0% found this document useful (0 votes)
59 views8 pages

Template Solutions To The Exam EC487: Advanced Microeconomics Lent Term 2016/7

(1) The document provides template solutions to exam questions on advanced microeconomics. It includes sketches of answers and diagrams to demonstrate supply and demand equilibrium. (2) Questions are answered regarding cost functions, individual and aggregate supply and demand, equilibrium price and quantity, producer profits, and Walrasian equilibria in Edgeworth boxes. Diagrams illustrate offer curves, equilibrium allocations, and Pareto efficiency. (3) The solutions show the existence and properties of competitive equilibrium, including how supply and demand determine price and quantity, and conditions for Pareto optimal allocations.

Uploaded by

amirhoseinrafaty
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
59 views8 pages

Template Solutions To The Exam EC487: Advanced Microeconomics Lent Term 2016/7

(1) The document provides template solutions to exam questions on advanced microeconomics. It includes sketches of answers and diagrams to demonstrate supply and demand equilibrium. (2) Questions are answered regarding cost functions, individual and aggregate supply and demand, equilibrium price and quantity, producer profits, and Walrasian equilibria in Edgeworth boxes. Diagrams illustrate offer curves, equilibrium allocations, and Pareto efficiency. (3) The solutions show the existence and properties of competitive equilibrium, including how supply and demand determine price and quantity, and conditions for Pareto optimal allocations.

Uploaded by

amirhoseinrafaty
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 8

LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS Department of Economics

Template Solutions to the Exam


EC487: Advanced Microeconomics
Lent Term 2016/7

1. Sketch of the answers:

(i) [20 marks] Notice first that, for any x ∈ X, (0, 1) - x - (3, 5) by
strict monotonicity and continuity. If such αx exists it is unique by
strict monotonicity. To show that αx exists for any x, use apply stan-
dard arguments using the continuity axiom as in the lectures (the
arguments are slightly simpler because of strict monotonicity).
(ii) [13 marks] Define u(x) = αx . Apply standard arguments as in the
lectures.

1
2. Sketch of the answers:

(i) [6 marks] Since a cost function is homogeneous of degree 1 in


(w1 , w2 ) then from

c(k w1 , k w2 , y) = k α min{w1α , w2α } y = k α c(w1 , w2 , y)

we conclude that
α=1

and the cost function is:

c(w1 , w2 , y) = min{w1 , w2 } y

(iv) [4 marks] The supply function for commodity y of each individual


producer is obtained from:

max p y − min{w1 , w2 } y
y

and it is perfectly elastic:

p = min{w1 , w2 }

(iii) [4 marks] Therefore the aggregate supply function is also perfectly


elastic:
p = min{w1 , w2 }

and it is plotted in the the following graph.


(iv) [4 marks] The Marshallian demand for each individual consumer is
the solution to the following problem:

max u(y) s.t. p y ≤ 2 p


y

that is y(p, m) = 2 from the monotonicity of u(·).

2
(v) [2 marks] The aggregate demand in this market is then

Y (p, m) = 16.

Aggregate supply and demand in this market are plotted in the fol-
lowing graph:

p 6

Y (p, m) = 16

p = min{w1 , w2 }

(vi) [6 marks] Equating aggregate demand and aggregate supply in this


market we obtain that the equilibrium quantity is:

Y ∗ = 16

while the equilibrium price is:

p∗ = min{w1 , w2 }.

Clearly the perfectly elastic supply in a one consumption good econ-


omy implies that the equilibrium price is completely supply deter-
mined while the equilibrium quantity is completely demand deter-
mined.
(vii) [3 marks] The equilibrium supply of commodity y of each individual
consumer is indeterminate being each producer’s supply identical

3
and perfectly elastic.
(viii) [4 marks] Each individual producer makes zero profit. Indeed his
revenues are p∗ y while his costs are min{w1 , w2 } y the formula for
the equilibrium price p∗ above implies that his profits are null.

4
3. The economy can be described in the Edgeworth box represented below.

