The E Ffects of Entrepreneurship Education: A, A, C B
The E Ffects of Entrepreneurship Education: A, A, C B
Abstract
Entrepreneurship education ranks high on policy agendas in Europe and the US, but little research is available to
assess its impact. To help close this gap we investigate whether entrepreneurship education affects intentions to
be entrepreneurial uniformly or whether it leads to greater sorting of students. The latter can reduce the average
intention to be entrepreneurial and yet be socially beneficial. This paper provides a model of learning in which
entrepreneurship education generates signals to students. Drawing on the signals, students evaluate their aptitude
for entrepreneurial tasks. The model is tested using data from a compulsory entrepreneurship course. Using ex ante
and ex post survey responses from students, we find that intentions to found decline somewhat although the course
has significant positive effects on students’ self-assessed entrepreneurial skills. The empirical analysis supports
the hypothesis that students receive informative signals and learn about their entrepreneurial aptitude. We outline
implications for educators and public policy.
JEL Classification: D83, J24, L26, M13
Keywords: entrepreneurship, entrepreneurship, education, Bayes’ Rule, learning, signals
I Acknowledgements: We would like to thank two anonymous referees for helpful comments. We also thank the participants of the 2009
SFB TR 15 Conference in Tutzing and the 2009 Max Planck Annual Summit Conference on Experimental Entrepreneurship for comments
and suggestions. Particular thanks go to Lotta Väänänen and Michael Fritsch for detailed suggestions for improvements. Dietmar Harhoff
and Georg von Graevenitz acknowledge the support of the SFB Transregio 15. The usual caveat applies.
∗ Corresponding author
Email addresses: [email protected] (Georg von Graevenitz ), [email protected] (Dietmar Harhoff), [email protected] (
Richard Weber)
1. Introduction
Policy-makers generally consider new venture formation to be instrumental for economic growth and techno-
logical progress. The academic literature is less unanimous. While many studies find positive effects (Reynolds
et al., 1994; Sheshinski et al., 2007; Audretsch and Fritsch, 2002), others caution that entrepreneurship in general
may not create growth in industrialized countries. However, many scholars concede that particular forms of en-
trepreneurship are associated with sizable positive effects (Sternberg and Wennekers, 2005; van Stel et al., 2005;
Wong et al., 2005; Acs and Szerb, 2007). There appears to be some agreement on the role of start-ups founded by
university graduates and faculty. Academic entrepreneurs are likely to employ more people than their non-academic
counterparts (Dietrich, 1999), and founders with university education apparently make higher investments in their
business than non-academic entrepreneurs (Reynolds et al., 1994). Moreover, their firms perform disproportionately
better (Shane, 2004). University spin-offs also create important spill-over effects for the regional economy (Harhoff,
1999; Shane, 2004). In awareness of these findings, some policy-makers declare the sensitization and advancement
of potential founders at tertiary educational institutions a primary goal of innovation policies. As a result, a wide
range of entrepreneurship education efforts have been initiated (Fayolle, 2000; Liñán, 2004; Kuratko, 2005).
The effects emanating from entrepreneurship education are still poorly understood. Several previous studies find
a positive impact of entrepreneurship education courses or programs at universities on perceived attractiveness and
feasibility of new venture initiation or even on actual startup activity (Tkachev and Kolvereid, 1999; Peterman and
Kennedy, 2003; Fayolle et al., 2006; Souitaris et al., 2007). Other studies find evidence that the effects are negative
(Oosterbeek et al., 2010). There may be methodological reasons why the literature has not generated consistent
assessments as of yet. While the studies provide intriguing results, many of them tend to have methodological
limitations. For example, few studies employ a pre-post design, and even fewer involve a control group. Most of the
studies focus on self-selected participants with some existing predisposition towards entrepreneurship which is likely
to bias results in favor of educational interventions (Gorman et al., 1997). But methodological weaknesses may not
be the only problem. Currently, there is also no agreement on what would constitute a suitable conceptual model for
the analysis of effects of entrepreneurship education. Most studies measure the impact of entrepreneurship education
merely by searching for uniform course-induced changes in entrepreneurial intentions. We argue that this approach
may be misleading because it masks important sorting effects which can be socially positive even if entrepreneurial
intentions decline as a consequence of entrepreneurship training.
Our paper seeks to make three contributions. First, we develop a new conceptual perspective which empha-
sizes learning and discovery of one’s own aptitude for entrepreneurship. In this view, entrepreneurship education
allows students to better assess whether they should pursue an entrepreneurial career. This view differs signifi-
cantly from the implicit notion that entrepreneurship education somehow enhances students’ willingness to become
entrepreneurs. We cast this new perspective in a formal model where learning follows Bayes’ Rule.1 Using this
1 Recent research by behavioral economists demonstrates that people do not always update their beliefs according to Bayes’ Rule (Rabin
and Schrag, 1999; Charness and Levin, 2005; Charness et al., 2007). However, the experiments undertaken by Charness et al. (2007)
demonstrate that Bayes’ Rule describes learning behavior better if subjects update their beliefs after interaction with people in larger
1
model of updating and learning, we show that if students differ in their aptitude for entrepreneurship and if en-
trepreneurship education helps them uncover these differences, entrepreneurship education may not always lead to
stronger entrepreneurial intentions on average. Thus, the new conceptual perspective allows us to develop a possible
explanation why the results in the literature have been somewhat contradictory.
As a second contribution, we study the effects of a large-scale compulsory entrepreneurship course at a ma-
jor German university, using a pre-test–post-test design. We explore whether students learned about their own
entrepreneurial aptitude from this course. A descriptive analysis of students’ intentions to become entrepreneurs
shows that the course induces sorting. Especially students who are initially uncertain about their entrepreneurial
aptitude are able to determine more clearly whether or not they are suited to entrepreneurship after the course. We
test three hypotheses derived from our model. The results confirm that learning about entrepreneurial aptitudes takes
place, and that it occurs as the model predicts. We can also show that while average measures of attitudes do not
change significantly, these attitudes do change at the individual level. These effects have not found any attention in
the extant literature.
In a third contribution we address the welfare implications of our results for future evaluation of entrepreneurship
education. Given our conceptual model and the empirical support provided by the data, we argue that a focus
on startup propensity alone is misleading. In order to come to a comprehensive assessment of entrepreneurship
education, the gains from improved matching between students and career paths need to be considered. Informing
non-entrepreneurial individuals that they are not well-suited for startup activities may be as valuable as confirming
and strengthening entrepreneurial tendencies in other students. We argue that this is not only the conceptually
appropriate approach, it is also ethically the right route to take.
The remainder of the paper contains six sections. Next, we review the literature on entrepreneurship education
and its impact on entrepreneurial activity. In Section 3, we discuss a formal model of learning based on Bayesian
updating. Section 4 describes the setting of our study and contains a descriptive analysis of the data. Section 5
provides an empirical test of the predictions from our model. Section 6 concludes and discusses future research.
2. Literature Review
Since much of the literature relates to the theory of entrepreneurship as intentional behavior (or variants of
that theory), we summarize this theory briefly. Intentionality is a state of mind directing a person’s attention (and
therefore experience and action) toward a specific object (goal) or a path in order to achieve something (means)
(Bird, 1988). Any planned behavior is best predicted by observing intentions toward that behavior, not by attitudes,
beliefs, personality or demographics (Bagozzi et al., 1989). Thus, according to the social psychology literature,
intentions are the single best predictor of planned behavior. This holds especially when the target behavior is rare,
hard to observe or when it involves unpredictable time lags (Ajzen, 1991). When the target behavior affords a person
2
complete control over behavioral performance, intentions alone should be sufficient to predict behavior, as explained
in the theory of planned behavior (Ajzen, 1991).
Intentions have been found to be an unbiased predictor of action, even where time lags exist, for example in
career choices (Lent et al., 1994). Hence, intentions predict behavior, while in turn certain specific attitudes predict
intention. Attitudes derive from exogenous influences (Ajzen, 1987). Thus, intentions are indirectly affected by
exogenous influences: either they drive attitudes or they moderate the relationship between intentions and behavior
(i.e. facilitate or inhibit the realization of intentions). And intentions serve as a mediator or catalyst for action:
intention-based models describe how exogenous influences change intentions and, in the end, actual behavior. This
is confirmed by meta-analytic studies (Kim and Hunter, 1993). Across a wide variety of target behaviors and related
intentions, attitudes explain over 50% of the variance in intentions, intentions in turn explain over 30% of the
variance in behavior. This compares to 10% usually explained by trait measures or attitudes alone (Ajzen, 1987).
Many researchers see entrepreneurship as a typical example of planned intentional behavior (Bird, 1988; Katz
and Gartner, 1988; Krueger and Brazeal, 1994). Having an entrepreneurial intention means that one is committed
to starting a new business (Krueger, 1993). The attitude towards entrepreneurship may be influenced by educational
measures. However, despite the recognition that education and prior entrepreneurial experiences may influence peo-
ple’s attitudes towards starting their own business, the impact of entrepreneurship education, as distinct from general
education, on intentions towards entrepreneurship has remained largely unexplored (Donckels, 1991; Krueger and
Brazeal, 1994).
Research about the effects of entrepreneurship education is still in its infancy (Gorman et al., 1997). Many
studies to date simply describe entrepreneurship courses (Vesper and Gartner, 1997), discuss the content of good
entrepreneurship education (Fiet, 2001) or evaluate the economic impact of courses by comparing takers and non-
takers (Chrisman, 1997). Some researchers have proposed a positive link between entrepreneurship education and
entrepreneurial attitudes, intention or action, but the evidence is still not strong (Gibb Dyer, 1994; Robinson et al.,
1991; Krueger and Brazeal, 1994).
