0% found this document useful (0 votes)
17 views18 pages

Wages and Prices: Past, Present, and Future

This document is Governor Ueda Kazuo's speech at a meeting of the Japan Business Federation discussing wages and prices in Japan over the past, present, and future. It summarizes that in the late 1990s, Japan entered a prolonged period of low inflation and wage growth as downward pressures from economic stagnation, globalization and demographic changes took hold. This entrenched expectations that wages and prices would not increase, making it difficult for firms to raise prices even if costs increased. Now, global inflationary pressures are pushing Japan's inflation above 2% annually, but changes may be needed for wages and prices to sustainably increase going forward.

Uploaded by

yp58qm4n7r
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
17 views18 pages

Wages and Prices: Past, Present, and Future

This document is Governor Ueda Kazuo's speech at a meeting of the Japan Business Federation discussing wages and prices in Japan over the past, present, and future. It summarizes that in the late 1990s, Japan entered a prolonged period of low inflation and wage growth as downward pressures from economic stagnation, globalization and demographic changes took hold. This entrenched expectations that wages and prices would not increase, making it difficult for firms to raise prices even if costs increased. Now, global inflationary pressures are pushing Japan's inflation above 2% annually, but changes may be needed for wages and prices to sustainably increase going forward.

Uploaded by

yp58qm4n7r
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 18

December 25, 2023

Bank of Japan

Wages and Prices: Past, Present, and Future

Speech at the Meeting of Councillors of Keidanren


(Japan Business Federation) in Tokyo

UEDA Kazuo
Governor of the Bank of Japan

(English translation based on the Japanese original)


Introduction
It is a great honor to have this opportunity to address such a distinguished gathering of
business leaders in Japan today.

Last year in his speech at the Keidanren meeting, former Bank of Japan Governor Kuroda
pointed out that we were "approaching a critical juncture in breaking out of the prolonged
period of low inflation and low growth." Looking back on 2023, it was indeed a year that
saw moves toward a transition. Japan's economy has turned to a moderate recovery, mainly
reflecting the normalization of economic activity and a waning of supply-side constraints,
and the output gap has improved to around 0 percent. Japan's inflation rate, measured in
terms of the consumer price index (CPI), has continued to exceed 2 percent. This is mainly
due to a pass-through of the past rise in import prices to consumer prices, but with
economic improvement, some changes have been seen in firms' wage- and price-setting
behavior. Given these changes, the likelihood of Japan's economy getting out of the
low-inflation environment that it has been in over the past 25 years and achieving the
Bank's price stability target of 2 percent in a sustainable and stable manner seems to be
gradually rising.

Today, I would like to talk about recent price and wage developments, which are closely
related. In assessing the current situation of wages and prices and predicting their future, it
is essential to consider the issue of why the situation in which wages and prices do not
increase easily has continued to this day. Therefore, let me begin with reflections on the
past.

I. The Past: Overview of and Background to the Low-Inflation Environment


Changes in the Wage and Price Situation in the Late 1990s
First, let me turn the clock back 25 years to the late 1990s. Wages and prices in Japan
continued to rise, albeit slightly, until around the mid-1990s. In the late 1990s, the
year-on-year rates of change turned 0 or negative (Chart 1).

Regarding changes seen in the late 1990s, not only did the aggregate rate of inflation fall to
around 0 percent, but data at a more micro level show that the tendency of firms to keep

1
prices unchanged had strengthened for many items to a considerable degree. It is natural for
prices of individual items to rise and fall in accordance with their costs and demand; from
the mid-1990s, however, the share of items for which prices were unchanged increased and
the frequency of price revisions declined, especially for services in these two cases (Chart
2). Similarly, when it comes to wages, the practice of increasing base pay fell by the
wayside at many firms. Wage growth slowed as, in addition to the fact that inflation
declined, labor and management cooperated in prioritizing job retention under the difficult
economic environment. These changes can be summarized as a shift from a state in which
wages and prices move to one in which they do not. Although wage growth and price
inflation also declined in the United States and Europe during this period, prices were still
being revised to some extent, and there was no major shift toward a situation in which firms
kept wages and prices unchanged.

