Boyer 2016 Uncertainty and Socio-Economic Rgimes
Boyer 2016 Uncertainty and Socio-Economic Rgimes
https://doi.org/10.1093/oso/9780198820802.001.0001
Published: 2018 Online ISBN: 9780191860430 Print ISBN: 9780198820802
Abstract
The chapter proposes a history of the grand narratives associated with a succession of recent socio-
economic regimes. Since the 2000s, radical uncertainty has greatly increased, given widespread
innovation, and the unprecedented complexity of domestic and international interdependencies. In
these circumstances, actors cannot form fully rational expectations because the past is a poor predictor
of the future. This agony of the rational expectation hypothesis has opened a wide space to consider
the role played by economic narratives in conditions of uncertainty. These narratives are generally
rather simple in form and promise a drastic reduction of radical uncertainty and system complexity.
Businesses use storytelling to convince markets to nance daring, uncertain projects, and economic
policy-makers rely on it to coordinate action. In this way, imaginaries and narratives are crucial in
moving capitalist spirits—but at the cost of recurring nancial and economic crises as each is found
wanting in turn.
This chapter provides a history of the narratives associated with a succession of recent socio-economic
regimes. It argues that radical uncertainty has reached an unprecedented level thanks to radical innovations
and the complexity of domestic and international interdependencies. This uncertainty cannot be overcome
by models based on the currently dominant rational expectations hypothesis. Actors are unable to base their
estimates on such determinist models because the past is a poor predictor of future socio-economic
regimes. The current agony of the rational expectations hypothesis has opened up a wide space for
economic narratives—generally fairly simple in nature—that promise a drastic reduction of radical
In the early 2000s, the economic profession was very proud of the discipline’s achievements. Due to
advances in conceptualization, the sophistication of econometric techniques, and the availability of real-
time data, macroeconomics had acquired the status of a quasi-natural science. Only details were still to be
worked out (Blanchard 2008). Economists were pleased to be one, if not the only, social science able to
deliver causal explanations and precise forecasts. This hope was destroyed by the bursting of the subprime
p. 40 bubble and its development into a world economic crisis that has yet to be overcome even a decade later.
The crisis was a shock for policy-makers: how and why had the scienti c discipline of economics been so
myopic that it failed to diagnose a speculative real estate bubble (Greenspan 2013) that any American taxi
driver might have sensed, but not the head of the Federal Reserve? In order to ght against cumulative
depression, central bankers had to give up their previous conservative principles. They had to buy bonds,
including toxic ones, to sustain the liquidity and solvency of commercial banks. Unfortunately, nobody
knows the way out of this policy of ‘quantitative easing’, a monetary approach that stands in clear violation
of the rational expectations hypothesis that remains central to contemporary macroeconomics.
This chapter proposes the concept of expectation regimes in order to analyse the succession of distinct
periods in which di erent sets of expectations prevail in the socio-economic order. Expectations can be
adaptive or rational within a quasi-stationary world. When key political compromises build complex but
coherent institutional architectures, the expectation regime is context-dependent. By contrast, when
nance is the hierarchically dominant institution, the radical uncertainty of economic futures has to be
reduced by the invention and di usion of narratives that range from business plans to society-wide utopias.
Because self-ful lling prophecies are exceptional (see the chapter by Esposito in this volume), nancial and
economic crises typically mark the shifts in narratives required to cure capital imbalances.
Expectation regimes that are historically contingent and based on narratives provide an alternative set of
microfoundations that—unlike those envisaged by standard economic theories—are able to account for the
central importance of uncertain futures in modern economies. The inadequacy of standard economic
theories in this regard is well understood. For example, the Walrasian auctioneer can do no more than
organize the synchronicity of exchanges, without any concern for uncertainty and di erent time frames in
the various spheres of society. This means that views about the future are excluded from analysis, although
they are crucial in any market and even more in a capitalist economy. Walrasian and by extension many
standard economic theories have limited applicability because they are unable to deal with time (Sapir
2000). They discard the historical dimension of economic processes (including progressive learning from
the past) and fail to recognize the futurity that lies at the heart of markets and capitalist economies. This
structural weakness is recognized by some of the modern theoreticians who have tried to generalize the
Walrasian theory. To date, however, none of these e orts have been successful because contingent
p. 41 commodity markets are rare, rational expectations internalizing the correct model (Muth 1961) are not valid
outside a stable equilibrium, and the creation of futures and option markets entails speculation without
ensuring dynamic stability.
