University of Pennsylvania Study
University of Pennsylvania Study
Abstract
Ballots are meant to be an expression of a voter’s electoral preferences. As more states and local
jurisdictions adopt ranked choice voting (RCV), they face a trade-off between allowing their voters to
express more complex preferences and the more complicated ballot potentially yielding higher rates of
ballot-marking errors and ballot rejections. What is missing from debates about the use of RCV is
empirical estimates of rates of improper marking and rejection rates, and how they compare to those
rates on traditional, single-mark ballots. We contribute to this debate by developing a general framework
for categorizing ways voters can improperly mark a single-mark or ranked ballot. We then apply that
framework to what we believe is the most comprehensive database of ranked choice ballots ever assembled–
including over 3 million cast vote records in four different electoral jurisdictions that use RCV. The data
show that in a typical ranked choice race, nearly 1-in-20 (4.8%) voters improperly marks their ballot in at
least one way. The rate of one type of improper marking (overvoting) is 14 times more likely to occur on
a ranked choice race than a non-ranked choice race that appears on the same ballot. Furthermore, we
find that votes in ranked choice races are nearly 10 times more likely to be rejected due to an improper
mark than votes in non-ranked choice races. These findings raise key normative questions about voter
participation and representation in ranked choice systems and have important policy implications for
jurisdictions that already have or are considering adopting ranked choice voting.
∗ University of Pennsylvania
† University of Pennsylvania
In a democracy, it is essential that voters can express their electoral preferences. Voters express those
preferences through ballots (Katz 1997), and in the United States a new kind of ballot is gaining momentum
through the adoption of Ranked Choice Voting (RCV). It has been used in a handful of municipalities for
decades, but in the past five years its use has grown, being adopted by New York City, the largest city in the
country, for municipal elections in 2021. It has also been used in two states, Maine and Alaska, for Federal
races since 2018 and 2022 respectively, and are on track to be joined by a third, Nevada, if voters re-approve
a ballot measure in 2024. RCV’s growing momentum makes it an important subject of study as millions of
This is especially true given that ballot design itself can influence how final vote counts reflect the attitudes
of voters. Researchers have explored this for typical single-mark ballots for decades (Cottrell et al. 2022;
Kimball and Kropf 2005)—most notably in the 2000 election (Wand et al. 2001; Herron and Sekhon 2003).
There have been some studies examining this for RCV (Graham-Squire and McCune 2024), alongside a good
deal of debate emanating from news and advocacy organizations (Shabad 2022; “Sarah Palin’s Defeat in
Alaska Proves Ranked-Choice Voting Works” 2022). Many studies have evaluated the tabulation methods
used in RCV, but this is only one part of how voter preferences are translated into vote counts. The second
part is the focus of this paper: how voters engage with their ballots, specifically, the ranked ballots use for
RCV.
This paper evaluates whether the more complex ballots used for RCV lead to more errors and ballot rejections.
We start by building on previous work on voter confusion (Atkeson et al. 2023) and voter irrationality (M.
Alvarez, Hall, and Levin 2018) in ranked choice systems to create an exhaustive framework for characterizing
all possible ways in which a voter can improperly “bubble-in” a ranked choice ballot. Importantly, we
distinguish between filling out a ballot in a politically strategic way–perhaps by not utilizing all available
rankings–and improper marks that reflect a mis-understanding of the ranked choice system, potentially
(although not necessarily) resulting in the vote not being counted. Our focus in this article is quantifying
We then apply this framework to what we believe to be the largest database of cast vote records of ranked
choice votes that have been studied. Cast vote record data from nearly 3 million ballots in Alaska, Maine,
New York, and San Francisco allow us to identify ballot improper marks at the individual vote/ballot level.
Furthermore, because most of the cast vote records in our database include both ranked choice and non-ranked
choice offices, we can compare error and rejection rates between the two groups of offices that appeared on
mark their ballot. We also demonstrate that voters are 14 times more likely to overvote— a type of error
found in both ranked and traditional, single-mark ballots— in ranked choice races than single-mark races
on the same ballot. Importantly, not every improper marking results in a ballot rejection: we find that on
average 0.35% of ballots are rejected in the first round of tabulation, with rejection rates increasing to 0.53%
in the final round of tabulation1 . Crucially, however, we also find that rejection rates tend to be more than
an order of magnitude higher in RCV than in non-RCV races. All of these findings hold true after accounting
for high rates of ballot exhaustion in RCV races,2 though it is worth noting that ballot exhaustion—the
literature for which we cover in Section 2— can also affect how voter preferences are translated into vote
Our paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2 we describe previous work on RCV, specifically highlighting
research about voter confusion and ballot rejection. In Section 3 we then detail our framework for identifying
improper marks and explain how it can be used to better understand how voters engage with their ballot.
We then describe our cast vote record data (Section 4), underscoring the breadth and depth of our database.
We use that data in Section 5 to measure how often voters improperly mark their ranked choice ballots
and provide an initial exploration of the correlates of these error rates, specifically the number of available
rankings, voter roll-off, and office salience. In Section 6 we show that while most ranked choice ballots with
an improper mark are ultimately counted, the ballot rejection rates in ranked choice offices are still more than
an order of magnitude higher than those in non-ranked offices. We conclude in Section 7 with a discussion of
the academic and policy implications of our findings, as well as the future avenues for research on the topic.
Our focus in this research is on ranked ballots, which have become increasingly utilized by American voters in
recent years. We distinguish multiple-mark, ranked ballots from traditional, single-mark ballots (Rae 1967).3
The vast majority of elected offices in the United States are elected via a single-mark ballot, on which voters
cast their vote for a single candidate. There are two major differences between elections that used ranked
The first of these differences is how ballots are tabulated and winners are determined. Most (although not
1 Section3 illuminates how rejection rates can increase from the beginning to the end of tabulation.
2 In
ranked choice voting, a ballot is exhausted when all candidates for whom the voter provided a ranking have been eliminated
during vote counting.
3We recognize that there are both other ballot types (such as approval voting, cumulative voting, or grading systems) and
many rules for counting votes on a ranked ballot (such as the Borda and Condorcet methods or multi-winner districts). Our
focus in this paper, however, is exclusively on ranked ballots and traditional, single-mark ballots in single-winner elections using
either Ranked Choice Voting or plurality winner tabulation procedures.
may be used in conjunction with one of several tabulation methods (Santucci 2021; Maloy 2019; Blais 1988;
McCune and McCune 2022). The most common of these methods in the United States is an instant runoff
system,4 where candidates with the fewest votes are sequentially eliminated and voters’ preferences among
the remaining candidates are counted until one candidate has a majority of support on the remaining ballots
In this paper, our main focus is on the second feature that distinguishes ranked choice from single-mark
ballots: the design of the ballot itself and how voters engage with it. On a race utilizing a single-mark ballot,
voters are presented with one bubble per candidate (or button, if they are voting on an electronic machine).