Some empirical studies do confirm that there is a positive impact of entrepreneurship education courses or
programs at universities on perceived attractiveness and perceived feasibility of new venture initiation (Tkachev and
Kolvereid, 1999; Fayolle et al., 2006). Reviews of literature on enterprise and entrepreneurship education (Dainow,
1986; Gorman et al., 1997) and of particular entrepreneurship programs (McMullan et al., 2002) give evidence
that these programs encourage entrepreneurs to start a business. But usually, there are serious methodological
limitations. For example, studies rarely involve control groups or a form of stochastic matching (Block and Stumpf,
1992), basic controls as pre- and post-testing are not employed and most studies survey participants with an existing
predisposition towards entrepreneurship, biasing the results in favor of educational interventions (Gorman et al.,
1997).
The studies by Peterman and Kennedy (2003), Souitaris et al. (2007) and Oosterbeek et al. (2010) are three
3
remarkable exceptions, using pre-test-post-test control group designs. Peterman and Kennedy (2003) find that expo-
sure to enterprise education affected entrepreneurial intentions of high-school students. Students from 17 Australian
schools participated in this study, with 109 participants in the treatment and 111 students in the control group. Inter-
estingly, the authors detect a differential effect: participants with weak ex ante entrepreneurial propensities experi-
enced a stronger positive treatment effect than participants with strong ex ante entrepreneurial intentions. Souitaris
et al. (2007) find that sensitization through a semester-long (January-May) entrepreneurship program led to stronger
entrepreneurial intentions. The authors employed a pre-test-post-test control group-design and conducted their sur-
vey at two major European universities surveying science and engineering students. They received 124 matched
questionnaires from the program group and 126 from the control group. The students of the program group took
an entrepreneurship course as an elective module within their curriculum. Hence, the allocation of students to the
program group was not fully random, and different classes were taught by different academic instructors so that the
treatment might have differed across classes. Oosterbeek et al. (2010) study the impact of entrepreneurship educa-
tion in a compulsory course, using a difference-in-differences framework. Since students may have self-selected into
different school locations, location choice (and thus treatment) is instrumented. Their results show that the effect on
students’ self-assessed entrepreneurial skills is insignificant. Moreover, the effect of the course on entrepreneurial
intentions is significantly negative.
While this literature has generated interesting insights, the research on effects of entrepreneurship education
still has huge gaps. Unsurprisingly, several researchers have called for more research to answer the question if
entrepreneurship education can influence entrepreneurial perceptions and intentions (Donckels, 1991; Kantor, 1988;
Krueger and Brazeal, 1994; McMullan et al., 2002). Descriptive and retrospective studies are not sufficient to provide
convincing evidence for the presumed effects (Alberti, 1999; Gorman et al., 1997; Matthews and Moser, 1996).
Peterman and Kennedy (2003) call for the development of credible methods of testing preconceived hypotheses,
using large sample sizes and control groups, in order to move this young field of research beyond its exploratory
stage (Alberti, 1999).
Our paper is meant to contribute to this agenda. But we note a conceptual gap too - none of the studies discussed
here has attempted to investigate the nature of learning processes that occur in the course of entrepreneurship
education. Students are assumed to face no uncertainty regarding their own skills and interests, while the process
of learning itself is hardly modeled.2 This is where our study deviates from its predecessors. We explore the
possibility that students need to find out above all whether entrepreneurial activity suits them, i.e., whether they
have sufficiently high entrepreneurial aptitude to become entrepreneurs. Depending on what they learn students
may adjust their entrepreneurial intentions upwards or downwards.
2 Recent work on learning under certainty notes that this is generally true of the literature on skill formation in economics (Cunha et al.,
2006; Cunha and Heckman, 2007).
4
concepts and facts. We conceive of this component as reducing the cost of becoming an entrepreneur. However, the
skills and the knowledge taught will have generic components (e.g., knowing how to write a business plan is also
helpful in an established corporation). Therefore, such education may not shift entrepreneurial intentions by much.
Nonetheless, where entrepreneurship education also affects the attitudes and perceptions of students it may affect
entrepreneurial intentions, and thereby actions.
Finally and most importantly for our paper, entrepreneurship courses may allow students to engage in en-
trepreneurial activity in an experimental setting, e.g., by supporting founders of startups in their actual day-to-day
activities. This experience may also be emulated in the classroom, e.g. in startup simulations. We argue that
this latter component will be particularly valuable in helping students reduce uncertainty as to how suitable an en-
trepreneurial career is for them personally. The most important effect of entrepreneurship education may therefore
lie in students adjusting and refining their assessment of their own entrepreneurial aptitude.
This view implies that some students learn that entrepreneurial careers are not well-suited for them while the
educational measures lead other participants to come to a more positive assessment of their entrepreneurial aptitude.
This perspective is radically different from the one that has dominated the literature. In that view, students face
no uncertainty about their own type and therefore do not have to learn about their entrepreneurial aptitude. As a
consequence, an important aspect of entrepreneurship education may have been neglected.
In this section we discuss a formal model of learning about own aptitude for entrepreneurial tasks. The model
itself is set out in the appendix (Appendix A). Our starting point is the assertion that most students are unlikely to
be very certain about their aptitude for entrepreneurial tasks. We model learning about entrepreneurial aptitude as
a process of Bayesian updating of beliefs based on signals generated before and during an entrepreneurship course.
By generating these signals the course affects students’ discovery of their own aptitude for entrepreneurial tasks.
In the course of learning about entrepreneurship the student may receive conflicting signals and different students
will receive signals of different quality. Any course on entrepreneurship can therefore be expected to generate three
types of outcome: students who learn nothing and students who either learn and discover that they like or dislike
entrepreneurship.
In such a context it is interesting to characterize what effects an informative course on entrepreneurship will have
on the distribution of students’ beliefs about their own entrepreneurial aptitude. For instance a course that leaves the
average belief about entrepreneurial aptitude unchanged but leads to greater polarization of beliefs may be counted
a success, because it has more clearly separated those who are suited to entrepreneurship from those who are not.
Our principal interest here is in characterizing the distribution of students’ beliefs about own aptitude for en-
trepreneurial tasks. We show how informative signals about entrepreneurial ability generated before and by en-
trepreneurship education determine such beliefs, allowing students to learn their type.
In our surveys we elicited the strength of the signals that students have received. In other words we measure how
sure a student is that they either are or are not an entrepreneur. A weak signal is equivalent to a signal that leaves
5
the student unsure about their aptitude. This information allows us to test for learning by exploiting variation in the
strength of signals that students receive. The model we develop focuses on the consequences of such variation in
signal strength.
Below we provide three formal results that can be tested empirically:
I We show that students’ beliefs about their entrepreneurial aptitude display higher variance after a course, if
uncertainty about entrepreneurial aptitude is sufficiently high before the course and if the course provides
information.
II We show that any course which provides students with informative signals about entrepreneurial ability will
have two main effects: i) it will leave students who receive consistent signals before and during the course
with stronger beliefs about their entrepreneurial aptitude than students who do not receive consistent signals;
and ii) it will leave students with stronger pre course signals with stronger beliefs about their entrepreneurial
aptitude.
III We show that an informative entrepreneurship course will change the beliefs of participants less the stronger
the pre course signal, if signals are consistent and sufficiently precise.
While none of these predictions is particularly surprising the benefit of a formal model is to provide exact
conditions under which these seemingly obvious results obtain. We find below that these conditions matter for the
statistical tests we undertake.
The formal setup of the model is relegated to the appendix. For the purposes of what follows here the following
assumptions we make should be noted. We assume students are uncertain about their entrepreneurial aptitude but
know how this aptitude is distributed in the population around them. Their pre university life and an entrepreneurship
course at university provide students with two independent signals of their entrepreneurial ability.
For simplicity we distinguish just between entrepreneurs and employees. Being (truly) an entrepreneur means
that one’s own utility from being in an entrepreneurial function is greater than the utility from being in an employee
function. Conversely, we label employees all students who are better suited to non-entrepreneurial work. The label
“employee” is not intended to be pejorative. An important function of entrepreneurship education is to help students
self-select into activities which they are most suited to. Our model shows when this type of sorting is supported by
entrepreneurship education.
6
In the appendix we derive the expectation and the variance of students’ beliefs that they are entrepreneurs before
and after the course. A comparison of these variances shows that the variance of beliefs after the course is greater
than the variance of beliefs before, if the strength of the pre course signal is low and if the course generates an
informative signal.
A course that provides informative signals will raise the number of students who have learned something about
their aptitude for entrepreneurial tasks. If students also received informative signals before a course, then the signal
provided by the course will increase sorting of students into two groups that are increasingly sure that they are or are
not entrepreneurs. However, this will be less likely if students already know a lot about their entrepreneurial ability
or if the signal generated by the course is very noisy.
In Section 5 below we test the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 1
The variance of beliefs after the course is greater than the variance of beliefs before the course.
Now consider the effects of pre course signals on the post course beliefs of entrepreneurs and employees. Con-
sistency of signals will lead to stronger beliefs. Also, greater strength of signals received before the course will
make beliefs after the course stronger.
Proposition 2
If the two signals received by students are consistent, then beliefs after the course will be stronger, than if signals
are inconsistent.
Stronger pre course signals lead to stronger beliefs after the course.
We prove this Proposition in Appendix Appendix A.2. While this proposition may look trivial it is important to note
that beliefs after the course will also be stronger for those students who receive conflicting signals. The hypothesis
corresponding to Proposition 2 is:
Hypothesis 2
i) If signals are consistent then beliefs after the course are stronger.
ii) Stronger pre course signals lead to stronger beliefs after the course.
To test the hypothesis we regress a measure of strong pre course signals (S FPS ) and of consistent signals (CS )
on the variance of beliefs after the course ( B̄) around their mean. The dependent variable is defined such that stronger
beliefs increase the level of the dependent variable. It does not matter whether the belief that one is an entrepreneur
is close to one or close to zero. In both cases students have strong beliefs and in both cases the level of the dependent
variable is high.
Hypothesis 2 implies that the coefficients on the measure of extreme signals, the measure of consistent signals
and their interaction are all positive. Our empirical model is:
where B̄ ≡ (B[2] − µ(B[2]))2 captures the squared deviation of students’ beliefs after the course (B[2]) from the
mean, CS is a measure of consistent signals, S FPS is a measure of the strength of the pre course signal and CS X
7
is the interaction of the latter two variables. X represents a vector of control variables. Hypothesis 2 predicts that
β1 > 0, β2 > 0 and β3 > 0.
