1996”, American Political Science Review, Vol. 86 (3).
[9] Sandler, Todd. & Hertley, Keith. 1995. The Economics of Defence. Cambridge surveys of
Economic Literature, UK : Cambridge University Press.
[10] Solow, Robert M. (1970) Growth Theory : An Exposition. New York: Oxford University Press.
[11] Solow, Robert M. (1957) “A Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function”, Review
of Economics and Statistics, Vol.39 (3), pp. 312-320.
[12] Barro, R. J. & Sala-I-Martin, X. (1995). Economic Growth. New York : McGraw-Hill.
[13] Feder, Gershon. (1983) “On Exports and Economic Growth”, Journal of Development
Economics, Vol. 12 : 59-73.
[14] Heo, Uk. & Karl DeRouen Jr. (1998) “Military Expenditures, Technological Change, and
Economic Growth in The East Asian NICs”, Journal of Politics , Vol. 60 : 830-46.
[15] Antonakis, Nicholas. (1999) “Guns versus Butter: A Multi-Sectoral Approach to Military
Expenditures and Growth with Evidence from Greece, 1960-1993”, Journal of Conflict
Resolution, Vol. 43 (4) : 501-520.
[16] Denison, Edward F. 1985. Trends in American Economic Growth, 1929-1982. Washington, DC :
Brookings Institution.
[17] Deger, Saadet & Sen, S. (1983) “Military expenditures, Spin-off and Economic Development”,
Journal of Economic Development, Vol. 13.
[18] Mintz, Alex & Stevenson, R. (1995) “Defence Expenditures, Economic Growth and the Peace
Dividend” : A Longitudinal Analysis of 103 Countries”, The Journal of Conflict Resolution,
Vol.39 (2) : 283-305.
[19] Dunne, J.; Smith, Ron; Wellenbockel, Dirk. (2005) “Models of military expenditure and Growth:
A Critical Review”, Defence and Peace Economics, Vol.16 (6).
[20] Ward, M.D.; Davis, D.R. & Lofdahl, C.L. (1995) “A Century of Tradeoffs : Defense and Growth
in Japan and the United States”, International Study Quarterly, Vol. 39, No.1, pp. 27-50.
[21] Wijeweera, Albert; Webb, Matthew J. (2009). “Using the Feder-Ram and Military Keynesian
Models to Examine the Link between Defense Spending and Economic Growth in Sri Lanka”,
Defence and Peace Economic.
[22] Wilkins, Nigel. (2004). “Defence Expenditure and Economic Growth : Evidence from a Panel of
85 Countries”, School of Finance Economics Sydney.
[23] Atesoglu, H. Sonmez. (2002) “Defense Spending Promotes Aggregate Output in the United
States : Evidence from Cointegration Analysis”, Defense and Peace Economics, Vol. 13 (1) : 55-
60.
[24] Halicioglu, Ferda. (2004). “Defense Spending and Economic Growth in Turkey : An Empirical
Application of New Macroeconomic Theory”, Review of Middle East Economics and Finance,
Vol. 2 (3).
[25] Huang, C. & Mintz, A. (1991) “Defence Expenditures and Economic Growth: The Externality
Effect”, Defence Economics, Vol. 3 (11).