Entrenchment of the Low-Inflation Environment


So, why did low inflation become entrenched in society and why did wages and prices stop
moving in Japan? I think the basic background is that various downward pressures on
wages and prices were operating for a long time.

In other words, the economic stagnation lasted for a prolonged period from the late 1990s,
due to the protracted balance-sheet adjustment pressure following the collapse of the bubble
economy and to Japan's financial crisis resulting from that collapse and the subsequent
decline in the functioning of financial intermediation. In the mid-2000s, the economy
finally began to recover in earnest and the output gap turned positive for a while (Chart 3).
Thereafter, however, Japan underwent a series of large shocks, including the Global
Financial Crisis and the Great East Japan Earthquake, and its economic activity and prices
were thus pushed down again.

While Japan's economy intermittently came under strong downward pressure from the
demand side, it should not be overlooked that structural changes, such as demographic
changes and globalization, continued to push down wages and prices. The declining
population likely pushed down expectations of growth in domestic demand and acted to
restrain factors such as business fixed investment. In some respects, advances in

2
globalization also exerted downward pressure on wages and prices. While the growth of
emerging economies created new markets, it also intensified international competition.
Price competition from low-priced imports had a large impact on Japan, mainly due to its
industrial structure and geographic position. Moreover, analyses using firms' financial data
suggest that, as firms' price competitiveness in product markets declined, it became difficult
for them to add increases in costs, such as of raw materials, to selling prices, forcing them
to hold down wages (Chart 4).1

Given the downward pressure on wages and prices, the Bank of Japan became the first
central bank in the world to adopt unconventional monetary easing measures, such as the
introduction of quantitative easing in the early 2000s, and endeavored to prevent, for
example, the economy from falling into a marked slowdown, concern over financial system
stability from growing, and prices from declining significantly. However, with short-term
interest rates -- the main monetary policy tool -- having fallen to 0 percent, there was
limited room for reducing interest rates, so the Bank could not sufficiently stimulate the
economy and bring wage growth and price inflation back into clearly positive territory.

As the rates of change in wages and prices remained at around 0 percent, as just described,
this may have gradually increased people's expectation that wages and prices would
continue not to move. With customers keeping a keen eye on prices and given that
competitors were unlikely to choose to raise prices, it was difficult for firms -- even if their

1
Fukunaga, Kido, and Suita (2023) show that shocks originating abroad pushed down prices in
Japan from the 1990s through the 2010s. Similarly, Aoki, Hogen, and Takatomi (2023) and Hogen et
al. (2023) show that, under the severe competitive environment, Japanese firms' price markups
shrank and downward pressure on wages intensified to make up for this.
Fukunaga, I., Kido, Y., and Suita, K., "Japan's Inflation and Global Inflation Synchronization,"
mimeo (2023).
Aoki, K., Hogen, Y., and Takatomi, K., "Price Markups and Wage Setting Behavior of Japanese
Firms," Bank of Japan Working Paper Series, no. 23-E-5 (April 2023).
Hogen, Y. et al., "Changes in the Global Economic Landscape and Issues for the Japanese
Economy," mimeo (2023).

3
costs had risen somewhat -- to opt to be the only ones to raise prices.2 As you may recall,
there were even cases in which a price hike by a single firm made headlines. When not
raising prices becomes the norm, the barriers to raising prices become even higher. In
macroeconomics, the costs that firms incur when revising prices are called "menu costs."
While the term menu costs originally comes from the costs that restaurants incur when
changing the prices of their dishes, firms incur a variety of costs when actually raising
prices, including explaining and negotiating price rises to and with customers. In Japan, in a
situation where, for example, firms kept prices unchanged for a prolonged period and the
know-how for raising prices was thus lost, menu costs may have become quite large, and
this may have been one of the factors that led to the entrenchment of a state in which prices
did not move. As it became the norm for wages and prices not to move, in the second half of
the 2010s, increases in wages and prices remained small even as the output gap continued to
be positive and labor market conditions became increasingly tight.