Proposition 3
If students receive sufficiently precise and reliable pre course signals then those who receive consistent signals will
change their beliefs less as pre course signals become stronger.
We prove this result in Appendix Appendix A.2. Proposition 3 is tested with the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 3
If students receive consistent signals, then those among them who have received stronger signals before the course
will change their beliefs less.
To test this hypothesis we regress the square of the change in beliefs due to the course on a measure of the
strength of pre course signals and of consistent signals. We predict a negative coefficient on the interaction of strong
and consistent signals. The dependent variable is squared, since our model makes predictions about the extent of a
change in beliefs, not about their direction.
The empirical model in this case is:
where 4̄ ≡ 42 captures the squared change in students’ beliefs. The remaining variables are defined as above.
Hypothesis 3 predicts that γ3 < 0.
Proposition 3 is weaker than Proposition 2. It relies on the additional assumption that the signaling process is
reliable. Additionally, it is weaker because our model predicts that in the counterfactual case in which students
receive inconsistent signals there are two groups with different reactions to more precise pre course signals. Our
model predicts that these two groups will be of equal size, in which case these reactions cancel out in aggregate. In
smaller populations we may see deviations from this prediction.
8
4. Data Description
Before we test the hypotheses introduced in the previous section, this section focuses on the data generated by
our surveys. First, we discuss data collection in the context of an entrepreneurship course. In particular, we focus
on the problem of sample selection. Next, we characterize the effects of the entrepreneurship course on students’
attitudes to entrepreneurship. It can be shown that the course we study is comparable in its effects to other courses
studied in the literature, e.g. Oosterbeek et al. (2010). Finally, we provide descriptive evidence consistent with the
hypothesis that these students learned about their entrepreneurial aptitude during the course.
The setting for data collection is the Department of Business Administration, in the Munich School of Man-
agement, at Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität (LMU) Munich, one of Germany’s largest universities. The Bachelor
curriculum at the Munich School of Management is somewhat untypical due to its obligatory entrepreneurship edu-
cation course ”Business Planning”. Every business administration student in the Bachelor of Science curriculum at
LMU has to enroll in this course in the third semester of their study program.
The objectives of the “Business Planning” course are threefold: i) to teach students basic capabilities needed
in the planning and management of a startup enterprise, in particular to convey the necessary knowledge and skills
for crafting a complete business plan; ii) to sensitize students for entrepreneurship according to the classification
by Liñán (2004): students are supposed to acquire knowledge about small enterprises, self-employment and en-
trepreneurship so that they can make rational career decisions; iii) to allow students to gain practical experience by
interaction with real-world entrepreneurs. The objectives of this course do not encompass any notion of convinc-
ing students to become entrepreneurs or to describe entrepreneurship as a particularly desirable option. While the
economic importance of entrepreneurship is clearly signaled, students are not meant to be indoctrinated.
The students we survey took the course between October 2008 and February 2009. They took part in eight
lectures conveying the principles of business planning. These lectures held by LMU faculty were augmented with
input from experts on financial planning, entrepreneurial marketing, experienced entrepreneurs and investors. Thus
students obtained first-hand insight into their businesses. The students also attended small group tutorials. In these
tutorials they practiced application of business planning concepts and developed their own business plan. Feedback
was given by fellow students, a teaching assistant and a tutor.
Students were surveyed (either using a written or an online survey) directly before the kickoff session of the
course and immediately before the time when the students received their grades at the end of the semester. The
survey instruments used had been reviewed by three academics and 12 non-participating students to ensure clarity
of wording and face validity of the constructs. Due to ethical concerns, we did not enforce participation in the
two surveys. The two survey instruments were largely identical. However, the second survey also contained items
used in the course evaluation.3 The survey forms were anonymized in both rounds, and matching was achieved by
9
employing a voluntary structured identification code.4
Participation in the Surveys and Possible Selection Biases. The setting of this course presents a particularly suitable
framework for our study since business studies students do not self-select into the “Business Planning” course.
Moreover, given that students interact with real-world entrepreneurs we believe that they receive informative and
important signals of their own ability as entrepreneurs.
While this setting allows us to eliminate the sample selection issues that affect most previous work on en-
trepreneurship education we cannot avoid sample selection due to self selection into business studies. Therefore,
it is desirable to repeat the survey we present here in entrepreneurship courses that include a more diverse set of
participants in the future.
We proceed to investigate whether the pattern of responses and non-responses to our survey suggests any ad-
ditional sources of sample selection bias. In total we received responses from 357 students. They represent 97.8
percent of total enrollment in the “Business Planning” course. 265 students participated in the first and 274 in the
second survey. For 196 students we were able to match two survey responses. While our research design has the
advantage that students cannot self-select into the course itself, we may still face selection issues due to differential
propensities to respond to our surveys.
A first indication that we do not face major (or possibly any) selection bias due to non-response can be taken
from Table 1. This provides demographic variables for three sets of respondents: those who only responded to the
first survey, those who responded to both surveys, and those who only responded to the ex post survey. Participants
to both surveys were significantly younger than those who responded to only one survey round. This may reflect
students’ behavior - older students are likely to feel more pressure to focus on their studies and may therefore be
less willing to ”waste” time on surveys. Moreover, students not participating in both surveys were more likely to
have self-employed parents (in the pre- and post-survey group) and had higher intentions to found (in the pre- and
post-survey group). However, it is important to note that while the intention to found declines significantly within
the group answering the survey ex ante and ex post, the intention to found is not significantly different, ex ante or ex
post, for those who only responded once and those who responded both times.
4 The code consisted of the first letter of the first name of the student’s mother, the last letter of the student’s name, the first digit of the
student’s month of birth, and the first letter of the student’s place of birth.
10
Given that we have some information about non-respondents for both of the two surveys, we can use a multi-
variate test to establish whether the likelihood of responding in the ex ante (ex post) survey is systematically related
to characteristics revealed in the second (first) data collection. We ran two probit regressions in which we predict
response behavior as a function of sex, age, religion, nationality and the employment status of parents and friends.
Additionally, we included scale variables for the students’ attitude towards entrepreneurship, the perceived social
norms in favor of entrepreneurship, the perceived entrepreneurial self-efficacy, and the perceived feasibility of a
startup project. Both probit regressions contained 11 regressors and were either largely or totally uninformative
(p=0.089, n=251 in the case of participation in the post-survey as a function of ex ante data, and p=0.267, n=263
in the case of ex ante participation as a function of data collected in the second round). The marginal explanatory
power in the ex post survey participation is due to non-German participants and students with self-employed par-
ents. The non-participation of these students is likely to introduce a conservative (if any) bias in our results.5 The
subsequent discussion focuses on the matched sample with ex ante and ex post information from 196 students.
Previous work on entrepreneurship education has shown that entrepreneurship courses may reduce the number
of students who intend to found (Oosterbeek et al., 2010). We confirm this finding here. The following section
provides an interesting perspective on it: entrepreneurship education helps students learn about their entrepreneurial
aptitude.
First we explore the impact of our entrepreneurship course. Table 2 summarizes evidence on ex ante and ex
post assessments of several classical attitudinal measures. First, we use a scale comprised of five items to measure
students’ attitude towards entrepreneurship.6 We test the scale using inter-item correlation. Scale reliability is
high for both surveys (Cronbach’s alpha=0.886 and 0.924 in the first and the second survey, respectively). To
5 The detailed results of these probit regressions are available upon request.
6 These items are taken from Gundry and Welsch (2001) and have been used in Kolvereid and Isaksen (2006).
11
maintain the scale’s information, we do not standardize the two measures. We also obtain a scale measure of risk
preference7 based on 6 items (Cronbach’s alpha 0.767 and 0.798), entrepreneurial self-efficacy8 based on 20 items
(Cronbach’s alpha 0.935 and 0.942), an assessment of the perceived feasibility9 of handling a startup project (six
items, Cronbach’s alpha 0.750 and 0.747) and finally a measure of perceived social norms.10 The latter is based on
four items asking for an assessment whether family members, friends, fellow students or other important persons
thought that the respondents ought to become entrepreneurs. These were transformed to yield a symmetric scale,
which was then multiplied by a weight obtained in a survey item in which respondents indicated to which extent they
cared about the particular opinion. This measure is best considered a formative variable since the social influence
of family members, friends, fellow students or other important persons may be additive.
Table 2 summarizes the mean values of these measures and their differences. Only the perceived feasibility of
handling a startup project displays a statistically significant change of about 7 percent of its ex ante value as a result
of the course.
An larger change is apparent in a confidence measure summarized in Table 3 below. Ex post, students agree
less to the statement ”I can always conclude my projects successfully” than ex ante, and the change is marginally
significant (p=0.087). The confrontation with a real-world problem may have led to an adjustment of assessments.
A large and significant improvement is apparent in the response to the statement ”I know everything that is needed
to start a new enterprise.” The ex ante average response to that statement was between ”do not agree” and ”rather
not agree” (mean value 2.50) and shifts to a mean value of 3.87 (between ”rather not agree” and ”neither agree nor
disagree”).
Moreover, the measure of general self-confidence has risen significantly, but much less than the response to the
entrepreneurship-specific question. We conclude from these answers that the course has had a significant positive
effect on students’ skills and self-confidence, and that it may have led to a reduced, and possibly more realistic
assessment of project success.
7 This scale is based on items first used in the 2004 wave of the Socio-economic Panel (SOEP) and employed by Dohmen et al. (2008) and
Caliendo et al. (2009).
8 This scale is based on 20 items derived from the work of Chen et al. (1998); De Noble et al. (1999); Anna et al. (2000). The items are used
together by Kolvereid and Isaksen (2006).
9 This scale is derived from Kolvereid (1996a) and subsequently used by Tkachev and Kolvereid (1999); Souitaris et al. (2007).
10 This measure is derived from Kolvereid (1996b) and has found use in Tkachev and Kolvereid (1999); Kolvereid and Isaksen (2006);
Souitaris et al. (2007).
