History of The Swedish System of Non-Profit Municipal Housing
History of The Swedish System of Non-Profit Municipal Housing
Foreword
This paper was originally written for the Commission of Inquiry on the
Conditions for Municipal Housing, and was included as Annex 11 in the
report "The European Union, Municipal Housing and Rents" (SOU
2008:38).
Knowledge about the history of the Swedish system of municipal non-
profit housing is crucial to the current debate about the role and future
tasks of the municipal housing companies. Boverket (the Swedish Board
of Housing, Building and Planning) therefore took the initiative to make a
reprint of the original paper.
The only addition that was made in the "Boverket version" was a
presentation of the directives to the Inquiry. In this English translation of
that reprint some very minor alterations have been made. These have only
been done for the sake of making the contents of the paper more
understandable for a non-Swedish reader.
The paper was written by Eva Hedman, who was Boverket's expert on
the Commission. She also did the reprint texts.
Martin Hedenmo
Head of Analysis Unit
4 A history of the Swedish system of non-profit municipal housing
5
Table of Content
Foreword .............................................................................................. 3
First steps: the state and municipalities enter the housing market ...... 9
Bibliography........................................................................................ 29
Publications............................................................................................. 29
Official government commissions............................................................ 31
6 A history of the Swedish system of non-profit municipal housing
7
Defining characteristics of
Swedish non-profit housing
In Sweden the term “allmännytta 1 ” (“for the benefit of everyone”) is
generally the word that has been used when speaking of the Swedish non-
profit housing sector. The Swedish “allmännytta” has four main
distinguishing characteristics: it operates on a not-for-profit basis; it is
almost entirely owned by municipalities; it is open to everyone, i.e. it is
not only directed at specific target groups; and its rents have been given
the role of serving as the main norm for rental levels across the entire
rented housing sector 2 . The origin of each of these four characteristics
may be traced to different historical periods 3 .
Housing production without a profit motive or purposes of personal
gain was something that existed in Sweden, albeit to a very limited
extent, from about the middle of the 19th century. At that time it was
usually a question of various kinds of charitable building in the cities,
initiated by wealthy and socially conscious members of the bourgeoisie
who were aware of and wished to improve the difficult housing situation
of the working class and the poor. It could also, less frequently, be a
question of workers in cities getting together to build their own housing –
a precursor of sorts to the cooperative housing associations of later years.
Non-profit housing companies, however – which are owned or
controlled by municipalities – did not begin to appear, with single
exceptions, until the mid-1930s. This was in connection with the
construction of the so-called “large family blocks”, aimed only at families
with many children. The state introduced special loans, combined with
rent allowances, for the “provision of affordable rental housing to less
well-off families with many children in cities, in city-like and other more
densely populated communities” 4 . This state support was only granted to
the municipality in question or through the municipality to such a
housing company that fulfilled a number of stated conditions. Conditions
for being recognised as such a housing company by the state building
loan bureau included the following 5 : the company’s dividend on owners’
equity must not exceed a sum that the state building loan bureau had
1
According to SABO’s (the Swedish Association of Municipal Housing Companies)
website, the Swedish term “allmännyttig” is a direct translation of the German
”gemeinnützig”. Norstedt’s German-Swedish Dictionary (1994) translates
”gemeinnützig” as “allmännyttig, samhällsnyttig”. The comprehensive German dictionary
Wahrig Deutsches Wörterbuch (Mosaik Verlag, edited 1980/1984) has the following
entry for ”gemeinnützig”: ”zum Wohl der Allgemeinheit, dem Nutzen der Allgemeinheit
dienend, sozial”, in which ”Allgemeinhet” refers to ”die Öffentlichkeit, das Volk, die
andern”. Which translates roughly as “for the good of, to be of service or benefit to, ‘the
general public’, ‘the people’ or ‘the others’. ”Gemeinnützig” is contrasted with
”Eigennutz”, i.e. as the opposite of individual benefit, good, gain, profit or yield.
2
See Chapter 12, Section 55 of the Land Code, SFS 2002:103.
3
In writing this paper I have been greatly helped by a number of presentations and
analyses of the development of both Swedish housing policy and non-profit housing. A
list of these may be found at the end of the paper.
4
SFS 1935:512.
5
SFS 1935:512, Section 12.