II. The Present: Changes in the Wage and Price Situation and the Bank's Thinking on
the Conduct of Monetary Policy
Global Upward Pressure on Prices
Next, let me turn the clock forward to the present. After the impact of the COVID-19
pandemic waned in 2021, inflation rose rapidly around the world. This was the result of a
rapid recovery in demand following the normalization of economic activity, coupled with
supply-side constraints, which were mainly due to supply-chain disruptions, and high
commodity prices following Russia's invasion of Ukraine. In the United States and the euro
area, year-on-year inflation rates at one point registered around 10 percent, and in Japan --
with the significant increase in the cost of imported raw materials being transmitted with a
lag -- the inflation rate has continued to exceed 2 percent since spring last year. The shock

2
In this context, Sasaki, Yamamoto, and Nakajima (2023) find that, in Japan, there is a nonlinearity
in the impact (pass-through) of increases in firms' input costs on the rate of CPI inflation, depending
on the size of cost increases. Moreover, using microdata from the Tankan (Short-Term Economic
Survey of Enterprises in Japan), Ikeda et al. (2023) show that firms tend not to raise selling prices
even if costs rise when their competitors do not raise prices.
Sasaki, T., Yamamoto, H., and Nakajima, J., "Nonlinear Input Cost Pass-Through to Consumer
Prices: A Threshold Approach," Bank of Japan Working Paper Series, no. 23-E-9 (May 2023).
Ikeda, S. et al., "Firms' Recent Price-Setting Stance: Evidence from the Tankan," Bank of Japan
Review Series, no. 23-E-2 (February 2023).

4
of rising import prices has brought about a major change in firms' price-setting behavior, at
least in the short term, as seen in the fact that even firms that had long kept their selling
prices unchanged have raised them (Chart 5).

So, the question is whether the state in which wages and prices do not move has truly
become a thing of the past. The first notable point is that the year-on-year rate of change in
import prices, which have led the recent price rises, has been negative since around spring
this year and that the rate of increase in producer prices has decelerated to around 0 percent
recently. Looking at the CPI, the rates of increase in prices of goods such as food and daily
necessities have started to decelerate. Given these developments, although it will take time,
the effects of the past rise in import prices pushing up overall prices are likely to gradually
wane.

Virtuous Cycle between Wages and Prices


As the impact of the rise in import prices wanes, an important issue in assessing whether
wages and prices have started to move is whether the recent changes in firms' behavior will
be sustained. The recent price rises are attributable to the unusual situation of the surge in
import prices, and some argue that wages and prices will stop moving again if the impact of
this surge wanes. However, I expect that this time around, Japan's economy will get out of
the low-inflation environment and achieve a virtuous cycle between wages and prices.

In the past, there were times when moves to raise prices did not become widespread, as
improving trends in the economy were cut short by declines in corporate profits and
household income due to rising costs of imported raw materials. In contrast, during the
current phase, demand has been underpinned by, for example, the government's economic
measures and the Bank's continuation of monetary easing, thus providing support for
achieving a virtuous cycle between wages and prices. A major difference from the past is
that, in this situation, corporate profits have improved and set a record high.

Moreover, changes have also been seen in some of the factors that have exerted structural
downward pressure on wages and prices thus far, such as demographic developments and
globalization. It remains the case that the aging and declining population tends to act to curb

5
growth expectations for domestic demand. However, the pace of increase in labor supply,
especially among seniors, is projected to slow, in part because the baby boomer generation
is approaching the age of 75, a level beyond which the labor force participation rate
declines significantly (Chart 6). This is expected to act as a factor leading to higher wages.
As for globalization, at least the environment in which competition from low-priced imports
from abroad pushes down prices has started to change. From a somewhat long-term
perspective, it is necessary to keep an eye on the possibility that supply-side shocks to
prices are changing in frequency, persistence, and nature due to factors such as (1) moves
toward strengthening supply chains and economic security in countries around the world,
(2) firms' efforts toward addressing climate change, and (3) heightened awareness of other
environmental, social, and governance issues, and that these changes are affecting the
global price environment.