For their vote to be counted, the voter must bubble-in or press the button for exactly one candidate. On
a ranked choice ballot, there are one bubble/button per candidate times the number of available rankings,
which either equals the number of candidates or some upper limit defined by law, and voters are asked to
rank-order their preferred candidates. Whether their vote is included in the first, intermediate, and final
vote-counting rounds depends both on whether they had ballot marking errors, where those errors were on
their ballot, and whether the candidates they ranked on their ballot had enough support from other voters to
Our work on improperly marking ballots builds on a growing literature about how RCV impacts political
behavior. McDaniel (2016) evaluates its impact on turnout of minority voters, and McDaniel (2018) assesses
its implications on racially-polarized voting. Clark (2020) also considers the impact that RCV has on the
cost of voting, finding that the “costs of ranked-choice voting. . . vastly outweight the benefits of the system of
voting.” Other scholars have studied whether candidates of color perform better under RCV (Crowder-Meyer,
Gadarian, and Trounstine 2023), if descriptive representation by women and minorities is improved (John,
Smith, and Zack 2018; Terrell, Lamendola, and Reilly 2021), or if campaign messaging is more civil (Donovan
and Tolbert 2023; Kropf 2021), potentially increasing turnout in the process (Juelich and Coll 2021).
Other scholars have also focused on the prevalence of ballot truncation in ranked choice voting–voters who
do not use all the rankings available to them. These studies generally find that ballot truncation is quite
common and can have effects on the outcome (Kilgour, Gregoire, and Foley 2020), from affecting who the
winner is (Tomlinson, Ugander, and Kleinberg 2022) to resulting in winners elected with less than a majority
of the original ballots cast (Burnett and Kogan 2015). In our study, we do not consider ballot truncation to
be a form of improper marking. Voters may have a sincere preference against ranking some candidates on
their ballot (McCune and Wilson 2023; Bartholdi and Orlin 1991). Others may choose to only rank a single
4 In Australia, this system is called the ‘Alternative Vote’ (Bean 1997).
ourselves to situations where it is difficult the believe that voters are improperly marking their ballots for
Our study most closely builds on previous work about the impact that ranked ballot complexity has on voter
confusion. Most of these studies utilize survey data to show that voters tend to find ranked ballots more
complicated than single-mark ballots (Curtice and Marsh 2014). In some cases, studies found that older
voters found ranking more difficult or had less understanding of RCV rules (Coll 2021; Donovan, Tolbert,
and Gracey 2019), thought not in others (Donovan, Tolbert, and Harper 2022). The literature finds few
systemic differences in understanding of RCV rules across racial/ethnic lines, though there does appear to be
such a relationship with education (Coll 2021; Donovan, Tolbert, and Gracey 2019; Donovan, Tolbert, and
Harper 2022). More recently, Atkeson et al. (2023) use exit polls to demonstrate that a considerable number
By analyzing actual rates of improper marks, rather than self-reported rates of confusion, we are able to
better understand how voters are interacting with the ranked choice system. Our empirical approach is more
comprehensive than prior work, but we are not the first to study ballot errors in ranked choice systems (M.
Alvarez, Hall, and Levin 2018 ). Previous studies of invalid ballots date as far back as the Progressive Era,
when ranked-ballot systems were adopted in jurisdictions across the US (Mott 1926). More recent work,
mostly on San Francisco, has shown that overvote rates are higher in RCV elections, and that voters of color
and older voters overvote at higher rates using RCV Neely and Cook (2008).
Because ranked ballots are more complex than single-mark one, there are more ways for a voter to make
a mistake in filling it out. In this section, we provide a general framework for thinking about the types of
mistakes a voter can make when filling out a ranked or single-mark ballot,5 which represent the vast majority
of ballots used for elections in the US. This framework provides for three types of improper marks that a
voter can make: overvotes, overranks, and skips.6 Later in this this section we describe these error types in
more detail.
We conceptualize two ways in which a voter can “correctly” mark a ranked choice ballot. First, a complete
5 In some ways, a single-mark ballot could be considered to be a special case of a ranked ballot. Voters only get to rank one
candidate, and the winner is determined by sequentially removing the candidates with the smallest number of votes until one
candidate has more than half of the remaining votes.
6 This framework formally categorizes the ballot marking approaches that (M. Alvarez, Hall, and Levin 2018) describe as
ranked ballot is one in which the voter utilizes all available rankings, and does not choose any candidate
more than once. The left panel of Figure 1 shows a complete ballot cast in the November 2022 Alaska Senate
election. This voter’s preferences were (in order) Murkowski, Chesbro, Kelley, write-in, and Tshibaka.7 In
jurisdictions that allow its voters to rank a write-in candidate, we consider a ballot to be “complete” even if
they did not specify a write-in choice for one of their rankings.8 This choice has no bearing on the empirical
The second group of properly marked ranked ballots are truncated ballots. A ballot is truncated if the voter
ranked one candidate for each ranking 1 through n, where n is less than the total number of available rankings,
and no candidate or ranking is used multiple times. The right side of Figure 1 provides an example of a
truncated ballot, where the voter’s rankings were Chesbro, Murkowski, and Kelley, leaving the fourth and
fifth ranking options blank. Although some voters may truncate their ballots due to confusion about ranked
choice rules, we do not consider ballot truncation to be a type of improper marking since it may convey a
In our analysis, we treat both complete and truncated ballots as correctly marked ballots. We now turn to
describing the three ways in which a ballot can be improper marked, which may sometimes result in the
7 The ballot image reproductions throughout his section come from Alaska’s cast vote records data, which we describe in
more detail later. The data do not include information about which write-in votes were actually cast for.
8 RCV may make it necessary to revisit rules for counting write-in votes, specifically in instances where a voter writes in the
name of a candidate who appears on the ballot. For example, some states count write-in voters for a named candidate toward
that candidate’s overall total during a recount. If that state adopted RCV, it would need to provide guidance on how such
write-ins should be handled during not just the final round of ranked choice vote counting, but also in intermediate rounds
where the order of candidate elimination can have cascading effects on the final winner of a race (Tucker et al. 2022; Williams,
Baltz, and Stewart 2023).
9 It is also worth noting that a truncated ballot that ranks all but one named candidate is identical to a complete ballot
from the perspective of tabulating the votes. At the latest, the winner of a race is guaranteed to be chosen when there are two
candidates left. If those candidates happen to be a voter’s last and second-to-last preferences, their vote will be counted for the
second-to-last preference, regardless of whether they filled in the final ranking column.