8 A history of the Swedish system of non-profit municipal housing
6
See SFS 1942:569, SFS 1946:551, SFS 1948:587, SFS 1957:360, SFS 1962:537, SFS
1967:552, SFS 1974: 946.
7
SOU 1972:40.
8
SFS 1974:946. The requirement that a non-profit (“allmännyttigt”) housing company be
wholly owned by a municipality applied until 1996, when the possibility of so-called
broadened ownership was introduced (SFS 1996:1435) – however, municipalities were to
continue to exercise the “decisive influence”. Since 2002, however (SFS 2002:102), a
housing company without municipal connections may also be defined as a non-profit
(“allmännyttigt”) housing company (more on this later in the paper).
9
SOU 172:40, “Competition in housing construction”, Ch. 7 contains an overview of how
conditions for authorisation as a non-profit housing company evolved over the period
from 1935 until 1972.
First steps: the state and municipalities enter the housing market 9
10
The utility value system, introduced in 1968 (Proposal 1968:91), deals with how a
rental dispute is to be settled in court. In order to assess the reasonableness of the rent, it is
to be compared with the rent for apartments that are equivalent in terms of “utility value”.
When rent control was abolished, the utility value system was introduced to protect
individuals’ right to tenancy, particularly in areas with a housing shortage. Its aim was to
allow for a transition to a market like development of rents.
The comparison rent was to be sought among the highest rents for flats with a similar
utility value in the same area, not taking single examples of very high rents into account.
It was not be sought among average rents as it was believed that this would preserve the
existing rent structure and “counteract a desirable flexibility in the setting of rents”
(Proposition 1968:91, Annex A, pp. 53-54). Thus the utility system as such was not aimed
at curbing rent increases but at safeguarding tenancy rights (ibid., p. 188). Nevertheless,
as the non-profit housing companies were the de facto dominant property developers, it
was expected that the prime cost rents applied in municipal housing would serve as
guidance and thereby serve to control and restrain the general level of rents.
A review later indicated that it was doubtful whether, in legal practice, municipal
housing rents had been given the price-guiding role intended for them, which according to
the Legal Affairs Committee (LU 1973:13, pp. 55-56) had been regarded as a necessary
means of preventing an uncalled-for increase of the general rent level. See Proposition
1974:150, p. 471. See also SOU 2000:33, pp. 33-35. From 1974, therefore, it was
stipulated by law that all rent assessments (not just those in shortage areas) be made
primarily by means of a comparison with (“which should principally take into account”)
rents in the municipal housing stock.
10 A history of the Swedish system of non-profit municipal housing
11
SFS 1942:569.
12
12
For an informative history, see e.g. SOU 1972:40, chapters 1 and 7.
The current situation for municipalities and their housing companies 13
of the cost of their initial outlays 13 . Later they would also be given tax
advantages, and later still, the largest interest subsidies 14 .
With the number of municipal housing companies now growing
quickly, the municipalities – with the help of the state – came to have at
their disposal instruments with which they were expected to contribute,
actively and on a non-speculative basis, to the fulfilment of the state’s
goals of doing away with the housing shortage and raising the general
housing standard 15 .
As has been mentioned, however, housing policy was not just a
central part of state welfare policy. It also became an integral part of state
economic policy, including labour market policy. Also this affected the
growth and development of the municipal housing sector. Together the
two areas of policy would become actively applied instruments in the
industrial, economic and geographical transformation of Sweden that
would characterise the decades up until the beginning of the 1970s.
Housing construction was regarded as an important motor of
economic growth, and as an instrument with which to moderate the ups
and downs of the economic cycle. Besides building for social reasons – to
improve the housing standard and end the housing shortage – this also
meant building in a way which made possible the development of an
efficient manufacturing and export industry. This in turn meant building a
sufficient number of dwellings where there was a particular need for
labour to allow for the expansion of industry. It also meant, however, that
construction could not tie up too much labour or capital, as these
resources were needed in other sectors.
The municipal non-profit housing companies became important
instruments for both the state and municipalities in this social, economic
and geographical process of structural change which would define
Sweden for several decades. It may be noted in retrospect that this was a
complex role which it was possible for these housing companies to play
precisely because their accommodation was meant for everyone. It would
have been impossible for them to fill such a complex and key role if the
municipal housing companies’ dwellings had been aimed only at those
who were worst off.