12
In Appendix Appendix B we provide further evidence that shows that students gave a positive evaluation of
various aspects of the entrepreneurship course they took. We conclude from this evidence that students’ evaluation
of entrepreneurship is not the result of a poor course.
This final section shows that students’ entrepreneurial intentions have become more pronounced as a result of
the course. Entrepreneurial intentions were surveyed with two items in the questionnaires. First, we asked a direct
question ”Would you like to found your own enterprise at some point?” requesting a yes or no-response. Second,
we asked for an indication of agreement regarding the statement ”I intend to found my own enterprise within the
next five to ten years” with responses on a seven-point rating scale. The results are presented in Tables 4 below and
B.13 in Appendix Appendix B.
Table 4 provides results for the more detailed measure of entrepreneurial intentions. Consistent with the less detailed
measure, the average score (interpreting the scale as metric) has decreased from 4.08 to 3.89 (p=0.069 in a two-
tailed test, N=196). Additionally, the distribution itself is informative. The share of neutral responses declined from
19.4% to 13.3%. The neutral overall balance in the ex ante survey (40.4% vs. 40.2% with negative vs. positive
assessments) gave way to a slightly more negative result (44.4% vs. 42.3%). These changes are small, but they
indicate that the course helps students to develop more precise plans for their future. The number of students with
neutral assessments declines, opinions grow stronger.
This result is also apparent in Table 5 where we cross-tabulate a discrete measure of changes in entrepreneurial
intentions with ex ante intentions. The table shows that students with strong ex ante opinions were less likely to
change their intentions than indifferent students. Changes in intentions occur mostly amongst the undecided, as one
would expect in a world with Bayesian updating during the course.
13
Table 5: Changes in Entrepreneurial Intention by ex ante
Intention
I intend to start my own enterprise within the next five to ten years.
Change in ex post response
Change No change Total
strongly disagree 8 50.0% 8 50.0% 16
disagree 14 51.9% 13 48.1% 27
somewhat disagree 24 66.7% 12 33.3% 36
Ex ante neutral 27 71.1% 11 28.9% 38
response somewhat agree 15 51.7% 14 48.3% 29
agree 14 53.8% 12 46.2% 26
strongly agree 12 50.0% 12 50.0% 24
Total 114 58.2% 82 41.8% 196
Note: N=196. Responses from matched surveys of LMU students.
However, it would be misleading to believe that only the undecided learned something from the course. Table
6 provides evidence to this regard. In the upper panel of the table, we display which percentage of students who
indicate a particular level of entrepreneurial intentions have parents or friends who are self-employed. For example,
while only 12.5% of those who disagree strongly with the statement ”I intend to found my own enterprise within
the next five to ten years” have self-employed parents, the share of students with self-employed parents is 58.3%
for those in the highest response category. There is a clear bivariate relationship between parental self-employment
and students’ intentions. This is even more clearly visible once we condition parental self-employment on positive
experience. The relationship is less pronounced for self-employment of friends, but again clearer once one requires
self-employment to have been a positive experience.
Ex post statement: ”I intend to found my own enterprise within the next five to ten years.”
parent self- ... and positive friends self- ... and positive
Level of agreement employed experience employed experience N
strongly disagree 23.1% 15.4% 69.2% 46.2% 26
disagree 32.3% 29.0% 71.0% 51.6% 31
somewhat disagree 40.0% 36.7% 86.7% 70.0% 30
neutral 53.8% 34.6% 84.6% 73.1% 26
somewhat agree 29.4% 26.5% 76.5% 64.7% 34
agree 50.0% 46.7% 73.3% 66.7% 30
strongly agree 66.7% 66.7% 88.9% 88.9% 18
Total 40.5% 54.2% 77.9% 64.6% 195
Note: parental and friends’ self-employment is taken from the ex-ante survey in both panels.
Note: N=195. Responses from matched surveys of LMU students.
14
While these results are not surprising, the second panel of Table 6 shows how the course affected students’
intentions. Here we find that the share of students with self-employed parents or friends has become much higher in
the lower ex post response categories. The share of students with self-employed parents has almost doubled now in
the lower response category, and it has increased somewhat in the upper one. This shows that the course detached
some participants from their ex ante entrepreneurial intentions.
At the end of this section we are left with an interesting puzzle. The course has apparently reduced the en-
trepreneurial intentions of participating students.11 However, it has also led students to develop firmer future plans.
Students state that they feel more assured regarding the capabilities needed to found a new enterprise (see Table 3
and Table B.12). Moreover, we find interesting evidence that students reshape their intentions and opinions regard-
ing entrepreneurship during the course. ”Weak” opinions become more defined, and students become detached from
previous convictions as determined by parental background and former personal environment. We consider these
descriptive results to be important since they shed new light on the learning process itself. In the next section we
test the predictions of the theoretical model to see whether Bayesian updating provides an explanation of what we
observe.
In this section we test the learning model discussed in Section 3 above. We begin by presenting the variables
which enter our regressions. Then we present results of a differences of variances test and two regressions. We
provide evidence to support all three of our hypotheses.
Table 7 below sets out descriptive statistics. At the top of the table we present the dependent variables, below that
we present the explanatory variables. The statistics are presented for the sample of 189 students whose responses to
pre and post questionnaires we are able to match.
We elicit students’ beliefs about their own entrepreneurial aptitude by asking them about their intention to found
their own company. A set of questions related to the feasibility of founding a company is used to measure what
signals the students have received about their entrepreneurial aptitude before and during the course.
The dependent variables. We test Hypothesis 1 using detailed measures of students’ intentions to found an en-
terprise within the next five to ten years. We analyze the variance of the intention to found before and after the
course.
11 We have to sound a warning here - the sentiment of students regarding entrepreneurship may also have been affected by the financial crises
that began to impact the economy at the end of 2009 - exactly the time when students enrolled in this class.
15
Hypothesis 2 focuses on the strength of students’ beliefs that they are (are not) entrepreneurs after the course.
We take the squared deviation from the mean of students’ intentions to found after the course ( B̄) as our measure of
the strength of students’ beliefs after the course.12
Hypothesis 3 is based on the change in students’ intentions resulting from entrepreneurship education. The
dependent measure here is the squared change of intentions to found (4̄). Here the change refers to the difference
between intentions measured before and after the course.13
Note N = 189. Responses from matched surveys of LMU students responding to a full set of questions.
12 In unreported results we find that the precise definition of strong beliefs does not affect our findings. Regressions in which we take the
squared difference between students’ intentions and the median of the seven point Likert scale on which intentions to found were reported
are qualitatively similar to the results we report below.
13 This variable is clearly skewed. Regressions in which we use its logarithm as the dependent variable produce qualitatively identical results
to those reported below.
14 This variable is defined in Section 3.
15 This variable is defined in Section 3.
16
Signals and their strength. We measure the level of students’ pre course signals of their type using the questions on
students’ assessment of the feasibility of founding and running their own company. We construct a scale from six
questions on feasibility to capture the signals students receive before the course. The values of this scale lie on the
interval [1, 7] for each individual. As Table 7 shows the realized values are above 2.332.
The level of the signal students receive during the course is measured as the difference between two scales
aggregating ex-ante and ex-post responses to the feasibility questions. The values of this measure could lie on the
interval [−6, 6]. Table 7 shows the realized values are restricted to the interval [−2, 1.5].
The strength of signals is measured by comparing each individual signal to the point on each scale indicating
indecision between being an entrepreneur and not being an entrepreneur. In case of the ex ante signal indecision is
indicated by a value of 4 and in the case of the ex post signal by a value of 0, these being the median values of these
scales. We define the strength of each signal as the squared deviation from these points of indecision. The resulting
variables capture the strength but not the direction of a signal.16
Consistency of signals. We define a sequence of signals as consistent if signals received before and during the
course were both high or both low. More particularly we define signals as consistently high if the first signal is
above the median of the seven point Likert scale (i.e. > 4) and if the realization of the second signal is slightly above
the median (0) of the scale for that signal. We define the signal received during the course as high if its realization
is greater than 0.2. By choosing a value above the median of the signal received during the course we exclude those
students from being classified as having strong signals who do not have very strong beliefs of their entrepreneurial
ability after the course. On this definition just under one third of students in our sample received consistent signals.
Consistently weak signals of entrepreneurial ability are defined symmetrically to consistently strong signals.17
Control variables. We employ a number of control variables such as gender, nationality and confession as well the
scales for social norms regarding entrepreneurship, self efficacy and risk which were discussed previously.
Our model of learning shows that Bayesian updating has the effect that students’ beliefs about their entrepreneurial
aptitude will have greater variance if students receive an informative signal of their aptitude from the course and if
the first signal of entrepreneurial ability is not too strong. Table 8 sets out the standard deviations of students’ beliefs
about their entrepreneurial ability for the pre- and post-course samples. We provide these for the full set of students
who responded to at least one survey and for the restricted sample of students that took part in both surveys. We also
consider the latter sample excluding all those students whose pre course intentions to become entrepreneurs were in
a range indicating indecision (neutral or somewhat agree / disagree) and whose intentions had not changed after the
course. This indicates that these students did not receive sufficiently strong signals from the course or that they do
16 In a previous version of this paper we construct the strength measure relative to the mean of the empirical distribution of students’ signals.
It remains for future research to establish whether students’ beliefs are based on a relative assessment of their ability or on an absolute
standard. The results we present below indicate that for this group of students we can confirm our hypotheses based on relative or absolute
measures of signal strength.
17 We have found that our results are robust to slight alterations in the cutoff points for what constitutes a strong signal.
17
not update beliefs as predicted by Bayes’ Rule. Finally, we show results when we also exclude those students who
received very strong signals before the course.
Table 8 shows that the variance of beliefs about entrepreneurial ability increases in all four samples: beliefs
after entrepreneurship education have greater variance than beliefs before. However, we are unable to reject the
hypothesis that the variances are statistically identical in the first three samples. The fourth sample excludes students
who do not update at all and students who received strong signals before the course. Here we find a statistically
significant increase in the variance of beliefs, once we allow for non-normality of the distributions by using Levene’s
robust test or Brown and Forsythe’s median test.