In fact, firms' price-setting stance and indicators of inflation expectations show that there
has also been a change in the medium- to long-term outlook, and a view that changes in the
wage and price situation are not temporary appears to be gradually becoming widespread.
Firms have maintained their outlook for selling prices that prices will rise firmly over the
medium term despite a decline in import prices. Similarly, indicators of medium- to
long-term inflation expectations show that inflation expectations have risen moderately
among all groups -- firms, households, and economists (Chart 7). Moreover, some firms
reported that, having experienced a price hike for the first time in a long time, they will find
it easier to negotiate price revisions in the future. This suggests that the menu costs I
mentioned earlier may be getting smaller.

Key Points for the Future


In sum, the likelihood of Japan's economy getting out of the low-inflation environment and
achieving the price stability target is gradually rising. However, I should note that this
likelihood is still not sufficiently high at this point. Since there are extremely high
uncertainties surrounding economic activity and prices at home and abroad, it is necessary
to examine how firms' wage- and price-setting behavior will change.

6
In terms of wage setting, the key point is whether wages will continue to rise markedly in
next year's annual spring labor-management wage negotiations. Looking at the recent
situation surrounding wages, labor market conditions have tightened even relative to last
year (Chart 8). Corporate profits, which are the source of wage hikes, have increased due to
improvement in economic activity, progress in the pass-through of cost increases to selling
prices, and the yen's depreciation. Meanwhile, the labor share seems to have declined
recently (Chart 9). Although a pass-through of higher raw material prices to selling prices is
necessary to secure corporate profits, price rises due to this pass-through mean an increase
in the burden of households. In order for the economy to see a sustained recovery led by
domestic demand and for the virtuous cycle between wages and prices to intensify, it is
essential that the increase in corporate profits lead to improvement in household income.

Therefore, in terms of price setting, the key is whether firms will be able to reflect increases
in costs besides raw material costs, such as wages and indirect costs, in selling prices. If
firms cannot reflect wage increases in selling prices to a certain extent, the virtuous cycle
between wages and prices will not last long. On this point, attention should be paid to the
fact that the year-on-year rate of increase in prices of services, for which labor costs account
for a large share in total costs, has gradually accelerated recently. However, what we have
heard from firms gives me the impression that many of them still consider it difficult to pass
on higher labor costs to selling prices (Chart 10). Recently, the government formulated
guidelines on price negotiations for an appropriate pass-through of labor costs, and its
impact on firms' price-setting behavior warrants attention.

The Bank's Thinking on the Conduct of Monetary Policy


Next, I will briefly explain the Bank's thinking on the conduct of monetary policy given the
wage and price developments just described. To this day, the Bank has patiently continued
with monetary easing while striking a balance between its positive effects and side effects.
This policy response may seem in contrast to responses taken by central banks in the United
States and Europe, which had raised policy interest rates substantially to address the rapid
increase in inflation.

7
The most significant factor behind the difference in policy responses between these central
banks and the Bank of Japan is the divergence in the situation surrounding prices and wages.
The central banks in the United States and Europe had taken a wait-and-see approach when
prices began to rise, based on the assessment that the rises were "frictions" associated with
the resumption of economic activity following the pandemic. Thereafter, however, with
further upward pressure on wages, for which developments had been generally consistent
with the 2 percent inflation, they became vigilant against the risk of a wage-price spiral and
thus significantly raised their policy interest rates. On the other hand, as I emphasized
earlier in this speech, Japan had remained in a situation where wages and prices did not
move. In order to turn the situation around and achieve sustainable and stable inflation
accompanied by wage increases, the Bank of Japan has patiently continued with monetary
easing.