One of the ideas of the Inquiry on the Social Conditions of Housing
had been that the volume of housing construction should be based on
long-term projections for the need of dwellings. Production should then
be kept at as even a pace as possible. Construction workers would thereby
13
SFS 1946:551. For cooperatives, the upper loan limit was 95 percent, while for others it
was 85 percent (90 percent in some cases). The differences between the municipal
housing companies and the others would remain, with certain adjustments of the levels,
until state housing loans were abolished in 1991 (SFS 1991:1932). The differences in loan
conditions for different categories of borrowers for the state loans had been introduced in
1942 (SFS 1942 no. 569), when state loans were no longer directed exclusively towards
municipalities and municipally controlled non-profit housing companies but to the whole
sector.
14
This was a consequence of the fact that their privileges with state loans gave them the
biggest share of loans, and that interest-rate subsidies were calculated on the basis of the
size of the granted loan.
15
See e.g. SOU 1972:40.
14 A history of the Swedish system of non-profit municipal housing
16
It proved rather difficult to reach an agreement about this, however. For example, in
1966 the Riksbank (the Swedish Central Bank) did not release sufficient credit, which led
to a notable drop in housing construction. In the political crisis that ensued, the
The current situation for municipalities and their housing companies 15
given new and increased means of controlling land use. State measures
were further applied to promote the construction of big projects using
industrial methods.
The stated goal was to end the housing shortage and improve housing
conditions. At the same time, the need to increase production in big city
areas and in places with expanding industry was stressed.
It was the municipal housing companies, along with the housing
cooperatives (in particular HSB and Riksbyggen 17 ), that became the key
players in achieving the goals of the Million Dwellings Programme. In
ten years just over a million new dwellings were produced, two thirds of
which were in blocks of flats. It was through the building of the Million
Dwellings Programme that the municipal housing companies became the
dominant manager of Sweden’s blocks of flats.
Those who first moved in to the new large housing estates of blocks of
flats were a mixture of different groups. This was where many moved
when they left old, deficient and crowded accommodation. This was
where many of the young baby-boom households set up their first homes.
This was also where many in the large groups of households that moved
for labour market reasons, from other parts of Sweden as well as from
abroad, took up residence. Finally, this was also where many of those
moved who had difficulties of some kind and needed to be given priority
when it came to housing.
Government forced the Riksbank to reconsider, and in 1967 housing construction was
back at a high level. See e.g. T Erlander’s memoirs, R Johansson/B Karlberg, O Eriksson.
17
In the face of the great housing shortage and the high unemployment rate in
construction, the building workers’ unions, in 1940, took the initiative themselves to
establish the building and housing association Svenska Riksbyggen.
16 A history of the Swedish system of non-profit municipal housing
18
These included the introduction of interest subsidies (SFS 1974:946) and the
establishment of municipal housing companies’ rent levels as the primary norm (see
proposition 1974:150 and the Rents Act/Land Code). The new financing system which
was introduced in 1975 meant that the principle of subsidy-free loans (but with interest
guarantees) was abandoned. Instead the state set a low so-called guaranteed interest rate.
The difference between this and the actual market interest rate was paid by the state in the
form of interest subsidies. It was in this context that state subsidies for the first time were
accepted as a permanent solution.
The current situation for municipalities and their housing companies 17
19
In 1950, the non-profit housing companies had formed SABO as their central
organisation.
20
See Lindberg, G & Karlberg, B (1988)
21
See e.g. the 1994 report of the National Board of Housing, Building and Planning:
“Bostadsmarknaden och 90-talets förändringar”, Boverket Rapport 1994:1 (The Housing
Market and the changes of the 1990s, in Swedish).
22
It should be added, however, that there had been widespread political agreement for a
number of years that something had to be done about state subsidies. It was pointed out
that the goal of a high national housing standard had been achieved, while at the same
time ever-growing subsidies and a large public debt threatened to undermine confidence
in the Swedish economy. As an example of the rapid cost developments, housing
subsidies totalled SEK 13 billion in 1987, and by 1992 they had grown to SEK 33 billion.
23
Until then, the interest subsidy system had been specially designed to do precisely that.
In the 1970s and 80s the state had additionally given municipalities and municipal
housing companies special support to cover the rent losses incurred by the many empty
flats. With the changes of the 1990s, financial risk was transferred from the state to
municipalities. See e.g. SOU 1996:156, Chapter 13.2 for a more detailed description.