This result shows that the formal model provides important conditions for the test - that we exclude those students
who have strong pre course signals and those who have not received sufficiently strong signals during the course.
Note that this condition significantly reduces the size of the sample which makes it harder to obtain a statistically
significant result. We conclude that our results confirm Hypothesis 1.
Table 9 below sets out results from regressions performed to test Hypothesis 2. Note that the dependent variable
in this regression is a continuous variable, so that we use OLS. There are 189 observations as we do not have
responses on all questions contained in the feasibility scale from all those students who took part in the first and
second round surveys. We set out four regressions. The first contains only control variables and shows that none of
these is able to explain the strength of students’ intentions to become entrepreneurs or to avoid entre-
18
Table 9: Regressions for Strength of Intentions after the Course
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Dependent Variable: B̄ B̄ B̄ B̄
Strength of signals 0.509** 0.541* 0.567**
before (0.246) (0.277) (0.273)
Consistent signals 1.949*** 1.995*** 2.043***
(0.546) (0.575) (0.564)
Consistent and strong 1.475*** 1.442*** 1.317**
signals (0.518) (0.535) (0.524)
Strength of signals -0.107 0.025
afterwards (0.414) (0.398)
non - German 0.343 0.536 0.523
(0.660) (0.599) (0.602)
Female -0.031 0.166 0.166
(0.533) (0.480) (0.481)
Protestant 0.699 0.667 0.669 0.493
(0.600) (0.539) (0.540) (0.526)
Parents self-employed 0.264 0.252 0.267
(0.520) (0.468) (0.473)
Friends self-employed -0.351 -0.495 -0.495
(0.613) (0.553) (0.555)
Scale: feasibility -0.497 -1.270*** -1.296*** -1.049***
assessment before (0.461) (0.449) (0.461) (0.324)
Scale: feasibility -0.123 -0.517 -0.508 -0.214
assessment afterwards (0.450) (0.418) (0.421) (0.367)
Scale: entrepreneurial 0.294 0.284 0.293
self efficacy (0.250) (0.225) (0.228)
Scale: risk preference -0.301* -0.222 -0.227
(0.177) (0.161) (0.162)
Perceived social norm 0.003 0.007 0.007
(0.011) (0.010) (0.010)
Constant 5.244*** 7.026*** 7.107*** 6.683***
(1.943) (1.815) (1.846) (1.316)
Adjusted R-squared -0.016 0.181 0.176 0.184
N 189 189 189 189
Standard errors are shown in parentheses: ∗∗∗ (∗∗ , ∗ ) denotes a 1% (5%,10%) level of significance.
preneurship after the course. This is interesting because several of these variables do provide information about the
level of students’ intentions before and after the course.18
Next we include the three measures suggested by Hypothesis 2: a measure of the strength of pre course beliefs,
a measure of consistent beliefs and the interaction of these two measures. Our results show that all three measures
have positive sign and are generally significant at the 1% and 5% levels. In the regressions reported in columns
2 and 3 of Table 9 we use the same large set of control variables as in column 1. We find that apart from the
feasibility assessment scale non of these variables is significant. In the regression reported in column 4 we drop all
those controls that are insignificant above the 20% level. We arrived at the specification reported there by iteratively
removing the least significant controls one by one. While the adjusted R-squared measure of this last regression is
highest we find that the coefficients estimated are not much affected by the procedure. We conclude that the effects
we identify are robust.
18 We do not report regressions on the intentions ex ante and ex post here as our model makes no predictions about these. The regressions are
available from the authors upon request.
19
These results indicate that the strength and consistency of students’ signals affect intentions to become en-
trepreneurs as predicted by Hypothesis 2.
Here we investigate how students who have received consistent signals and who have a stronger pre course signal
adjust their beliefs during the course.
Table 10 shows that we are unable to reject Hypothesis 3. The table provides coefficients of four ordered probit
regressions.19 In column (1) we regress the main variables of interest on the dependent variable. We find that the
strength of signals received during the course significantly affects changes in intentions as does the interaction of
consistent and strong pre course signals. The interaction term has the sign predicted in Proposition 3. In column (2)
we introduce a large set of control variables. This does not affect the significance of the main variable of interest,
nor is the coefficient significantly altered. Columns (3) and (4) provides the starting point and the results of testing
down, iteratively removing the least significant regressors. Once more this has no significant effect on the signs or
coefficients of the interaction effect.
19 As noted above the dependent variable here is defined as the square of the change in intentions to found. this variable has seven discrete
values, so that we use ordered probit here.
20
We also calculate the average marginal effects (AME) for the interaction term (Bartus, 2005; Cameron and
Trivedi, 2005). Table 11 below provides these estimates for the models reported in columns (1) and (4) of Table 10
above. We find that the marginal effect is generally highly significant and negative for all groups of students who
change their beliefs.
As a further robustness check we investigate whether the boundedness of the dependent variable affects our
findings. In particular one may wonder whether students who already have an extreme signal of their entrepreneurial
ability before the course will find their initial belief confirmed and further strengthened. Our scale would not allow
them to indicate if this were the case. To test this we predict students’ second stage beliefs using ordered probit
and adjust those students’ beliefs for whom even more extreme beliefs are predicted. We then rerun the regressions
reported above. We find that our results are robust to this test.20
These findings indicate that the strength and consistency of signals students receive affect changes in students’
intentions to become entrepreneurs as predicted by Hypothesis 3.
6. Conclusion
This paper provides an analysis of learning processes in entrepreneurship education. While entrepreneurship
education has been introduced and promoted in many countries and at many institutions of tertiary education, little
is known at this point about the effect of these courses. In particular, it is largely unknown how the courses impact
students’ willingness to engage in entrepreneurial activity and what kind of learning processes are responsible for
these effects. Instead, the literature has focused on a simplified ”up and down” analysis which studies outcomes, but
does not consider the causes or the path of learning.
21
In the context of funding of entrepreneurial ventures it has been argued that subsidizing finance for new en-
trepreneurs could be socially wasteful (De Meza and Southey, 1996; De Meza, 2002; Shane, 2009). By analogy,
one might expect that entrepreneurship education could have negative effects if it succeeded in convincing those not
suited to entrepreneurship that they should become entrepreneurs. Alternatively, and more positively, it could be
that such education actually informs students and allows them to discover their specific abilities. In this case, even
a decline in entrepreneurial intentions could be socially valuable, since it may indicate that subsequent matches in
the labor market will be improved.
In this paper we analyze the effects of entrepreneurship education on a group of students who are not selected
for their interest in entrepreneurship. We postulate that student behavior is largely driven by Bayesian updating
- students enter entrepreneurship courses with prior beliefs about their own ”type”, but update their beliefs in the
course of entrepreneurship training. Based on a theoretical model we derived three hypotheses that link ex post
intentions as well as changes in intentions to the strength and consistency of signals received by students prior
to and during the entrepreneurship course. Data were collected in a compulsory entrepreneurship class at a large
German university.
In a descriptive analysis, we find evidence that students update their beliefs about their entrepreneurial aptitude.
In particular, initially undecided students are most likely to change their beliefs most readily. More formally we
show that the variance of beliefs about entrepreneurial aptitude increased significantly during the course if we focus
on students who learn during the course. Two further hypotheses derived from our model cannot be rejected either.
We show that strong ex ante beliefs and consistency of signals lead to stronger ex post intentions to found or not
to found, and that changes in intentions due to the course tend to be smaller if ex ante signals are strong and if the
signals received by students are consistent.
A number of caveats apply. The current study does not employ data from a control group.21 Hence, we cannot
exclude the possibility that students updated their beliefs based on information that was extraneous to the course.
We consider this unlikely, since the course contents were very specific and not duplicated in other courses. Nor do
we know if particular content characteristics of this course have led to the described outcomes.
In our overall assessment, the results can be read as confirmation for educational policies that view entrepreneur-
ship training as a way of informing students about career options, and of creating learning opportunities for cali-
brating and refining their assessments of which career is most suitable. We have no means to assess how costly
the mistakes of choosing the ”wrong” career would be to the students and to society at large. Hence, we cannot
quantify the true economic and societal impact of entrepreneurship training. But it seems worthwhile to consider
that a simple increase in entrepreneurial activity may neither be a good objective, nor the most likely outcome for
including entrepreneurship in the curriculum.
Our results also have implications for public policy, and in particular for the evaluation of entrepreneurship
21 In addition to the data collection for the course studied, we also obtained data on a small sample of students at another Munich university.
However, with 44 observations the sample is too small for setting up a fully developed pre-post control group design. Entrepreneurial
intentions declined in the control group as well and more strongly than in our treatment group.
22
education. Currently, evaluation is based on estimating positive outcomes (increases in the actual or anticipated
startup rate) and trading that benefit off against program costs. In our view this approach misses the sorting benefits
highlighted in our paper. Consider a student who has learned that she would probably not be a good entrepreneur
or would not enjoy being an entrepreneur. Rather than performing a possibly very costly real-world experiment of
starting a firm and failing at the task, this student may now decide to enter a managerial career. This should be
considered to be a positive outcome of entrepreneurship education, while most of the current literature (and many
policy-makers) would proclaim it a case of failure. We believe that this kind of welfare accounting needs to be
rethought.
The framework we outline in this paper opens up several avenues for future work. First and foremost we intend
to further test our theoretical framework. We intend to reapply the framework to other entrepreneurship courses and
seek to establish whether the framework also describes effects of other types of education, which are intended to
help students discover their proclivity for a specific type of work. Secondly, an integration of the framework with
the theory of planned behaviour is likely to be helpful in further identifying exactly which benefits and costs that
entrepreneurship education can affect. Finally, the integration of uncertainty into models of skill formation over the
life cycle (Cunha et al., 2006; Cunha and Heckman, 2007) holds out the promise of a theory of learning about own
aptitude.
Acs, Z., Szerb, L., 2007. Entrepreneurship, economic growth and public policy. Small Business Economics 28,
109–122.