That said, if the virtuous cycle between wages and prices intensifies and the likelihood of
achieving the price stability target of 2 percent in a sustainable and stable manner rises
sufficiently, the Bank will likely consider changing its monetary policy. Given the
uncertainties surrounding economies and financial markets at home and abroad, the timing
of a policy change is yet to be decided. The Bank will carefully examine economic
developments as well as firms' wage- and price-setting behavior, and thereby decide on
future monetary policy in an appropriate manner.

III. The Future: Price Stability, Firms, and the Economy


Moderate Inflation and Room for Policy Responses
So far, I have looked back on the past and talked about recent changes in the wage and price
situation in Japan. Now, I will turn the clock forward to the future. By "future," I'm
referring to a state in which the virtuous cycle between wages and prices will have been
achieved. I would like to consider what this cycle would mean to firms and Japan's
economy as a whole.

In standard economics, the most obvious benefit of a slightly positive inflation rate is larger
room for monetary policy responses to an economic downturn. The primary transmission
channel of monetary easing is lowering interest rates to stimulate economic activity. When

8
inflation continues to be 0, nominal interest rates accordingly are low and there is little
room for reducing them further. In contrast, in a state in which the inflation rate continues to
be positive, nominal interest rates are higher, providing room to substantially lower interest
rates if necessary. It is considered that conducting monetary policy effectively reduces the
risk of the economy deteriorating significantly or reverting to deflation. This view is widely
accepted around the world, and I believe that greater economic stability as a result of
securing room for monetary policy responses will have a significant positive effect on firms
as they formulate their business plans.

Effects on Resource Allocation and Other Factors


Moreover, based on Japan's experience, I think that, if wages and prices start to move, this
will likely add to the positive effect just mentioned on the overall economy.

As I have explained today, a key feature of the low-inflation environment that Japan fell
into was the strong bias toward the status quo in wage- and price-setting behavior, which
resulted in prices of many items being unchanged. This meant that relative prices between
individual goods were less likely to change and the market's price discovery function was
less effective. As a result, it may have become inefficient to allocate resources, which may
have led to reduced productivity of the economy as a whole. The same is true for wages.
While I believe that it was important to maintain employment during difficult times by
freezing base pay and cutting bonuses, if a situation where wages do not increase easily
continues even after these difficult times pass, the allocation of labor and changes in the
wage system will become static. If the situation becomes such that wages increase every
year, this could lead to more efficient allocation of labor through setting wages flexibly. In
this regard, changes have been seen recently as the labor market has tightened, such as an
increasingly active labor market for regular employees looking for new jobs. These
developments are also expected to benefit the economy as a whole, as they promote the
appropriate allocation of human resources to areas where they are most needed.

9
Impact on Firms' Behavior
So, how will this movement in wages and prices affect the business community? 3 As part
of its review of monetary policy from a broad perspective, which was initiated this spring,
the Bank of Japan is currently conducting a large-scale survey of firms. In the survey, it is
asking firms about whether and why a state in which wages and prices move or do not move
is preferable for them, as well as common questions regarding their views on corporate
behavior over the past 25 years and recent changes in this behavior. Many of the firms
represented by you have also participated in the survey, and I would like to thank you for
your cooperation.

While the Bank aims to understand the views of the business community through such
dialogue, one possible hypothesis at this time is that, in a state in which wages and prices
move in general, it will be easier for individual firms to do so as well. For example, if
wages and prices move, it may be easier than in the past for firms to be more flexible in
their wage and price setting and their product strategies when formulating business plans.
There is no shortage of issues and topics for firms to address, such as digitalization and
labor saving amid the expected continuation of labor shortages, decarbonization and other
climate change responses, and strengthening supply chains. In this new environment, if
firms take these issues as a business opportunity and show a higher tendency to move
proactively, the positive impact should permeate throughout the economy.