18 A history of the Swedish system of non-profit municipal housing
24
More on this in the final section of this paper.
25
As reported during a visit on 28-29 March 2007.
26
It may be noted that a discussion about turning the municipalities’ housing companies
into limited companies had been held much earlier, albeit from a different perspective. In
SOU 1972:40 it was suggested that the limited company form was preferable to the
foundation form as it would give the companies’ activities greater stability. At the time,
the main concern was about rules for reporting and audits, but also companies’
distribution of responsibility between executive director, board and annual general
meeting. It was even suggested that only limited companies should in future be authorised
as municipel housing companies. However, no decision to this effect was made.
The current situation for municipalities and their housing companies 19
27
Above all by the Swedish Union of Tenants.
28
SFS 1986:694, SFS 1996:1435, SFS 1999:608, SFS 2002:102.
29
Cf. Note 9. See also Proposition 2001/02:58, Section 4.3.6.
20 A history of the Swedish system of non-profit municipal housing
groups want to move there. In practice, however, what had most often
been achieved were expensive physical transformations and only
temporary improvements.
Around the mid-1990s, however, some municipal housing companies,
supported by their municipalities, began to think and act in radically new
ways – with positive results this time 30 . One of the conclusions
underlying these changes was that it was the housing company’s day-to-
day, ongoing management – not temporary projects – that made
successful renewal possible in a housing estate. Another conclusion was
that when renewal was planned it must start out from the residents’
perspective, not be imposed by the housing company according to its own
predetermined objectives.
The main pioneers in this included MKB in Malmö (in Holma and
parts of Rosengård) 31 , Botkyrkabyggen in the Stockholm region and
Förvaltnings AB Framtiden in Göteborg (in particular Gårdsten and
Hjällbo). In all of these estates, it was clear that the situation was
untenable. Financial losses were mounting due to damage, high occupant
mobility and many empty flats. Earlier attempts with comprehensive
physical alterations and other ways to attract other categories of tenants
had failed. A point had been reached where everyone agreed that
something radical had to be done.
As a starting point, these municipalities decided that their housing
company should not try to replace those living in the estate with
perceived better tenants. Instead the current residents should be the point
from which renewal and change began. Their needs, wishes and – not
least importantly – active participation were to be the basis for renewal.
There would be no more temporary “projects” of renewal, instead
renewal was to be carried out within the framework of the ongoing
management of the estate. All the housing companies involved realised
that this required a new form of organisation, with changed working
methods and a new attitude towards tenants. The earlier approach, which
had been hierarchical and specialised, was abandoned. “House
heads/housekeepers”, managing between 100 and 300 flats with full
personal responsibility for results, became the key staff category. Large
investments were made in their professional development, and recruiting
concentrated on individuals with the right social competence. They were
to be present on the estates, in direct and continuous contact with the
people living in the area 32 .
30
See e.g. conference summaries from the Swedish National Board of Housing, Building
and Planning’s (Boverkets) Planning and Building Days on 27-29 August 2002, the
seminar entitled (in Swedish) “Can the landlord mitigate exclusion?”. For various
descriptions, see also Alenmark (1994), Alfredsson/Cars (1996) (1997),
Alfredsson/Andersson/Cars (1998), Birve (2007), Boverkets Byggkostnadsforum (2007),
Hansson (2007), Olsson et al (2005), Öresjö (1996 and 2006).
31
MKB in Malmö had actually begun in the 1980s already, in the Gullviksborg and
Örtagården/Rosengård estates. See Ahlström et al (1982), Andersson et al (1987),
Örtagården (1987).
32
It may be noted that these companies in their own internal reviews reached similar
conclusions to those underlined in the new management policy launched by SABO in
1981, but that they chose to act on them in much more far-reaching ways.
The current situation for municipalities and their housing companies 21
One important lesson was that it proved necessary also to deal with
issues beyond the scope of traditional property management. This was
expressed as the importance of moving from “managing properties” to
“creating a good housing/living environment”. In order to achieve this, it
proved necessary to set out from the issues that tenants themselves
expressed were most important – even if they went beyond traditional
property management issues.