3.1 Overvoting
The first category of improper markings are overvotes. An overvote occurs when a voter selects more than
one candidate for a given ranking. Of the three types of ballot marking errors we describe in this section,
overvoting is described most extensively in the literature, since it is a type of error that can occur on a
single-mark ballot (Kimball and Kropf 2005). Most of this literature couples overvotes with undervotes
(i.e. leaving an office completely blank) to calculate the residual vote rate, which has been used to study
problems with voting technology (R. M. Alvarez, Beckett, and Stewart III 2013; Sinclair and Alvarez 2004),
ballot design (Kimball and Kropf 2005; Cottrell et al. 2022; Herron et al. 2023), and expressive non-voting
Overvoting on a ranked ballot is similar to overvoting on a single-mark ballot, but with more opportunities
for it to happen. We conceptualize an overvote as a feature of a numeric ranking (i.e. the columns of the
example ballots). Figure 2, shows two examples of overvotes from the 2022 Alaska Senate election. The
ballot on the left side includes first-choice votes for both Chesbro and Tshibaka and is thus an overvote in
column 1. The ballot on the right has an overvote in the second column.
These two examples highlight an important aspect of improperly marked ranked ballots: improperly marking
a ranked ballot does not necessarily preclude a vote from being counted. The vote on the left side of Figure 2
would never be counted because the voter’s intent for their first-choice preference is ambiguous. But because
Tshibaka was not eliminated during vote tabulation, the vote on the right side of that figure was counted in
the final tabulation. If their first-choice vote had instead been for Kelley (who was eliminated after the first
with an overvote usually, but do not always result in a voided vote. This is an important distinction from
overvoting on a single-mark ballot, which always yields an invalidated/spoiled vote (Kimball and Kropf 2005).
3.2 Skipping
The second category of improper markings are skips, which are definied as leaving a ranking blank, but filling
in a subsequent ranking. This definition distinguishes skips from truncated ballots, wherein a voter selects
candidates for rankings 1 through n, but leaves blank all rankings after n. Skipping can come in one of two
forms.
The first form, demonstrated on the left side of Figure 3, is an interior skip. They occur when a blank ranking
column is preceded and succeeded by non-blank ranking columns. The voter in this example ballot skipped
rankings 2 and 4, but marked rankings 1, 3, and 5. The second form of skipping is a front skip, which occurs
when the voter leaves blank the first n rankings, but marks a vote in ranking n + 1. The right side of Figure
3 shows a ballot with a front skip. This ballot also illustrates that a voter can both front and interior skip on
More than overvotes, whether or not a skip results in a voided vote depends on the vote counting rules of
the jurisdiction. Some jurisdictions, like New York City and San Francisco, ignore skips in the tabulation
process and would treat each of the ballots in Figure 3 as if the voter had utilized rankings 1, 2, and 3 and
left blank 4 and 5 (New York City Charter 2023; San Francisco 2023). Alaska and Maine’s vote counting
rules terminate the counting of a ballot if the tabulation algorithm encounters more than one consecutive
skipped ranking. In the case of the ballots in Figure 3, both would be counted under this rule, but if the
In our analysis we consider skips to be a form of improper marking a ballot. The only scenario we can imagine
where a voter would skip rankings for the purpose of expression would be if they ranked a disliked candidate
last, with front or interior skips immediately before. But doing this is also probably an indication that the
voter does not understand the vote tabulation rules, since (depending on their jurisdiction’s rules about
ignoring skipped rankings) it could result in their vote being counted for this extremely disliked candidate.
We believe the population of voters who would cast their ballot in this way and also have sufficient knowledge
about the nuances of ranked choice vote counting is small enough to justify treating all skips as errors that
3.3 Overranking
The final category of ballot marking errors is overrankings, which occurs when a voter selects the same
candidate for more than one ranking. Figure 4 shows two overrankings in the Alaska Senate race. The voter
on the left overranked Murkowski by voting for her as their second and fourth choice. The voter on the right
In contrast to overvoting, which has a high chance of resulting in an uncounted ballot, overranking a candidate
has a much smaller chance of yielding a voided ballot. The ballot on the left of Figure 4 is guaranteed to be
counted, since all named candidates are ranked and the over-ranking of Murkowski occurs after valid rankings
for all other candidates. Whether the ballot on the right of that figure would be counted depends on whether
or not Tshibaka is eliminated, and if the jurisdiction’s election law treats overrankings in choices 2 and 3 as if
It is also worth noting that that (unlike over-voting) over-ranking could be a form of political expression,
rather than a manifestation of voter confusion. Take, for example, a voter who selects the same candidate
for every available ranking and omits all other candidates from their ballot. This pattern could result from
voter confusion, but may also be an expression of a particularly strong preference for this candidate and
dislike of the others. Our data suggest that this type of overranking is the modal pattern of overranking, but
it still makes up a small minority of all overranked ballots. For this reason, we treat all ballots with any
overranking as improperly marked, but all our analyses provide enough detail to allow the reader to interpret
We now turn to assessing the prevalence of each types of marking errors on ranked ballots. To do this, we
utilize cast vote record (CVR) data, which records all markings on a voter’s ballot, rather than just the fina,
aggregate vote totals. Researchers have used CVRs to gain greater insight into voting behaviors such as
ticket splitting (Kuriwaki 2023; Agadjanian and Robinson 2019), party cues in low-information elections (M.
Alvarez, Hall, and Levin 2018), and under/overvoting (Herron and Sekhon 2003). CVRs have also been used
to study aspects of ranked choice voting, such as the prevalence of overvotes (Neely and Cook 2008; Neely
and McDaniel 2015), ballot exhaustion and truncation (Burnett and Kogan 2015; Kilgour, Gregoire, and
Foley 2020), and to compare RCV to other preferential voting methods (McCune and McCune 2022).