Of course, the shift to a state in which wages and prices move will present new challenges
for firms. Whether it is recruiting and retaining employees or developing pricing and
product strategies, firms may need to find different approaches than what they have taken
thus far, including investment in new groups of people and resources. I strongly hope that
firms will take full advantage of the benefits that should arise in a state in which a virtuous
cycle between wages and prices is achieved, and that they will strengthen their positive
moves.

3
While there are not many theoretical or empirical studies examining this effect, one example is a
series of studies by Professor Watanabe Tsutomu of the University of Tokyo on the effects of low
inflation and a deflationary environment on the economy and firms' behavior. See, for example,
Watanabe, T. and Watanabe, K., "Defure-ki ni okeru kakaku no kōchokuka: Gen'in to gan'i," Bank of
Japan Working Paper Series, no. 16-J-2 (February 2016) (available only in Japanese).

10
Concluding Remarks
The time for my speech is running out. Today, I talked about the past, present, and future of
the wage and price situation in Japan.

I would like to conclude my speech by turning the clock to the present again. Firms' wage-
and price-setting behavior is changing and the likelihood of achieving the price stability
target of 2 percent in a sustainable and stable manner is gradually rising. In order to ensure
these developments, the Bank has patiently continued with monetary easing, aiming to
facilitate a favorable environment for wage increases. Going forward, it will carefully
examine economic developments and closely monitor whether the virtuous cycle between
wages and prices will intensify -- in other words, whether wages will be raised in reflection
of price rises and such wage increases will be reflected in selling prices. By doing so, the
Bank aims to appropriately assess whether the price stability target has been achieved in a
sustainable and stable manner.

Thank you very much for your attention.

11
Wages and Prices: Past, Present, and Future
Speech at the Meeting of Councillors of Keidanren
(Japan Business Federation) in Tokyo

December 25, 2023


UEDA Kazuo
Governor of the Bank of Japan

Introduction
I. The Past: Overview of and Background to the Low-
Inflation Environment
II. The Present: Changes in the Wage and Price Situation
and the Bank's Thinking on the Conduct of Monetary
Policy
III. The Future: Price Stability, Firms, and the Economy

Concluding Remarks
I. The Past: Overview of and Background to the Low-Inflation Environment Chart 1

Wages and Prices


y/y % chg.
8

6
CPI (less fresh food)

4 Nominal wages

-2

-4
FY 80 85 90 95 00 05 10 15 20

Notes: 1. The CPI figures are staff estimates and exclude the effects of the consumption tax hikes, policies concerning the provision of free education, and travel subsidy programs. Figures for
nominal wages are for establishments with 30 or more employees up through fiscal 1990, and with 5 or more employees from fiscal 1991 onward.
2. Figures for fiscal 2023 are April-October averages.
Sources: Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications; Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare.
1

I. The Past: Overview of and Background to the Low-Inflation Environment Chart 2

Price-Setting Trends
Price Change Distribution Frequency of Price Changes

share of the number of items, % %


40 16
Goods
35 14
Services
30 Dec. 2018 12

Dec. 1999
25 10
Dec. 1992
20 8

15 6

10 4

5 2

0 0
-10 -5 0 5 10 15 20 CY 91 95 99 03 07 11 15 19 23
or less or more
y/y % chg.
Notes: 1. In the left-hand chart, figures are based on the CPI for all items less fresh food.
2. In the right-hand chart, figures are the share of prices (based on the average for each item and city) that changed from the previous month (12-month backward moving average).
Data excludes fresh food, electricity, manufactured and piped gas, water charges, housing rent, periods of consumption tax hikes, and temporary price changes mainly due to special sales.
Source: Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications.
2
I. The Past: Overview of and Background to the Low-Inflation Environment Chart 3

Output Gap

6 %
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3
-4
-5
-6
-7
CY 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 20 22

Note: Figures are staff estimates.