What the tenants were generally concerned about – besides the basic
issues of having employment and being able to support oneself – was
safety and security in the area, the condition and cleanness of the
buildings and the area, and not having to feel ashamed about where they
lived. They were also concerned about being treated with respect by the
management staff, about good schools, childcare and other facilities for
children, as well as about various types of commercial and public
services.
Many of these were management issues and thus clearly within the
remit of the housing companies. Other issues could be dealt with through
collaboration with municipal and other bodies. In some cases, however,
the housing companies found that if anything was to happen, they had to
apply the measures themselves – despite the fact that they were thereby
dealing with issues that weren’t really within their area of responsibility.
All of these “pioneers” have underlined the importance of receiving
clear owner’s directives from the municipality, which emphasise both the
need for broader-based renewal efforts and the importance of business-
mindedness and sound finances. They have said that clear objectives –
but not political micro-management of the kind where the municipality
intervenes in daily management activities – in combination with
independent financial control creates the kind of freedom that the
company needs in order to be perceptive and act on the basis of what the
immediate situation requires, but also on the basis of longer-term social,
economic and environmental perspectives. Not least importantly, they
have all pointed out that rehabilitation and renewal take time.
33
See e.g. “Den allmännyttiga bostadssektorn i Danmark, Nederländerna och England”
(“The non-profit housing sector in Denmark, the Netherlands and England”) Boverket
(The Swedish National Board of Housing, Building and Planning), 2000. Here it emerges
that neither the Danish nor the Dutch “allmännytta” is publicly owned, but is owned by
private and financially independent housing companies operated on a not-for-profit basis.
22 A history of the Swedish system of non-profit municipal housing
34
Those municipal housing companies which had already been authorized continued to
receive, under special transitional rules, the more favourable support they had been
granted under the previous acts.
35
Boverkets’s (The National Board of Housing, Building and Planning) study “En studie
av allmännyttiga bostadsföretag som kommunala instrument”, (2006), Part I, pp. 13-15,
presents a brief history of how the concrete content of the not-for-profit requirement has
been reformulated over the years.
24 A history of the Swedish system of non-profit municipal housing
36
Not to be confused with the “stop law” in health care, which was about the sale of
hospitals owned by county councils. See also Note 37.
37
The following section has been added after the report was written for the Inquiry.
38
In place of the hitherto existing unspecified and ambiguous concept being used.
The current situation for municipalities and their housing companies 25
the essence of Swedish housing policy, including the foundations for the
roles played by municipal housing companies.”
The change in government in the autumn of 2006 brought certain
changes to the directives for the commission. The first additional
directives (Directive 2007:18) stated that the commission should assume
that “the regulations requiring permission for the transfer of real estate as
well as shares and units in municipal housing companies will be
abolished during 2007”. Compare that with what has been said above
about the repealing of part of the Act on Non-Profit Housing Companies.
The second set of additional directives (Directive 2007:73) brought a
larger number of changes and additions. It stated that the commission
needed a wider mandate to be able to propose such changes as were
deemed necessary with regard to EC rules.
Under the original directives, municipal housing companies were to
adhere to a long-term cost price principle. This restriction was now
removed, with the explanation that it could limit the commission’s
possibilities for presenting alteration proposals that were compatible with
EC rules.
The new directives specified that the commission should specially
examine both the extent to which EC rules involve rate of return
requirements for municipal housing companies, and the extent to which
limited rate of return requirements for municipal housing companies are
compatible with EC rules. The present limit on dividends paid was a
particular issue.
In the new directives it was specifically stressed that municipal
housing was to continue being a housing form for everyone. It was stated
that Swedish municipal housing “has long been characterised by the
fundamental concept that it is a form of housing available to everyone,
regardless of social, economic, ethnic or other background. It is important
that municipal housing does not change in this respect.” It was
specifically pointed out that “If several models are possible in order to
make necessary changes, the commission shall not propose any model
which implies that the municipal and non-profit housing companies begin
to move towards only providing housing for particular groups or
following special testing, e.g. according to specific income criteria.”
Another special item that was brought out in the directives was that
the rent setting system should be adapted to EC rules. Real protection of
tenancy rights was to be the term of reference in this context. The aim of
proposed changes should be to “create the conditions for a well-
functioning rental market” that can meet the housing demand of
individuals and on which both private and municipal housing companies
can operate under conditions that are neutral as to competition and also
otherwise reasonable. The commission should also consider the need for
guaranteeing the supply of rented accommodation. The directives further
stated that if it appeared suitable, the commission should suggest how the
municipal housing companies’ normative role in setting rents might be
abolished.