For this study, we assembled what we believe to be the largest CVR database of ranked ballots, with about
3 million ballots included. These data span ten election events in four jurisdictions, which when combined
represent approximately 80% of the voters who use RCV(“Where Is Ranked Choice Voting Used?” 2022). In
three of the jurisdictions (Alaska, New York City, and San Francisco) the CVRs provide us ballot marking
information for all offices (ranked choice or single-mark). In Maine, the CVR data only include ranked choice
These jurisdictions are some of the most noteworthy places to have used ranked choice voting in the United
States. In 2002, San Francisco became the first major city to adopt RCV for its local elections (San Francisco
2023). Maine was the first state to adopt RCV for federal primary and general elections and state-level
primary elections in 2018 (Santucci 2018). New York City is the largest US jurisdiction to adopt RCV, using
it for its Mayoral and City Council primary elections since 2021 (Montanaro 2021). And in 2022, Alaska
10 In Alaska, where overranks are treated as skips, the ballot on the right’s vote for Murkowski would not be counted.
11 For this reason, we omit the Maine data from some of our analyses where its inclusion could produce selection bias.
10
2022). Our database includes 100% of counted ballots in Maine, New York City, and San Francisco. The
data in Alaska are over 99.9% complete, with 253 missing ballots in the August 2022 Special Election and
Although the cast vote records do not provide an indication of which ranking was ultimately counted in
the final round of tabulation, we have applied each jurisdiction’s vote counting algorithm to identify the
first-choice and final-counted preference of every voter in every race in our database. In Maine, New York
City, and San Francisco, we perfectly replicate the official vote counts of every round of tabulation for every
office. In Alaska, we almost perfectly replicate the results, and are no more than about 250 votes off (due
to missing data). In our analyses, we omit any races where a single candidate ran unopposed. We also
omit completely undervoted races (i.e. no marks or selections made by the voter for the race), so all of our
estimates of error rates are conditional on a voter having made some sort of mark or selection.
We start by examining improper marking rates on the 3.09 million ballots that voted in the 165 ranked choice
races in our dataset. Figure 5 shows the percentage of voters in each of these races who skipped, overranked,
or overvoted in each race, as well as the percentage who committed at least one of these errors. Each point
in this graph represents one of the 165 elections, colored and shaped based on their electoral jurisdiction
(i.e. AK, ME, NYC, or SF). The x-axis shows the type of improper marking, and the y-axis the percent of
voters who made that error. The small, horizontal, colored bars show the average error rate within each
jurisdiction, and the larger black bars show the error rate (and 95% confidence interval) averaged across
geographies.
The average error rate across jurisdictions was 4.8%, meaning that for a typical ranked-choice race nearly 1
in 20 voters improperly marked their ballot.12 Each jurisdiction had different error rates: rates tended to be
lowest in Alaska, averaging around 2% (1 in 50 voters), and highest in San Francisco and Maine, averaging
around 6.7% (1 in 15 voters). This is particularly noteworthy because it cuts against the idea that improper
marking rates will decrease as voters become more accustomed to voting on a ranked choice ballot. The data
in Alaska are from the first time voters used RCV, while the data from San Francisco come from elections
Figure 5 also reports the rates for each type of error. For an average ranked-choice race, 2.0% of voters front
12 This average error rate is consistent with M. Alvarez, Hall, and Levin (2018), who find the rate of “irrational” candidate
rankings to be 6.43%, 3.84% and 5.33% in the three RCV elections in Pierce County, Washington.
11
or interior skipped somewhere in their rankings for that race. In Alaska, rates of skipping were the lowest at
1.2%, while they were the highest in New York City, at 2.9%.
On average in ranked choice races, 2.4% of voters overranked at least one candidate, with high variance
across jurisdictions. Only about 0.8% (< 1 in 100) of voters overranked in Alaska races, while about 4.4%
(1 in 20) overranked in Maine races. Maine also features one anomalous race (the 2022 ME-02 US House
race) where over 20% of voters overranked their ballot. Most of these overrankings followed the pattern of a
voter choosing the same candidate for every ranking. While this datapoint is certainly an extreme outlier,
its omission only decreases the overall overranking rate from 2.4% to 2.3%. It is also worth noting that the
overranking rates in New York City and Maine are almost certainly underestimates of the true rate because
of how the data are reported. The cast vote records in these jurisdictions do not indicate which candidates
were included in an overvote (the data simply read “overvote” for that ranking), so if a voter overvoted and
The final error type is overvoting, which was the least common improper mark. On average, 0.6% of voters
overvoted at least one of the rankings on a ranked choice race. About 0.2% of voters overvoted in Alaska,
compared to 0.9% in New York City. In addition, we find that around 0.6% of voters overvote in San
12
and McDaniel 2015). While these numbers are certainly smaller than the rates of overranking and skipping,
overvoting is also more likely to yield a voided, uncounted ballot, which we explore further in Section 6.
While these rates may seem relatively small, the CVR data allows us to compare the overvote rate in these
ranked choice races to the overvote rate on the non-ranked choice races from the exact same ballots. Figure 6
shows these rates for the six election dates in which we have ranked choice and non-ranked choice data. The
red lines showing the average overvote rate (and 95% confidence interval) for non-ranked choice races (one
circle for each race) and the blue lines representing the averages (and confidence interval) for ranked choice
races (triangles).
This graph makes clear that although the magnitude of overvoting may seem small, it is extremely high when
compared to the overvote rates typical of single-mark races. Averaging across these six these election dates,
the average overvoting rate for ranked choice races is 0.60%–about 14 times higher than rate in non-ranked
choice races (0.04%).13 Each of the six election events in this graph had a statistically significant (p < .01)
jump in the overvote rate between non-ranked choice and ranked choice races. In NYC’s 2023 election, the
ranked-choice overvote rate was 3.3 times higher than the non-ranked choice rate. In the August 2022 primary
13 In Appendix 8.1, we replicate a finding in Neely and McDaniel (2015), which shows that the number of candidates is a
significant predictor of overvote rates in ranked and non-ranked races. We find, however, that the difference in overvote rate
between ranked and non-ranked races is substantively unchanged whether or not you control for the number of candidates.
13
ranked choice races appear in different locations on the ballot in each geography. In Alaska and New York
City, ranked choice races appear at the top of the ticket, while in San Francisco, they appear below a large
While it is not possible to make similar comparisons to the skip and overranking rates (which are not possible
on single-mark ballots), the findings here suggest that voters are more likely to improperly mark their ballot
when voting in a ranked choice race. We now turn to identifying whether there are other features of the
One of the factors which seems to impact improper marking rates is the number of available rankings for
a given office. In Figure 7, each panel is a different type of improper mark, with the x-axis displaying the
number of candidates a voter could rank.14 The y-axis displays the percent of voters who made the given
error. Each dot is an office, with OLS best-fit lines showing the pattern.
14 Because we only focus on races with at least two candidates on the ballot, and because voters have the opportunity to rank
14
mark their ballot, although this pattern varies by the type of improper mark. For overvotes and skips, a
higher number of potential rankings correlates with significantly higher rates of voter errors. This pattern
holds when all races are pooled together, as well as when including fixed effects for geography.15 .