Source: Bank of Japan.
3

I. The Past: Overview of and Background to the Low-Inflation Environment Chart 4

Impact of Globalization
Prices and Overseas Factors Changes in Wage and Price Setting
y/y % chg. ratio ratio
5 1.3 2.2

↑Wage surpression
4 Others

Overseas factors 1.2 1.8


3
CPI (less fresh food and energy)

2
1.1 1.4
1
↓Selling price surpression

0
1.0 1.0

-1 Price markups (left scale)

Wage markdowns (right scale)


-2 0.9 0.6
CY 97 99 01 03 05 07 09 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 FY 95 00 05 10 15 20
Notes: 1. In the left-hand chart, shocks are identified by combining short- and long-term zero and sign restrictions using a structural VAR model with domestic and international macro data.
2. In the right-hand chart, figures are estimated based on the approach used by Aoki, Hogen, and Takatomi (2023).
Price markups = Output prices / Marginal costs, and Wage markdowns = Marginal revenue product of labor / Marginal wage costs.
Sources: Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications; Bank of Japan; Development Bank of Japan (DBJ); Cabinet Office.
4
II. The Present: Changes in the Wage and Price Situation and the Bank's Thinking on the Conduct of Monetary Policy Chart 5

Consumer Prices and Output Prices


Consumer Prices in Japan, Pass-Through of
the United States, and the Euro Area Cost Increases to Output Prices
y/y % chg. output prices DI ("rise" - "fall"), % points
12 50
Japan Firms cautious about changing output prices
40
10
United States 30 Other firms
"Rise"
8 Euro area 20 ↑

10 "Fall"
6
0
4
-10

2 -20

-30
0
-40

-2 -50
CY 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 CY 91 93 95 97 99 01 03 05 07 09 11 13 15 17 19 21 23
Notes: 1. In the left-hand chart, figures for Japan are the CPI for all items less fresh food, excluding the effects of the consumption tax hike, while those for the United States and the euro area are
the CPIs for all items.
2. In the right-hand chart, figures are based on the Tankan (all industries and enterprises). Figures for "firms cautious about changing output prices" are for firms that for at least about
95 percent of the period from 1991 to 2019 replied that their output prices were "unchanged."
Sources: Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications; Haver; Bank of Japan.
5

II. The Present: Changes in the Wage and Price Situation and the Bank's Thinking on the Conduct of Monetary Policy Chart 6

Structural Changes in the Labor Market


Population by Age Group Labor Force Participation Rate
by Age Group
140 mil. persons 100 %

90
120
80

100 70
75-
60
80
65-74
50
60 20-64
40
0-19
40 30

20
20
10

0 0
CY 1995
15-19
20-24
25-29
30-34
35-39
40-44
45-49
50-54
55-59
60-64
65-69
70-74

2010 2025
75-

age group

Notes: 1. In the left-hand chart, figures are based on the Population Pyramid for Japan released by the National Institute of Population and Social Security Research.
2. In the right-hand chart, figures are based on the Labour Force Survey (2022).
Sources: National Institute of Population and Social Security Research; Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications.
6
II. The Present: Changes in the Wage and Price Situation and the Bank's Thinking on the Conduct of Monetary Policy Chart 7

Changes in Price-Setting Behavior


Firms' Outlook for Output Prices in the Tankan Inflation Expectations
Manufacturing Nonmanufacturing
chg. from the current level, % y/y, ann. avg., %
5.0 chg. from the current level, % 5.0 2.5
Economists 1 (6 to 10 years ahead)
4.5 4.5
Economists 2 (7 to 11 years ahead)
4.0 4.0 Households (over the next 5 years)
2.0
3.5 1 year ahead 3.5 1 year ahead Firms (5 years ahead)