Ajzen, I., 1987. Attitudes, traits, and actions: dispositional prediction of behavior in personality and social psychol-
ogy. Advances in experimental social psychology 20, 1–63.
Ajzen, I., 1991. The theory of planned behavior. Organizational behavior and human decision processes 50, 179–
211.
Alberti, F., 1999. Entrepreneurship education: scope and theory, in: Salvato, C., Davidsson, P., Persson, A. (Eds.),
Entrepreneurial Knowledge and Learning: Conceptual Advances and Directions for Future Research, Jönköping
International Business School, Jönköping. pp. 64–84.
Anna, A., Chandler, G., Jansen, E., Mero, N., 2000. Women business owners in traditional and non-traditional
industries. Journal of Business Venturing 15, 279–303.
Audretsch, D., Fritsch, M., 2002. Growth regimes over time and space. Regional Studies 36, 113–124.
Bagozzi, R., Baumgartner, J., Yi, Y., 1989. An investigation into the role of intentions as mediators of the attitude-
behavior relationship. Journal of Economic Psychology 10, 35–62.
Bartus, T., 2005. Estimation of marginal effects using margeff. Stata Journal 5, 309–329.
Bird, B., 1988. Implementing entrepreneurial ideas: the case for intention. Academy of Management Review 13,
442–453.
23
Block, Z., Stumpf, S., 1992. Entrepreneurship education research: experience and challenge, in: Sexton, D.L.,
Kasarda, J.M. (Eds.), The State of the Art of Entrepreneurship, PWS-Kent, Boston, MA. pp. 17–42.
Caliendo, M., Fossen, F., Kritikos, A., 2009. Risk attitudes of nascent entrepreneurs – new evidence from an
experimentally validated survey. Small Business Economics 32, 153–167.
Cameron, A., Trivedi, P., 2005. Microeconometrics: methods and applications. Cambridge University Press.
Charness, G., Karni, E., Levin, D., 2007. Individual and group decision making under risk: an experimental study
of Bayesian updating and violations of first-order stochastic dominance. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 35,
129–148.
Charness, G., Levin, D., 2005. When optimal choices feel wrong: a laboratory study of Bayesian updating, com-
plexity, and affect. The American Economic Review 95, 1300–1309.
Chen, C., Greene, P., Crick, A., 1998. Does entrepreneurial self-efficacy distinguish entrepreneurs from managers?
Journal of Business Venturing 13, 295–316.
Chrisman, J., 1997. Program evaluation and the venture development program at the University of Calgary: a
research note. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 22, 59–74.
Cunha, F., Heckman, J., 2007. The technology of skill formation. American Economic Review 97, 31–47.
Cunha, F., Heckman, J., Lochner, L., Masterov, D., 2006. Interpreting the evidence on life cycle skill formation.
Handbook of the Economics of Education 1, 697–812.
Dainow, R., 1986. Training and education of entrepreneurs: the current state of the literature. Journal of Small
Business 3, 10–24.
De Meza, D., Southey, C., 1996. The borrower’s curse: optimism, finance and entrepreneurship. The Economic
Journal 106, 375–386.
De Noble, A., Jung, D., Ehrlich, S., 1999. Entrepreneurial self-efficacy: The development of a measure and its
relationship to entrepreneurial action. Frontiers of entrepreneurship research , 73–87.
Dietrich, H., 1999. Empirische Befunde zur selbständigen Erwerbstätigkeit unter besonderer Berücksichtigung
scheinselbständiger Erwerbsverhältnisse. Mitteilungen aus der Arbeitsmarkt-und Berufsforschung 32, 85–101.
Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., Sunde, U., Schupp, J., Wagner, G., 2008. Individual risk attitudes: new evidence
from a large, representative, experimentally-validated survey. Discussion Paper 511. DIW Berlin.
Donckels, R., 1991. Education and entrepreneurship experiences from secondary and university education in Bel-
gium. Journal of Small Business 9, 35–42.
24
Fayolle, A., 2000. Exploratory study to assess the effects of entrepreneurship programs on french student en-
trepreneurial behaviors. Journal of Enterprising Culture 8, 169–184.
Fayolle, A., Gailly, B., Lassas-Clerc, N., 2006. Assessing the impact of entrepreneurship education programmes: a
new methodology. Journal of European Industrial Training 30, 701–720.
Fiet, J., 2001. The theoretical side of teaching entrepreneurship. Journal of Business Venturing 16, 1–24.
Gibb Dyer, W., 1994. Toward a theory of entrepreneurial careers. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 19, 7–21.
Gorman, G., Hanlon, D., King, W., 1997. Some research perspectives on entrepreneurship education, enterprise ed-
ucation and education for small business management: a ten-year literature review. International Small Business
Journal 15, 56–77.
Gundry, L., Welsch, H., 2001. The ambitious entrepreneur: High growth strategies of women-owned enterprises.
Journal of Business Venturing 16, 453–470.
Harhoff, D., 1999. Firm formation and regional spillovers-evidence from germany. Economics of Innovation and
New Technology 8, 27–55.
Kantor, J., 1988. Can entrepreneurship be taught?–a Canadian experiment. Journal of Small Business and En-
trepreneurship 5, 12–19.
Katz, J., Gartner, W., 1988. Properties of emerging organizations. Academy of Management Review 13, 429–441.
Kim, M., Hunter, J., 1993. Relationships among attitudes, behavioral intentions, and behavior: a meta-analysis of
past research, part 2. Communication Research 20, 331–364.
Kolvereid, L., 1996a. Organizational employment versus self-employment: reasons for career choice intentions.
Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice 20, 23–31.
Kolvereid, L., 1996b. Prediction of employment status choice intentions. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice
21, 47–57.
Kolvereid, L., Isaksen, E., 2006. New business start-up and subsequent entry into self-employment. Journal of
Business Venturing 21, 866–885.
Krueger, N., 1993. The impact of prior entrepreneurial exposure on perceptions of new venture feasibility and
desirability. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice 18, 5–21.
Krueger, N., Brazeal, D., 1994. Entrepreneurial potential and potential entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurship: Theory
and Practice 18, 91–104.
Kuratko, D.F., 2005. The emergence of entrepreneurship education: Development, trends, and challenges. En-
trepreneurship Theory and Practice 29, 577–597.
25
Lent, R., Brown, S., Hackett, G., 1994. Toward a unifying social cognitive theory of career and academic interest,
choice, and performance. Journal of Vocational Behavior 45, 79–122.
Liñán, F., 2004. Intention-based models of entrepreneurship education. Piccolla Impresa / Small Business 3, 11–35.
Matthews, C., Moser, S., 1996. A longitudinal investigation of the impact of family background and gender on
interest in small firm ownership. Journal of Small Business Management 34, 29–43.
McMullan, W., Chrisman, J., Vesper, K., 2002. Lessons from successful innovations in entrepreneurial support pro-
gramming, in: Chrisman, J., Holbrook, J., Chua, J. (Eds.), Innovation and Entrepreneurship in Western Canada:
From Family Businesses to Multinationals, University of Calgary, Calgary, Alberta. pp. 207–223.
Oosterbeek, H., van Praag, M., Ijsselstein, A., 2010. The impact of entrepreneurship education on entrepreneurship
skills and motivation. European Economic Review 54, 442–454.
Peterman, N., Kennedy, J., 2003. Enterprise education: influencing students’ perceptions of entrepreneurship.
Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 28, 129–144.
Rabin, M., Schrag, J., 1999. First impressions matter: a model of confirmatory bias. Quarterly Journal of Economics
114, 37–82.
Reynolds, P., Storey, D., Westhead, P., 1994. Cross-national comparisons of the variation in new firm formation
rates. Regional Studies 28, 443–456.
Robinson, P., Stimpson, D., Huefner, J., Hunt, H., 1991. An attitude approach to the prediction of entrepreneurship.
Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 15, 13–31.
Shane, S., 2004. Academic Entrepreneurship: University Spinoffs and Wealth Creation. Edward Elgar Publishing,
Cheltenham, U.K.
Shane, S., 2009. Why encouraging more people to become entrepreneurs is bad public policy. Small Business
Economics 33, 141–149.
Sheshinski, E., Strom, R., Baumol, W., 2007. Entrepreneurship, Innovation, and the Growth Mechanism of the
Free-enterprise Economies. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Souitaris, V., Zerbinati, S., Al-Laham, A., 2007. Do entrepreneurship programmes raise entrepreneurial intention of
science and engineering students? The effect of learning, inspiration and resources. Journal of Business Venturing
22, 566–591.
van Stel, A., Carree, M., Thurik, R., 2005. The effect of entrepreneurial activity on national economic growth. Small
Business Economics 24, 311–321.
Sternberg, R., Wennekers, S., 2005. Determinants and effects of new business creation using global entrepreneurship
monitor data. Small Business Economics 24, 193–203.
26
Tkachev, A., Kolvereid, L., 1999. Self-employment intentions among Russian students. Entrepreneurship & Re-
gional Development 11, 269–280.
Vesper, K., Gartner, W., 1997. Measuring progress in entrepreneurship education. Journal of Business Venturing
12, 403–421.
Wong, P., Ho, Y., Autio, E., 2005. Entrepreneurship, innovation and economic growth: Evidence from GEM data.
Small Business Economics 24, 335–350.
27
Appendix A. A Model of Learning About Own Entrepreneurial Ability
This appendix provides the analytical results from which we derive the hypotheses provided in Section 3 above.
The appendix consists of two sections: the first sets out our assumptions and definitions, the second contains proofs
of Propositions 1- 3.
We assume that there are two types of student: entrepreneurs (n) and employees (m). Students know that these
two types exist and have information about the proportion of entrepreneurs in the population φ, but they do not know
their own type.
In our model students receive information about their ability as entrepreneurs and as employees in two successive
periods: periods one and two. Period one takes place before students go to university. Here students receive a signal
σ1 of their entrepreneurial ability. Period two takes place once students go to university. Here students receive a
signal σ2 of entrepreneurial ability from formal entrepreneurship education. We distinguish between signals that
entrepreneurs (σn ) and employees (σm ) receive about entrepreneurial ability.