On the other hand, we do not find a significant bivariate relationship between the number of rankings and the
overranking rate and find a negative significant relationship when controlling for geography. If this finding
is not a spurious one, it would cut against the idea that providing more opportunities to rank candidates
will necessarily translate into higher error rates by voters. Future research should explore whether there is,
perhaps, something fundamentally different about ranked choice races that have just two candidates (plus a
Because of the conflicting directionality of these correlations, when all three types of errors are combined
together, we find no statistically significant relationship between the number of available rankings and the
probability that a voter has any type of improper mark. While this is encouraging, the fact that overvoting
rates increase with the number of candidates is worth considering further. Allowing voters to express more
detailed electoral preferences via the ranking process is touted as one of the normative benefits of ranked
choice voting. But the findings in Figure 7 highlights the cost of voters being more likely to overvote, which
as we show in Section 6 makes it highly likely that their vote will be uncounted.
The second major factor that seems to contribute to improper marking rates is the salience of the office being
elected. Previous research indicates that voters who lack information about candidates are more likely to
roll-off on down-ballot offices (Wattenberg, McAllister, and Salvanto 2000; Lamb and Perry 2020). It also
stands to reason that voters who roll-off for this reason are also the same type of voters who are more likely
to improperly mark their ranked choice ballot. If this hypothesis were true, we would observe that improper
marking rates would be lower for lower salience (down-ballot) races because the voters that attempt to vote
in them tend to be more informed about the election and perhaps politics more generally.
We test this hypothesis using data from the November 2022 Alaska general election. This election provides
a useful test because ranked choice voting was used in Alaska’s high salience US Senate, US House, and
Governor races, as well as for lower salience State House and State Senate races. We expect to find the error
rates in the state legislative races to be lower than those in the three statewide races.
15 For regression tables showing these results, see Appendix Section 8.2
15
Figure 8 reports the ballot improper marking rates among the statewide, State Senate, and State House races.
Each point is an individual race and the horizontal bars (and vertical 95% confidence intervals) mark the
average error rate for each category. The clear pattern in the graph is that for all types of improper marking,
the average error rate is significantly higher for the three statewide races than for the state legislative races.
The overall improper marking rates are, on average, 3.7% in the statewide races and just under 2% for both
State Senate and House races. For skipping, overranking, and overvoting, the error rates in the statewide
races tend to be roughly twice the rates for the state legislative races. This is suggestive evidence in support
of our hypothesis.
To further investigate our hypothesis, we group voters based on whether they voted in their State House and
State Senate race, voted in just voted in one race or the other, and those who voted in neither. Figure 9
shows how the improper marking rates in statewide races differed between these three categories of voters.16
The idea here is that voters who skipped both state legislative races tend to be less politically informed and
thus more likely to make an error when voting for the higher profile statewide races.
The blue squares and 95% confidence intervals represent the improper marking rates of voters who skipped
16We omit the 17% of voters who lived in a State Senate or State House district where there was not a contested election.
16
both state legislative races on their ballot. For every statewide office and every type of improper mark, this
group of voters had higher error rates than the groups who voted in one (green triangles) or both (red circles)
state legislative races. With the exception of skipping in the governor’s race and overranking in the US
Senate race, there is a statistically significant (p < 0.01) difference in the error rates between those who voted
in both state legislative races and those who voted in neither.17 And with the exception of skips, there is a
statistically significant (p < 0.05) difference in the error rates between those who voted in at least one and
These results suggest that the chances that a voter improperly marks their ballot is positively correlated with
their probability of rolling-off in down ballot races. The implication is that improper marks do not happen
randomly–certain types of voters seem to be more likely to do it. Understanding more about who these voters
are (such as their political attitudes or demographic traits) is an important avenue for future research.
17 For a table with these results, see Appendix Section 8.3.
17
In the previous section, we showed that roughly 1-in-20 voters improperly marks their ranked choice ballot
in a way that suggests a misunderstanding about the proper way to fill it out. We also show that for the
one type of improper mark that allows for comparison to single-mark ballots–overvotes–the error rate is
roughly 14 times higher on ranked ballots than single-mark ones. The question we turn to in this section
is whether those high error rates translate into higher rates of ballot rejection. What we find is that while
most improper markings do not result in a rejected ballot, the rejection rate in ranked choice races is still
Figure 10: Rejection rates by error type (among those who made an error)
We begin by assessing the proportion of improperly marked rankings that actually result in the vote not
being counted due to the error. Figure 10 shows the percentage of improperly marked ballots that were not
included in the final-round vote count due to an error.18 In calculating the rejection rates, we omit from the
numerator “exhausted” ballots – those where a voter did not rank at least one of the candidates remaining in
the final round of tabulation–but leave them in the denominator. Excluding them from the denominator
would result in rejection rates that are even higher than those in the figure.
Among the 4.8% of votes that contain any type of improper mark, Figure 10 shows that only 9.8% of them
18 For this graph, the “final-round” vote includes the first round vote in any races that did not take multiple rounds to
determine a winner, as well as final-round votes in races that did require multiple rounds.
18
lower (5.1% and 5.8%, respectively), whereas in Maine and New York City the rates were higher (12.8% and
12.9%, respectively).20
By far, the type of improper mark that is most likely to translate into a rejected ballot is an overvote. Roughly
two-thirds of the time (65.8%) overvoting any ranking for a race results in the ballot being excluded from
the final round tabulation. This is particularly high when you consider that most elections in our data had
a winner determined in the first round of counting. This means that a large proportion of these rejections
Ballots with overrankings are the least likely to be rejected. Only about 1.5% of them result in an uncounted
vote. The jurisdiction with the highest rejection rate of ballots with overrankings was Alaska, with a rejection
rate of just 2.8%. It is important to remember that although we treat overranking as evidence of voter
confusion over the ranked choice system, the rules around tabulating votes would not typically cause a ballot
to be rejected due to overranking. Instead, this 1.5% rejection rate happens because voters who overrank are
also more likely to also skip or overvote on the same office, thus yielding a voided ballot. Appendix Section
8.6 shows that voters who overranked on an office were more than 2.5 times more likely to also overvote,
The final category of improper marks reported in Figure 10 is skips. Voters who skipped a ranking had their
ballots rejected about 5.8% of the time. Maine’s rejection rates are noticeably higher here because of all cast
vote records in Maine come from elections which required more than one round to counting to be resolved.
Interior and many front skips cannot result in a rejected ballot in round 1, and because we do not observe
the CVR data from races resolved in one round of counting, our data in Maine exclude the races where we
would expect the rejection rate to skipped ballots to be lowest. While Maine is an outlier, omitting its data
does not meaningfully change in the overall average rejection rate–it decreases from 5.8% to 4.6%.
What these results highlight is that although the improper marking rates on ranked ballots seem to be high,
about 90% of the time improperly marked ballots are included in the final vote tabulation. However, the
question still remains whether the ranked choice rejection rates are comparable to the rejection rates in
non-ranked choice offices. What we now show is that ranked choice votes are rejected at much higher rates
will result in a ballot rejection. For example, New York City and San Francisco ignore skips in the vote tabulation process.