3.0 5 years ahead 3.0 5 years ahead


1.5
2.5 2.5

2.0 2.0
1.0
1.5 1.5

1.0 1.0

0.5 0.5 0.5

0.0 0.0

-0.5 -0.5 0.0


CY 14 16 18 20 22 CY 14 16 18 20 22 CY 05 07 09 11 13 15 17 19 21 23
Note: In the right-hand chart, "Economists 1" shows the forecasts of economists in the Consensus Forecasts, while "Economists 2" shows the forecasts of forecasters surveyed for the ESP
Forecast. Figures for households are from the Opinion Survey on the General Public's Views and Behavior, estimated using the modified Carlson-Parkin method for a 5-choice question.
Figures for firms show the inflation outlook of enterprises for general prices (all industries and enterprises, average) in the Tankan.
Sources: Bank of Japan; JCER, "ESP Forecast"; Consensus Economics Inc., "Consensus Forecasts."
7

II. The Present: Changes in the Wage and Price Situation and the Bank's Thinking on the Conduct of Monetary Policy Chart 8

Labor Market Conditions


Firms' Perception of Firms' Perception of
Labor Shortage Labor Shortage by Employment Status
inverted, DI ("excessive" -
% 3 DI ("shortage" - "surplus"), % points
-40 "insufficient"), % points 50
"Insufficient" "Shortage"
2
-30
40
1
"Excessive" "Surplus"
-20
0 30

-10 -1
20
0 -2

-3 10
10 Regular employees, etc.
-4 Part-time employees
Employment conditions DI (left scale) 0
20
-5
Output gap (right scale)
30 -6 -10
CY 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 CY 10 12 14 16 18 20 22

Notes: 1. In the left-hand chart, the employment conditions DI figures are based on the Tankan.
2. In the right-hand chart, figures are the DIs for firms' employment conditions in the Survey on Labour Economy Trend.
Sources: Bank of Japan; Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare. 8
II. The Present: Changes in the Wage and Price Situation and the Bank's Thinking on the Conduct of Monetary Policy Chart 9

Corporate Profits and Labor Share


Current Profits Labor Share

16 s.a., tril. yen 76 4-quarter backward moving avg., %


Large firms
14
Small and medium-sized firms 74

12
72
10
70
8
68
6

66
4

2 64

0 62
CY 08 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 CY 08 10 12 14 16 18 20 22

Notes: 1. Figures are based on the Financial Statements Statistics of Corporations by Industry, Quarterly and exclude "finance and insurance." Figures from 2009/Q2 onward exclude pure
holding companies.
2. In the right-hand chart, Labor share = Personnel expenses / Value-added, and Value-added = Operation profits + Personnel expenses + Depreciation expenses.
Source: Ministry of Finance.
9

II. The Present: Changes in the Wage and Price Situation and the Bank's Thinking on the Conduct of Monetary Policy Chart 10

Developments in Prices
Consumer Price Index Passing on Higher Labor Costs
(Goods/Services) to Output Prices
Firms experiencing difficulty in passing on higher labor costs
y/y % chg. to output prices
8
• We have been forced to pass on increases in raw material
costs to our output prices and have continued to raise prices.
7 On the other hand, we have absorbed higher labor costs by
Goods raising productivity and have not passed them on to output
6 prices (eating and drinking).
General services • Further output price hikes could lead to a decline in demand.
Given the ongoing labor shortages, we intend to continue
5 raising wages from next spring onward but plan to keep
prices unchanged (hotel).
4 • Although upward pressure on labor costs has continued,
since we are concerned about losing customers, we do not
3 plan to pass on higher labor costs to output prices (services
for individuals).

2 Firms making progress in passing on higher labor costs to


output prices
1 • We plan to raise wages next fiscal year. In light of this, we
have raised prices for the first time since our establishment
(services for individuals).
0 • In response to rising electricity charges as well as higher
labor costs partly due to the effects of the increase in
-1 minimum wages this fall, we have raised output prices
CY 21 22 23 (pharmacy).

Notes: 1. In the left-hand chart, figures for goods exclude fresh food and energy, while those for general services exclude mobile phone charges..
2. The box on the right shows responses by firms in interviews with the Bank of Japan. The industry of the interviewee is shown in parentheses.
Sources: Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications; Bank of Japan.
10

You might also like