Students’ beliefs about their own entrepreneurial ability are distributed on the interval [0, 1]. A belief of 0
implies that the student believes absolutely that they are an employee, a belief of 1 implies that they believe they are
certainly an entrepreneur. Each type of student will receive a positive signal of high entrepreneurial aptitude in each
period with probability ψk where ψ ∈ [0, 1] and k ∈ {n, m}. Define the precision of these positive signals as ςi where
i ∈ {1, 2}.
We make a number of assumptions about the signals that students receive:
b) Further, we assume that the signaling process is informative - call this Assumption (I).22 This assumption has
three components:
ψm
(i) 1 ≥ ψn > ψm ≥ 0 (ii) 1 ≥ ςi > .
ψm + ψn
Part (i) implies that the probability that an entrepreneur-type receives a positive signal that they are an en-
trepreneur is greater than the probability that an employee-type receives such a signal. Part (ii) implies that
signals always contain some information. Now define the strength of signals of entrepreneurial aptitude that
a student receives as:
(iii) σni ≡ ψn · ςi σm
i ≡ ψ · (1 − ςi )
m
ψm
Then signals will be informative (σni > σm
i ) if ςi > ψm +ψn .
c) Finally, we assume that students update their beliefs about their own type according to Bayes’ Rule.
22 We would like to thank Lotta Väänänen for her comments regarding this part of the model.
28
Assumption (I) implies that the belief of an entrepreneur-type student that she is an entrepreneur will not decline
if she receives a positive signal of entrepreneurial aptitude (σni ).
Note that greater precision of signals simultaneously improves the strength of the signal of entrepreneurial
aptitude received by an entrepreneur-type and reduces the strength of this signal as received by the employee-type.
This means that students receiving the correct signal about their type will revise their beliefs more as the precision
of the signal increases.23
Definitions
Initially students only know that a proportion φ of people in the population around them are entrepreneurs.
Hence their prior of the probability that they are an entrepreneur is φ. Then, in the course of their pre university life
they receive the first signal about their own entrepreneurial ability. This signal will generally differ depending on
their type.
Beliefs after Period One. By Bayes’ rule the strength of the beliefs of entrepreneurs that they are entrepreneurs after
period one is:
σn1 φ 1 − σn1 φ
Bnn ≡ n and Bnm ≡ , (A.1)
σ1 φ + σm (1 − φ)
1 1 − σn1 φ + 1 − σm 1
(1 − φ)
where Bnn is the strength of the pre course belief of an entrepreneur n that they are an entrepreneur n if they receive a
positive signal, while Bnm is the strength of the entrepreneur’s pre course belief that they are an entrepreneur if they
receive a negative signal. The expressions in (A.1) show that the first period signal divides the group of entrepreneurs
into two sets, one of which believes more firmly that they are entrepreneurs (Bnn ) and one of whom no longer believes
very strongly that they are entrepreneurs (Bnm ).
Given these definitions the strength of the beliefs of the employees that they are employees after period one can
be expressed as:
Bm n
n ≡ 1 − Bn and Bm n
m ≡ 1 − Bm . (A.2)
Beliefs after Period Two. Applying Bayes’ rule once more the strength of beliefs of the entrepreneurs that they are
entrepreneurs after period two is given by:
where Bnn|n is the strength of the entrepreneur-type student’s belief that she is an entrepreneur after receiving a second
period signal that she is an entrepreneur and a pre course signal that she is an entrepreneur (n|n ). Bnm|n is the student’s
23 This corresponds to a simultaneous increase in the sensitivity and specificity of the signals.
29
second period belief that she is an entrepreneur if she received a second period signal that she is an employee and a
pre course signal that she is an entrepreneur (n|n ) given that she is an entrepreneur (n ).
After period two there are four groups of students each with a distinct level of belief about their entrepreneurial
ability. These beliefs are a function of the history of signals that students have received. Two groups of students
have received signals going in the same direction and they now have the strongest (Bnn|n ) and the weakest (Bnm|m )
beliefs that they are entrepreneurs. In contrast the other two groups have received countervailing signals. These
groups revise their belief about being entrepreneurs upwards (Bnn|m ) and downwards (Bnm|n ) after period two.
Analogously there are four groups of employees with different levels of beliefs that they are employees after
period two:
n|n = 1 − Bn|n
Bm n|m = 1 − Bn|m m|n = 1 − Bm|n and m|m = 1 − Bm|m .
n
, Bm n
, Bm n
Bm n
There are those employees who are truly employee-types and have received a series of consistent signals, leading
them to believe quite strongly that they are employees (Bm m
m|m ) or quite strongly that they are not (Bn|n ). Also, those
employees who receive inconsistent signals will revise their beliefs that they are entrepreneurs upwards (Bm
n|m ) and
downwards (Bm
m|n ).
Proof of Proposition 1
To complete the proof we derive the expectations of first and second period beliefs. Then we derive the variances
of first and second stage beliefs. Finally, we derive conditions under which the variance of second stage beliefs
exceeds that of first stage beliefs.
µ1 = Bnn − Bnm φψn + ψm (1 − φ) + Bnm . (A.5)
We define λ ≡ φψn + ψm (1 − φ) to simplify calculations further below. Note that it must be true that 1 ≥ λ ≥ 0.
Now we reexpress the expectation of first stage beliefs as:
The Variance of First Period Beliefs. Given the definition of the expectation of first stage beliefs the variance of
first stage beliefs may be written as:
V1 = λ Bnn − µ1 + (1 − λ) Bnm − µ1 .
2 2
(A.7)
30
Substituting out the expectation and simplifying we obtain:
h i
µ2 = Bnn|n φ(ψn )2 + (1 − φ)(ψm )2 + Bnn|m + Bnm|n φ(1 − ψn )ψn + (1 − φ)ψm (1 − ψm )
+ Bnm|m φ(1 − ψn )2 + (1 − φ)(1 − ψm )2 , (A.9)
h i
µ2 = Bnn|n + Bnm|m − Bnm|n + Bnn|m Λ − λ + Bnn|n λ + Bnm|m (1 − λ) . (A.11)
To simplify further calculations we define R ≡ Bnn|n + Bnm|m − Bnm|n + Bnn|m and S ≡ Bnn|n − Bnm|m . Then we can
h i
express the expectation of second stage beliefs as: µ2 = R Λ − λ + S λ + Bnm|m .
2 2 2 2
V2 = Bnn|m − µ2 + Bnm|n − µ2 − Bnn|n − µ2 + Bnm|m − µ2 [λ − Λ]
2 2
+ Bnn|n − µ2 λ + Bnm|m − µ2 [1 − λ] (A.12)
" h i 2 h i 2 #
− R λ − Λ + S (1 − λ) + R λ − Λ − S λ [λ − Λ]
h i2
+ R2 λ − Λ + S 2 (1 − λ) λ (A.13)
h i
Defining Z ≡ R λ − Λ − S λ this may be further simplified to:
" 2 2 #
V2 = Z + (Bn|m − Bm|m ) + Z + (Bm|n − Bm|m ) − (Z + S ) − Z [λ − Λ]
n n n n 2 2
h i2
+ R2 λ − Λ + S 2 (1 − λ) λ (A.14)
" 2 2 # h i2
= Bnn|m − Bnm|m + Bnm|n − Bnm|m − S 2 − 2ZR [λ − Λ] + R2 λ − Λ + S 2 (1 − λ) λ
31
" 2 2 #
= Bnn|m − Bnm|m + Bnm|n − Bnm|m + R Λ + Rλ(2S − R) [λ − Λ] + S 2 Λ − λ2
2
The Difference of First and Second Period Variance of Beliefs. Here we show that the variance of second stage
beliefs (V2 ) is greater than the variance of first stage beliefs (V1 ).
Note that:
Z
"z 2
}|
2
{
#
n 2
V2 − V1 = Bn|m − Bm|m + Bm|n − Bm|m − Bn − Bm + R Λ + Rλ 2S − R [λ − Λ]
n n n n n 2
" #
n 2
+ S − Bn − Bm
2 n
Λ − λ2 . (A.15)
Given that S = Bnn|n − Bnm|m it is easily shown that S = (Bnn|n − Bnn ) + (Bnn − Bnm ) + (Bnm − Bnm|m ). Each of the differences
in this sum is non-negative if Assumption (I) holds. Therefore, it must be the case that S > (Bnn − Bnm ). Note also
that (λ − Λ) and (Λ − λ2 ) are always non-negative if Assumption (I) holds.
2 2 2
It remains to show that Z = Bnn|m − Bnm|m + Bnm|n − Bnm|m − Bnn − Bnm > 0. A change of variables will simplify
the argument here. Define a ≡ (Bnn|m − Bnm ), b ≡ (Bnm − Bnm|m ) and c ≡ (Bnm|n − Bnm ). Then we can reexpress the problem
as:
This expression is positive as long as b + c > 0. We show below that this corresponds to the requirement that
−4nm|m > −4nm|n which is the case if 1/2 ≥ σn1 and if Assumption (I) holds.
Proof of Proposition 2
To complete the proof we derive results on levels and changes in second period beliefs as first period beliefs
change. We focus on beliefs of entrepreneurs as those of employees can be derived by relabeling. We comment on
this below.
Consistent and Inconsistent Signals. Here we show that beliefs of students that they are entrepreneurs if they receive
consistent signals that they are entrepreneurs are higher than beliefs of all other students. We also show that beliefs
of students that they are entrepreneurs if they receive consistent signals that they are not entrepreneurs are lower
than beliefs of all other students. This is the first part of Proposition 2.