Second, some improper marks will occur in later rankings than are necessary to determine a winner. If a voter overvotes in
ranking number 3, but their choice for ranking number 1 is the ultimate winner, their vote will still be counted.
20 For comparison, Appendix Section 8.5 includes a version of Figure 10 for voters who did not make each type of improper
mark. All the rejection rates in that figure are zero or extremely close to zero. They are not all exactly zero because it is possible
to not skip on a ballot, but to have it rejected due to overvoting.
19
Figure 11 shows the ballot rejection rates in six election events in our data.21 The circles and red lines
(and vertical 95% confidence intervals) display the percentage of ballots that were rejected for counting in
non-ranked choice races. The triangles and blue lines show the percentage (and CI) of ballots that were
uncounted during the first round of tabulation in all ranked choice races. And the squares and yellow lines
correspond to the final-round rejection rates, but only in the subset of ranked choice offices that required
multiple rounds to determine a winner. The percentages in this figure are considerably smaller than those in
Figure 10 because these include all ballots, whereas those in the previous figure included only votes with
improper marks.
What this figure shows is that in each election event, the average proportion of vote attempts that are rejected
in ranked choice offices is statistically significantly higher than the rejection rate in non-ranked choice offices.
Averaging across the six election events, the average rejection rate in a non-ranked choice race is 0.04%. The
rates in ranked choice races are roughly an order of magnitude higher. In the first round of ranked choice
tabulation the rate is 0.35%, and in the final round of races requiring multiple rounds it is 0.53%. These
differences are noteworthy because these offices appear on the same exact ballots, so the population of voters
21 Maine is excluded because we do not have cast vote records for non-ranked choice races.
20
While this average ballot rejection rate may appear small, it is important to consider that RCV is most
advantageous when there are several candidates with similar levels of support. These are the instances that
provide the strong case for RCV to allow voters to be more detailed in their expression of electoral preference.
But it is these exact circumstances in which high rates of ballot rejection are the most likely to change the
outcome of the election by changing which candidate is eliminated in any round of counting, not just in the
final round. The November 2022 State Senate race in Alaska’s District E provides an example. In the first
round of voting, the three candidates’ vote percentages were 33.84%, 33.12%, and 33.04%. Roselynn Cacy,
the only Democrat in the race, was eliminated in the first round by a margin of 14 votes. In the first round
tally, there were 4 votes that were uncounted due to overvoting and another 9 that were rejected because
of skipping. While this is not enough rejected ballots to change the outcome of the race, it is not hard to
The comparison of rejection rates to non-ranked choice races also provides important context. Take, as an
example, the November 2022 general election in San Francisco. At the top-of-the-ticket, non-ranked choice
race for Governor, there were 59 San Francisco voters (out of about 300k) who attempted to vote (i.e. didn’t
undervote), but had their ballot rejected, and there were 99 voters who had their ballot rejected for single-mark
US Senate race. Compare this to the ranked choice race for San Francisco District Attorney, which had an
unusual amount of media attention due to a successful recall election earlier in the year (Seitz-Wald 2022). In
that race, there were 1,293 voters whose vote attempts were rejected in the first round count, which increased
to 1,569 by the final count as more improper marks were counted in subsequent rounds of tabulation.
Figure 11 also shows interesting heterogenity in rejection rates between Alaska, New York City, and San
Francisco. Despite its voters having used ranked choice voting since 2007, San Francisco’s rejection rate is
significantly higher than Alaska’s, where voters used RCV for the first time in 2022. The ranked choice offices
on San Francisco’s ballot in 2020 and 2022 were also further down-ballot than the ranked choice races on the
Alaska and New York City ballots. Ballot roll-off by less-informed voters may actually be driving down San
Francisco’s RCV rejection rates from where it would be if they used it in top-of-ticket races.
We conclude this section with a deeper dive into San Francisco’s ballot rejection rates. In this analysis, we
depart from using cast vote records and instead analyze vote tabulation reports in all SF elections since 2007
that included at least one ranked choice race.23 Figure 12 shows the difference in rejection rates between
22 Maloy and Ward (2021) use an experiment where subjects are randomly assigned to cast a fake vote using either a ranked
choice or non-ranked choice ballot. They find no difference in the ballot rejection rates between the two groups. The stark
differences in rejection rates in Figure 11 casts doubt on the external validity of the null findings of this experiment.
23 Such an extensive analysis is only possible because the city’s vote certification documents either explicitly include rejected
ballot counts or include enough information to calculate them. Even in non-ranked choice races in other cities and states, it is
21
22
The average first and final round rejection rates for ranked choice races are significantly (p < 0.01) higher
than those for all other types of races. Rejection rates for first-round votes are between 2.5 and 8 times as
high as rejection rates for different types of non-ranked choice offices. In the races that required multiple
rounds of tabulation to resolve, final round rejection rates are about 5 to 16 times as high the non-ranked
choice offices.
On San Francisco ballots, the local elections that use ranked choice voting appear after federal, statewide,
and state legislative races, before any ballot propositions, and generally in the same part of the ballot as
‘Other district offices’ (such as BART Director or municipal judges). The ranked choice offices have rejections
rates that are higher than the offices before and after it on the ballot. This suggests that these differences
are not attributable to a ballot order effect. Instead, we believe the evidence in this graph, as well as our
findings in previous sections, suggests that it is the use of ranked choice voting itself which is resulting in
higher ballot marking mistakes by voters and thus higher ballot rejection rates.
7 Discussion
Voters express their electoral preferences by casting ballots in an election. As American states and cities adopt
ranked choice voting, voters are given the opportunity to express those preferences in a more complex way.
But trade-off to that benefit is that ranked ballots require more complexity than a traditional, single-mark
ballot. We show in this article that this complexity results in roughly one-in-twenty (4.8%) attempted votes
for an office including an improper marking. One type of improper mark—overvotes—is about 14 times more
We also show that giving voters the opportunity to rank more candidates–perhaps the chief benefit of ranked
choice voting–is correlated with higher’ rates of overvoting and skipping. And the data suggest that these
errors are most common among voters who are less engaged with politics and also less likely to vote in
down-ticket races. This implies that ranked choice voting is particularly ill-suited for electoral environments
The normative and policy implications of these high error rates would be worth considering, even if the errors
do not translate into higher rates of rejected ballots. We do find that about 90% of ballots that contain an
error are ultimately included in the vote count. But that is overshadowed by an average ballot rejection rates
on ranked choice races (0.35% in the first round of tabulation) that is nearly ten times that of non-ranked
rare to have enough information to calculate these values.