The directives point out that the utility value system in itself
constitutes protection against exorbitant rents and guarantees for real
protection of tenancy rights. However, it was especially pointed out that
26 A history of the Swedish system of non-profit municipal housing
the commission was to consider whether there might arise a need for
extra regulations guaranteeing that tenants are not subjected to
unacceptable rent increases.
Among other things highlighted in the directives was the instruction
that the commission should indicate how support could be given to
municipal and private housing companies in municipalities with high
vacancy rates due to a decreasing population, without breaking
Community state aid rules.
39
See e.g. SOU 1996:156, Section 13.2.1.
40
SFS 1999:608, often referred to as the “stop law”. This replaced the earlier law from
1996 (SFS 1996:1435) under which not only the interest subsidies for the sold properties
would be cancelled, but also the interest subsidies paid out for the rest of the properties
the housing company owned. Under SFS 1999:608 the general state grant would also be
The current situation for municipalities and their housing companies 27
subsidies had reached such a low level that their cancellation was no
longer considered an effective means of pressure 41 . The Council on
Legislation made it a condition for the application of this measure, which
was not aimed at the housing companies but at the municipalities, that it
be temporary. When the Act on Non-Profit Housing Companies came
into force in 2002, this measure was revoked. After that, no state
sanctions remained for either the sale of municipal housing companies (or
of part of their housing stock) or the payment of excessive dividends to
the municipality. All that remained was that permission had to be sought
from the county administrative board for sales, and that the housing
companies’ dividends should be reported annually to the county
administrative board.
For municipalities the present situation thus means that it is up to them
themselves – more than before – to judge whether they find it meaningful
to have at their disposal a municipal not-for-profit housing company as an
instrument of housing policy. It has become necessary – very much more
so than before – to keep an eye on the housing company’s finances, as
well as on the municipality’s financial conditions. Since the 1990s, the
close intertwining of housing companies’ and municipalities’ finances –
previously almost the rule – has largely been undone. Most municipal
housing companies are now run as limited liability companies. These
may be owned by the municipalities and be controlled by means of
municipal directives, but they have been separated from regular
municipal economic activities in a wholly new way.
The current situation also includes the prospect that financial support
from municipalities to their housing companies may not just be
problematic for reasons of municipal economy, but also – as has been
mentioned – due to the conditions highlighted by EC competition and
state aid rules.
In other words, what remains for the municipalities is the old question,
albeit more “naked” than before: is it worthwhile owning housing
companies, to use as municipal instruments? 42 If the answer is yes: then
for what? Do the municipalities primarily want them in their capacity of
being limited companies that can provide earnings and dividends for the
municipality? Or do the municipalities want to continue seeing them
primarily as the broadly conceived municipal instruments of housing, and
social and economic policies that they have served as since the 1940s –
albeit now within the framework of a necessarily more businesslike
conduct? And if the municipalities choose to see their housing companies
as policy instruments, then what might be, or possibly ought to be, the
reduced if the municipal housing company had paid a dividend that exceeded “reasonable
returns”.
41
See SOU 1997:81. Final report of the Inquiry into Municipal Housing Companies.
42
Against this background, it is hardly surprising that SABO began, in 2006, a
comprehensive study of future conditions (Frambo). The reports from this study, which
was presented in the spring of 2007, formed the basis of the new conceptual programme
that SABO adopted at its congress in June 2007.
28 A history of the Swedish system of non-profit municipal housing
43
The National Board of Housing, Building and Planning was asked, as a part of the
ongoing inquiry, to study the current ownership directives of 25 municipalities´ housing
companies. This study showed that there was considerable variation in the goals
expressed in these documents and also in what the housing companies themselves
regarded as their goals as municipal housing companies. In the Board’s report, the various
municipalities’ stated goals have been arranged under one or more of the following
headings: formal rules, financial premises, provision of housing, social responsibility,
responsibility for general municipal development, and environmental aspects. For a more
detailed description, see Boverket (2006). See also Bergsten and Holmqvist (2007).
44
Gårdsten in Gothenburg and Herrgården, part of Rosengård in Malmö, are two estates
where this has been the case.
29
Bibliography
Publications