We show that: Bnn|n > Bnm|n , Bnn|n > Bnn|m . We also show that: Bnm|m < Bnm|n , Bnm|m < Bnn|m . The corresponding
n|n < Bm|n , Bn|n < Bn|m and Bm|m > Bm|n , Bm|m > Bn|m .
relationships for employees hold by symmetry: Bm m m n m m m n
32
σn2 σm2 φ(1 − φ) σ1 − σ1
n m
h ih i >0 (A.17)
σn2 σn1 φ + σm 2 σ1 (1 − φ) σ2 (1 − σ1 )φ + σ2 (1 − σ1 )(1 − φ)
m n n m m
σn2 Bnn 1 − σn2 Bnn
Bnn|n − Bnm|n = n n m − m =
σ2 Bn + σm 2 Bn (1 − σn2 )Bnn + (1 − σm2 )Bn
(σn2 − σm n m
2 )Bn Bn
h ih i >0 (A.18)
σn2 Bnn + σm 2 Bn
m
(1 − σn2 )Bnn + (1 − σm m
2 )Bn
(1 − σn2 )Bnm σn2 Bnm
Bnm|m − Bnn|m = − m =
(1 − σn2 )Bnm + (1 − σm 2 )Bm
m
σn2 Bnm + σm 2 Bm
(σm − σn2 )Bnm Bm
m
h i 2h i <0 (A.19)
σ2 Bm + σ2 Bm (1 − σ2 )Bm + (1 − σm
n n m m n n
2 )Bm
m
These expressions imply that students receiving consistent signals hold stronger second period beliefs than students
receiving inconsistent signals.
Comparative Statics of Consistent Signals. We investigate how the strength of first period signals affects the strength
of second period beliefs.
These derivatives demonstrate that second period beliefs of entrepreneurs who receive consistent signals that they
are entrepreneurs increase as first period signals for entrepreneurs and for employees become stronger. Note that
signals are stronger if (σn1 → 1) or (σm
1 → 0).
These derivatives demonstrate that second period beliefs of entrepreneurs who receive consistent signals that they
are employees decrease as first period signals for entrepreneurs and for employees become more precise.
33
∂Bnm|n ∂ (1 − σn2 )σn1 φ (1 − σn2 )σn1 (1 − σm2 )φ (1 − φ)
= = − <0 (A.26)
∂σm
1 ∂σm1 (1 − σ n
2 )σ n
1 φ + (1 − σ m
2 )σm (1
1 − φ) ((1 − σ n
2 )σn
1 φ + (1 − σ m
2 )σ1
m (1
− φ))2
These derivatives demonstrate that second period beliefs of entrepreneurs who receive first a correct and then an
incorrect signal will tend to be closer to entrepreneurship Bnm|n → 1 as first period signals for entrepreneurs and
employees become more precise.
These derivatives demonstrate that second period beliefs of entrepreneurs who receive first an incorrect and then a
correct signal will tend to be further from entrepreneurship Bnn|m → 0 as first period signals for entrepreneurs and
employees become more precise.
Proof of Proposition 3
This section sets out the proof of Proposition 3. We define changes in beliefs as follows:
Here the first set of changes in beliefs describes students receiving consistent signals and the second describes
students receiving inconsistent signals.
To simplify the following analysis we introduce a change of variables:
ζ ≡ (1 − σn1 )φ υ = (1 − σm
1 )(1 − φ) ν = σn1 φ ω = σm
1 (1 − φ) (A.31)
νω(σn2 − σm 2) ζυ(σm2 − σ2 )
n
4nn,n = 4nm,m =
[ν + ω][σ2 ν + σm
n
2 ω] [ζ + υ][ζ(1 − σn2 ) + υ(1 − σm
2 )]
νω(σ m
− σ n
) ζυ(σ n
− σ m
)
n,n = m,m =
2 2 2 2
4m 4m
[ν + ω][σn2 ν + σm 2 ω] [ζ + υ][ζ(1 − σn2 ) + υ(1 − σm
2 )]
ζυ(σn
− σ m
) νω(σ m
− σ n
)
4nn,m = 2 2
4nm,n = 2 2
[ζ + υ][σn2 ζ + σm 2 υ] [ν + ω][ν(1 − σn2 ) + ω(1 − σm2 )]
ζυ(σm
− σ n
) νω(σ m
− σ n
)
n,m = m,n =
2 2 2 2
4m 4m
[ζ + υ][σn2 ζ + σm 2 υ] [ν + ω][ν(1 − σn2 ) + ω(1 − σm2 )]
(A.32)
34
Consistent Signals. Begin first with changes in the beliefs of those receiving consistent signals. There are two
groups here: those receiving correct and those receiving incorrect signals.
Correct signals:
h i +
∂4nn,n ω(σn2 − σm
2 ) σ2 ω
m 2
− σ 2 ν
n 2 z}|{
∂ν
= (A.33)
∂σn1 [ν + ω]2 [σn2 ν + σm
2 ω]
2 ∂σn1
h i −
∂4m
m,m
υ(σ n
2 − σ m
2 ) (1 − σm 2
2 )υ − (1 − σ n 2 z}|{
2 )ζ ∂ζ
= (A.34)
∂σn1 [ζ + υ]2 [ζ(1 − σn2 ) + υ(1 − σm2 )] 2 ∂σ n
1
uninformative and there are approximately as many entrepreneurs as employees in the population (φ/(1 − φ) ≈ 1),
then the change in beliefs of those receiving correct signals in both periods is decreasing in the precision of the first
period signal . To see this note that in this case the overall sign of equations (A.33) and (A.34) is negative as the
following analysis of the terms in square brackets in the numerators shows:
σn2 σn1 2 φ2
σm
2ω
2
σn2 ν2 = σm
2ω
2
− 1 − (A.35)
σm2 σ1 (1 − φ) )
m2 2
The terms in square brackets in the numerators of equations (A.33) and (A.34) have the opposite sign to the signed
terms at the end of each expression leading to an overall negative sign if signals are sufficiently informative. This
means that σn1 → 1 and σm
1 → 0. In this case expression (A.35) is negative and so is the derivative at (A.33).
same conclusion. This is intuitive as nothing in the model prevents us from relabeling employees and entrepreneurs.
We have now shown that entrepreneurs and employees receiving correct and consistent signals will display lower
changes in beliefs from period one to period two if their first period signals are more precise and these signals are
sufficiently informative.
In contrast, if students receive uninformative signals then the effect of stronger first period information differs
by the type of student and by the type of signal. We do not pursue this case here.
35
Misleading signals:
h i −
∂4nm,m υ(σ2 − σ2 ) υ (1 − σ2 ) − ζ (1 − σ2 ) ∂ζ
m n 2 m 2 n z}|{
= (A.37)
∂σn1 [ζ + υ]2 [ζ(1 − σn2 ) + υ(1 − σm
2 )]
2 ∂σn1
h i +
∂4m
n,n
νω(σm
2 − σ n
2 ) σ2 ω
m 2
− σ2 ν
n 2 z}|{
∂ν
= (A.38)
∂σn1 [ν + ω]2 [σn2 ν + σm
2 ω]
2 ∂σn1
2 − σ2 ), which is
We can apply the same arguments as above to these two expressions. The common term (σm n
Conflicting Signals. Now focus on those receiving contradictory signals. Here there are two groups to distinguish
depending on the sequence in which the correct and the misleading signal arrive.
Sequence: misleading, correct We start with those who get a misleading signal and then a correct signal.
h i −
∂4nn,m υ(σ2 − σ2 ) σ2 υ − σ2 ζ
n m m 2 n 2 z}|{
∂ζ
n = (A.39)
∂σ1 [ζ + υ] [σ2 ζ + σ2 υ]
2 n m 2 ∂σn1
h i +
∂4m
m,n
ω(σn2 − σm
2 ) (1 − σ m
2 )ω2
− (1 − σn 2 z}|{
2 )ν ∂ν
=
∂σn1 [ν + ω]2 [ν(1 − σn2 ) + ω(1 − σm
2 )]
2 ∂σn1
Again we can apply the same reasoning as above. This shows that those who receive a misleading signal first, will
change their beliefs less as the precision of the first period signals increases if signals are sufficiently informative.
Again we can apply the same reasoning as above. This shows that those who receive a correct signal first, will
change their beliefs more as the precision of the first period signals increases.
This section provides several additional tables with evidence on the quality of the entrepreneurship course which
this study is based on. First we provide a table with evidence about the course impact. Next we provide additional
evidence on entrepreneurial intentions which supports the results we report in Table 4 above.
36
Assessment of Course Impact. An overall positive assessment of the course emerges from course evaluation ques-
tions available for 274 students participating in the course evaluation. These are tabulated in Table B.12. 81.4%
(9.1%) percent of the students agreed (were neutral) to the statement that they ”better understand the steps that one
has to take to found a firm.” The cooperation with real-world entrepreneurs yielded a smaller effect. 57.5% (25.1%)
agreed (were neutral) that they ”better understand the attitudes, values and motivation of entrepreneurs.”24 An im-
provement of practical management skills for founding a firm was confirmed by 66.8% percent of students, 19.7%
were neutral, 13.5% percent did not see an improvement. Asked whether the course has had the effect that ”I will
consider founding or taking over an enterprise” 41.6% responded positively, and 38.3% negatively. 20.1% percent
of students gave a neutral response. 34.7% percents stated that as an effect of the course, they would tend to prefer
an employee position, 41.2% disagreed with that statement, and 24.1% were neutral.
Cross-tabulating the last two responses shows that at the end of the course, about 40% percent of students indicated
that they have entrepreneurial intentions (and a dislike of an employee position), and about 35% have the opposite
preference.
Entrepreneurial Intentions. Table B.13 shows that the share of students indicating that they want to found their own
business at some point has decreased at the conclusion of the course. In the pre-course survey, 71.4% of the 196
students indicated entrepreneurial intentions. At the conclusion of the course, this share has decreased to 63.8%.
The differences are highly significant in a chi-square test (Pearson’s chi-squared=71.6, p < 0.001).
24 The somewhat smaller effect is probably due to the fact that student teams engaged in considerable division of labor, and that only some
students within the respective teams directly interacted with the cooperating entrepreneurs.
37
Table B.13: Ex ante and ex post Entrepreneurial Intentions
Would you like to found your own enterprise at some point?
Ex post response
no yes Total
Ex ante no 46 10 56 28.6%
response yes 25 115 140 71.4%
Total 71 125 196 100.0%
36.2% 63.8% 100.0%
Note: N=274 - data from the ex post survey and course evaluation.
38