23
translates into thousands of additional rejected ballots. And when RCV is used in small jurisdictions or in
races with low turnout, margins-of-victory are tight and even modest rejection rates could affect outcomes.
These effects could be even more pernicious if other factors such as ballot exhaustion also affect how voter
The findings in this article open several new avenues for research about ranked choice voting and ballot
marking errors more generally. Our framework for classifying different types of ballot improper marks provides
future researchers with a consistent language for talking about errors on single-mark and ranked ballots.
There are also important questions about the interaction between vote mode (i.e. in-person versus mail
voting), vote technology (hand-marked versus electronic ballots), and improper marking rates in ranked
systems.
Perhaps the biggest avenue for future research is understanding what types of voters tend to make more
errors when presented with a ranked ballot. If, for example, there are differences in improper marking rates
between different racial groups or people with different levels of education, there could be important normative
implications for voter participation and representation in a ranked choice system. If those differences correlate
with partisan differences in ballot rejection rates, then improper marks on ranked choice races could have an
The policy implications of our findings also grow in importance as more jurisdictions consider adopting ranked
choice voting. This article provides important evidence about improper marking rates and vote rejection rates
that, to this point, had been mostly missing from debates about the adoption of RCV. And for jurisdictions
that have already or plan to implement RCV, this work can help inform their choices about administrative
24
8.1 Appendix: Overvote rates by ranked choice races and number of candidates
25
Dependent variable:
Any error Any error Overrank Overrank
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Possible rankings 0.005 −0.003 −0.002 −0.007∗∗∗
(0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.002)
(Intercept) 0.028∗∗ 0.030∗∗ 0.033∗∗∗ 0.033∗∗∗
(0.014) (0.012) (0.009) (0.008)
Geo fixed effects ✓ ✓
Observations 165 165 165 165
R2 0.013 0.289 0.006 0.285
Note: ∗
p<0.1; ∗∗
p<0.05; ∗∗∗
p<0.01
Dependent variable:
Overvote Overvote Skip Skip
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Possible rankings 0.003 ∗∗∗
0.002 ∗∗∗
0.005 ∗∗∗
0.004∗∗
(0.0004) (0.0004) (0.001) (0.001)
(Intercept) −0.006∗∗∗ −0.005∗∗∗ −0.001 −0.001
(0.002) (0.002) (0.006) (0.005)
Geo fixed effects ✓ ✓
Observations 165 165 165 165
R2 0.234 0.439 0.086 0.185
Note: ∗
p<0.1; ∗∗
p<0.05; ∗∗∗
p<0.01
26
Table 4: Error rates of voters who voted in neither state legislative race versus those who voted in both
Table 5: Error rates of voters who voted in neither state legislative race versus those who voted in one
27
The previous analyses treated all ranked choice offices on a ballot as independent data points. But our cast
vote record data allow us to combine together offices that appeared on the same ballot to study error rates
at the voter level. In this section, we assess how common it is for a voter to make an improper marking
Figure 13 displays ballot-level error rates: the proportion of voters who made at least one mistake on at
least one ranked choice race. The x-axis of the graph shows the number of ranked choice offices that a voter
attempted to cast a vote for (whether or not that vote was ultimately counted). This accounts for two things.
First, ballots include different numbers of ranked choice races. Second, even among voters presented with
identical ballots, some voters may have cast a vote in every ranked choice race, while others may skip some of
them. Each line shows how (in a particular state/city) the error rates change with the number of ranked
The figure shows that the percentage of voters who made a any type of mistake in any ranked choice race
ranged from 5.3% (roughly 1-in-18 voters) to 12.6% (roughly 1-in-8), depending on the jurisdiction and the
24We omit Maine because their cast vote records do not allow us to tie together a voter’s choices for separate offices.
28
with between 2.0% and 5.7% of ballots featuring it. Over-voting occurred the least often–between 0.4% and
3.0% of ballots.
29
30
Figure 15 reports how common it is for each type of improper marking to co-occur with the other types of
improper marks. Each panel of the three panels represents one of the three types of improper markings. The
blue bars in the panel represent the voters who did make the panel’s error type, and the red bars represent
voters who did not make that type of error. So, the first blue bar on the far left shows that 1.6% of voters
who overranked also overvoted. The red bar next to it shows that 0.6% of voters who did not overrank, did
overvote.
The general pattern here is that making one type of improper mark increases the probability that a voter
also improperly marked their ballot in a second way. Voters who overvote seem to be the most likely to
commit other types of errors. Looking at the middle panel, we see that 6.9% of people who overvoted also
overranked, compared to just 2.8% of people who did not overvote. And 24.8% of people who overvoted also
skipped a ranking, compared to just 2.0% of those who did not overvote.
31
Split-Ticket Voting with Cast Vote Records Data.” Working Paper. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.
cfm?abstract_id=3443722.
Alvarez, Michael, Thad Hall, and Ines Levin. 2018. “Low-Information Voting: Evidence from Instant-Runoff
Alvarez, R Michael, Dustin Beckett, and Charles Stewart III. 2013. “Voting Technology, Vote-by-Mail, and
Atkeson, Lonna Rae, Eli McKown-Dawson, Jack Santucci, and Kyle L. Saunders. 2023. “The Impact of
Bartholdi, John J, and James B Orlin. 1991. “Single Transferable Vote Resists Strategic Voting.” Social
Bean, Clive. 1997. “Australia’s Experience with the Alternative Vote.” Representation 34 (2): 103–10.
Blais, Andre. 1988. “The Classification of Electoral Systems.” European Journal of Political Research 16 (1).
Burnett, Craig M., and Vladimir Kogan. 2015. “Ballot (and Voter) ‘Exhaustion’ Under Instant Runoff
Clark, Jesse. 2020. “Rank Deficiency? Analyzing the Costs and Benefits of Single-Winner Ranked Choice
Coll, Joseph. 2021. “Demographic Disparities Using Ranked-Choice Voting? Ranking Difficulty, Under-Voting,
and the 2020 Democratic Primary.” Politics and Governance 9 (2): 293–305.
Cottrell, David, Felix E Herron, Michael C Herron, and Daniel A Smith. 2022. “Auditing the 2020 General
Election in Georgia: Residual Vote Rates and a Confusing Ballot Format.” Election Law Journal: Rules,
Crowder-Meyer, Melody, Shana Kushner Gadarian, and Jessica Trounstine. 2023. “Ranking Candidates in
Local Elections: Neither Panacea nor Catastrophe for Candidates of Color.” Journal of Experimental
Curtice, John, and Michael Marsh. 2014. “Confused or Competent? How Voters Use the STV Ballot Paper.”