B
.
oA .....
U B .
.....
.
oB ω F....
s s
..
.....
.
.....
.
.....
x2 .
.....
.....
...
E ..s...
.
.....
.
.....
. UA
...
A x1

(i) [4 marks] The offer curve of consumer A, denoted oA , is plotted in


the Edgeworth box above.
The offer curve of consumer B, denoted oB , is also represented in
the same Edgeworth box above.
(ii) [8 marks] There exists a continuum of Walrasian equilibria in this
economy. These WE are supported by any strictly positive relative
price p of commodity x1 and they correspond to the allocations in
the segment EF in the Edgeworth box above.
(iii) [5 marks] The set of Pareto-efficient allocations is defined by any
allocation of the main diagonal of the Edgeworth box above. The
WE allocations are therefore Pareto efficient.

5
Consider now the economy with the modified endowments.

P B
.. . ...
. .
oA
. .... U B
.....
. .
..... .....
ωs oB . .
...s.. .....
. .
..... E ..... F
. .
..... .....
. .
x2
..... .
.....
. .
..... .....
..... .....
. .
..... .....
. .
..... .. ...
. .
..... U A
. ....
... ...
A M x1

(iv) [4 marks] The offer curves of consumers A and B are oA and oB ,


respectively, as represented in the Edgeworth box above.
(v) [8 marks] The unique Walrasian equilibrium price is p∗ = 0 however
there exists a whole set of Walrasian equilibrium allocations. These
correspond to the segment EF in the Edgeworth box above. No-
tice that there may exist Walrasian equilibrium allocations such that
there exists excess supply of commodity x1 (For example the alloca-
tion of consumer A might be the one corresponding to E while the
allocation of consumer B might be the one corresponding to F .
(vi) [4 marks] The Pareto-efficient allocations are all the allocations in
the box in the area AP BM . Clearly all the Walrasian equilibrium
allocations in (v) above are Pareto efficient.

6
4. Sketch of the answers:

(i) [10 marks] We proceed by backward induction. Assume that n = 2


Consider the subgame starting in the t = T = 4 period, clearly the
extensive for of this subgame is the extensive form of a take-it-or-
leave-it offer of player B. This implies that A will accept any offer x
such that x ≥ 0 and B will offer x = 0 and the payoffs associated
with these strategies are (0, 1). Move back one period to t = 3 since
it is still the case that by rejecting the offer and moving to next period
A can guarantee herself a payoff of 0 then A will accept any offer x
such that x ≥ 0 and B will offer x = 0.
Consider now period t = 2. By rejecting the offer and moving to next
period B can guarantee himself a payoff of 1 hence it is a best reply
for B in this subgame to accept any offer 1 − x ≥ δ. This implies
that A’s subgame perfect equilibrium strategy is to offer x = 1 − δ in
this subgame. Consider now period t = 1. By rejecting the offer and
moving to next period B can guarantee himself a payoff of δ hence
it is a best reply for B in this subgame to accept any offer 1 − x ≥ δ 2 .
This implies that A’s subgame perfect equilibrium strategy is to offer
x = 1 − δ 2 in this game.
(ii) [7 marks] The payoffs associated with these subgame perfect equi-
librium strategies are
(1 − δ 2 , δ 2 ).

(iii) [10 marks] Notice that the game described above is equivalent to a
bargaining game where players alternate every period in making an
offer there are n periods and both players discount the future at the
rate
τ = δ2. (1)

The equilibrium payoffs of the unique SPE of such a transformed


game, given that n is even, are:

1 − τn τ + τn
ΠA = , ΠB = (2)
1+τ 1+τ

7
Substituting (1) in (4) we get:

1 − δT δ2 + δT
ΠA = , ΠB = (3)
1 + δ2 1 + δ2

(iv) [6 marks] The equilibrium payoffs of the unique SPE of the trans-
formed game, given that n is odd, are:

1 + τn τ − τn
ΠA = , ΠB = (4)
1+τ 1+τ

Substituting (1) in (4) we get:

1 + δT δ2 − δT
ΠA = , ΠB = (5)
1 + δ2 1 + δ2

You might also like