Donovan, Todd, and Caroline Tolbert. 2023. “Civility in Ranked-Choice Voting Elections: Does Evidence Fit
Donovan, Todd, Caroline Tolbert, and Kellen Gracey. 2019. “Self-Reported Understanding of Ranked-Choice
32
and Utilization of Ranked Choice Voting.” Social Science Quarterly 103 (7): 1539–50.
Graham-Squire, Adam, and David McCune. 2024. “Ranked Choice Wackiness in Alaska.” Math Horizons 31
(1): 24–27.
Graham-Squire, Adam, and N. Zayatz. 2021. “Lack of Monotonicity Anomalies in Empirical Data of
Herron, Michael C., Michael D. Martinez, Marc Meredith, Michael Morse, and Daniel A. Smith. 2023. “A
Typology of Electoral Harms and the 2018 United States Senate Race in Florida.” Working Paper.
Herron, Michael C., and Jasjeet S. Sekhon. 2003. “Overvoting and Representation: An Examination of
Overvoted Presidential Ballots in Broward and Miami-Dade Counties.” Electoral Studies 22 (1): 21–47.
John, Sarah, Haley Smith, and Elizabeth Zack. 2018. “The Alternative Vote: Do Changes in Single-Member
Voting Systems Affect Descriptive Representation of Women and Minorities?” Electoral Studies 54.
Juelich, Courtney, and Joseph Coll. 2021. “Ranked Choice Voting and Youth Voter Turnout: The Roles of
Campaign Civility and Candidate Contact.” Politics and Governance 9 (2): 319–31.
Kilgour, Marc, Jean-Charles Gregoire, and Angele Foley. 2020. “The Prevalence and Consequences of Ballot
Kimball, David C, and Martha Kropf. 2005. “Ballot Design and Unrecorded Votes on Paper-Based Ballots.”
Kropf, Martha. 2021. “Using Campaign Communications to Analyze Civility in Ranked Choice Voting
bvgz3.
Lamb, Matt, and Steven Perry. 2020. “Knowing What You Don’t Know: The Role of Information and
Maloy, Jason Stuart. 2019. Smarter Ballots: Electoral Realism and Reform. Springer.
Maloy, Jason Stuart, and Matthew Ward. 2021. “The Impact of Input Rules and Ballot Options on Voting
McCune, David, and Lori McCune. 2022. “Does the Choice of Preferential Voting Method Matter? An
Empirical Study Using Ranked Choice Elections in the United States.” Representation 0 (0): 1–16.
McCune, David, and Jennifer Wilson. 2023. “Ranked-Choice Voting and the Spoiler Effect.” Public Choice.
McDaniel, Jason. 2016. “Writing the Rules to Rank the Candidates: Examining the Impact of Instant-Runoff
Voting on Racial Group Turnout in San Francisco Mayoral Elections.” Journal of Urban Affairs 38 (3).
33
Ranked-Choice Voting in Mayoral Elections.” California Journal of Politics and Policy 10 (2).
Miller, Nicholas R. 2017. “Closeness Matters: Monotonicity Failure in IRV Elections with Three Candidates.”
Montanaro, Domenico. 2021. “Ranked-Choice Voting Gets a Prime-Time Shot Under New York City’s
mayors-race.
Mott, Rodney L. 1926. “Invalid Ballots Under the Hare System of Proportional Representation.” American
Neely, Francis, and Corey Cook. 2008. “Whose Votes Count?: Undervotes, Overvotes, and Ranking in San
Neely, Francis, and Jason McDaniel. 2015. “Overvoting and the Equality of Voice Under Instant-Runoff
New York City Charter. 2023. “Section 1057-g. Ranked Choice Voting for Certain Primary Elections and
Elections for Which Nominations Were Made by Independent Nominating Petitions.” https://codelibrary.
amlegal.com/codes/newyorkcity/latest/NYCcharter/0-0-0-3079.
Rae, Douglas W. 1967. The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws. Yale University Press.
Santucci, Jack. 2018. “Maine Ranked-Choice Voting as a Case of Electoral-System Change.” Representation
54 (3): 297–311.
———. 2021. “Variants of Ranked-Choice Voting from a Strategic Perspective.” Politics and Governance 9
(2): 344–53.
“Sarah Palin’s Defeat in Alaska Proves Ranked-Choice Voting Works.” 2022. The Washington Post. https:
//www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/2022/09/05/sarah-palin-alaska-ranked-choice-works/.
Seitz-Wald, Alex. 2022. “California Voters Oust Reformist DA in San Francisco as House Battlegrounds
primary-elections-rcna32276.
Shabad, Rebecca. 2022. “After Sarah Palin’s Election Loss, Sen. Tom Cotton Calls Ranked-Choice Voting ’a
cotton-calls-ranked-choice-voting-s-rcna45834.
Sinclair, Betsy, and R Michael Alvarez. 2004. “Who Overvotes, Who Undervotes, Using Punchcards?
Evidence from Los Angeles County.” Political Research Quarterly 57 (1): 15–25.
Stewart, Charles, R. Michael Alvarez, Stephen S. Pettigrew, and Cameron Wimpy. 2020. “Abstention,
34
Terrell, Cynthia Richie, Courtney Lamendola, and Maura Reilly. 2021. “Election Reform and Women’s
Representation: Ranked Choice Voting in the u.s.” Politics and Governance 9 (2): 332–43.
Thiessen, Mark. 2022. “What’s Next for Ranked-Choice Voting After Alaska?” NBC News. https:
//www.nbcnews.com/meet-the-press/meetthepressblog/s-ranked-choice-voting-alaska-rcna45929.
Tomlinson, Kiran, Johan Ugander, and Jon Kleinberg. 2022. “Ballot Length in Instant Runoff Voting.”
Tucker, Jill, Jordan Parker, J. D. Morris, and Nami Sumida. 2022. “Alameda County Admits Tallying
Error in Ranked-Choice Voting, Flips One Result and Raises Big Questions.” San Francisco Chronicle.
https://www.sfchronicle.com/bayarea/article/Alameda-County-admits-tallying-error-in-17682520.php.
Wand, Jonathan N., Kenneth W. Shotts, Jasjeet S. Sekhon, Walter R. Mebane, Michael C. Herron, and
Henry E. Brady. 2001. “The Butterfly Did It: The Aberrant Vote for Buchanan in Palm Beach County,
Wattenberg, Martin P., Ian McAllister, and Anthony Salvanto. 2000. “How Voting Is Like Taking an Sat
Test: An Analysis of American Voter Rolloff.” American Politics Quarterly 28 (2): 234–50.
voting-information/#where-is-ranked-choice-voting-used.
Williams, Jack, Samuel Baltz, and Charles III Stewart. 2023. “Administering Instant Runoff Voting Elections:
35