Luckily, the actors populating real-life economies have been continuously inventing practical devices to
reduce uncertainty and complexity. During the post-Second World War Golden Age, indicative planning was
used in order to mimic the impact of heterogeneous strategies and discover a minimalist basis for coherence
at the macroeconomic level. The neoliberal project that followed aimed at delegating this coordination to
These practical devices can be grouped under the concept of expectation regimes, de ned as the mix of
individual and collective coordination mechanisms that facilitate and channel decisions over multiple
periods and thus have a long-lasting impact. Since the nineteenth century, quite di erent regimes have
been invented, matured, and decayed. In the modern era when the e cacy of macroeconomic institutions is
declining, the heterogeneity of interests is increasing, and intense structural change is obscuring the future,
the time of narratives has come. Nevertheless, because such narratives rarely lead to the world they pretend
to build, many fail. As this chapter demonstrates, the narratives of Japan number one, the new economy, and
the omniscience of nancial markets are all good examples of a relentless quest for attractive narrative
representations of an unknown future.
This analytical framework provides a suggestive interpretation of the higher frequency and severity of
economic crises since nancial liberalization: the timeframe of nanciers’ representations is far too short
compared with the time required to change products, technologies, lifestyles, education and training, public
spending priorities, and the tax system. As a consequence, the sources (and the nature) of economic crises
have changed dramatically. In socio-economic regimes dominated by a nancial logic, storytelling is no
longer restricted to the road shows of companies’ chief nancial o cers. Instead, it has permeated the
mass media and transformed the very process of democratic political choices and government policies. ‘New
era’ narratives and associated emotions and passions (Akerlof and Shiller 2009) sustain attractive but
frequently unfounded stories that drive markets and even penetrate the political agenda. This amounts to
the end of well-planned political programmes and ushers in an era of vibrant but unstable imaginary
visions.
It might be tempting to restrict the role of narratives and ctions to nance-led contemporary capitalism
p. 42 (Boyer 2018). It is, however, much more insightful to revisit brie y theories that point out the
uncertainty inherent in any monetary economy, before examining the particular prevalence of uncertainty
(requiring resolution with the help of narratives) in globalized and nance-led capitalist systems.
The Three Uncertainties of Any Capitalist System
Many theoretical and historical approaches have shown that the institution of money is a necessary
condition for a market economy to exist, contrary to the neoclassical myth whereby it is the extension of
barter that calls for the introduction of money. This raises the question of how a market economy reaches
equilibrium via the price mechanism. Karl Marx seems to be the rst to have pointed out that the issue is not
only the determination of relative prices; rather, the existence of money allows actors to deal with the
uncertainty stemming from the frequent temporal separation of selling one good and buying another (Marx
1867 [2017]).
A third level of uncertainty is introduced once innovation becomes a key driver of competition: by
de nition, innovation undermines repetition and thus cannot be assessed by rational calculus. The
challenge is the more daunting, the longer the time lag between the investment in research and
development and the delivery of new goods or services to the market. This is the core message of Joseph
Schumpeter (1926). Logically, the standard microeconomic approach is unable to deliver any reasonable
solution, because no probability distribution can be derived from previous innovations. This central
importance of innovation and novelty in modern economies (see also Shackle 1972) dictates a crucial role
for contingent imaginaries and social representations of uncertain futures in contemporary capitalism.
The rst reason is that the deepening of the division of labour creates strong structural interdependencies:
any localized event might have surprising fallouts in distant sectors and territories. Generally, economic
agents have neither the power nor the resources to diagnose and control this uncertainty. They have
therefore to forge ad hoc representations of these interdependencies, taking into account only a few of the
actually existing causal relations.
The second reason is that globalization has developed global value chains that are di cult to master even
for the leading rms that organize the segmentation of production. Rather than uncertainty being limited to
the local environment of each production site, it is related to worldwide shocks that a ect both demand in
nal markets and the supply of resources. Clearly, even the most talented experts with huge data sets have
been unable to anticipate the successive crises of the new economy.
Finally, the explosion of derivatives linked to each basic transaction has created an impressive complexity in
nancial instruments. Because the position of each trader is based in large part on private information in a
context in which bilateral ad hoc contracts are the norm, outside observers are unable to detect emerging
structural imbalances: they are revealed only when a node of the international nancial system goes
bankrupt. The collapse of Lehmann Brothers is a good example of this obscurity at the heart of the nancial
markets that standard economic theory had generally assumed were transparent. Financiers and traders are
left to invent ctions in order to pretend they are masters of a process that ultimately they cannot
comprehend.
Has contemporary economic theory found practical solutions to overcome or channel this uncertainty and
make investment decisions easier and safer? Despite all the e orts in economics, only unsatisfactory
De facto, institutions address the various sources of uncertainty diagnosed by economic sociology (Beckert
2016, 43). Institutions frame the context for individual decisions; they constrain the range of alternatives
considered; and they provide a simpli cation of the interactions with other domains. Of course, the rules of
the game that institutions set do not fully determine the outcome but they delineate strategies and restrict
radical uncertainty. They give structure to a problem with otherwise unlimited dimensions (Aoki 2010).
Indicative Planning: A Method for Socializing Individual Strategies
While these general institutional forms may reduce ‘local’ uncertainty, their interaction can still display a
lack of compatibility that generates chaotic dynamics that appear as uncertainty at the global or system
level. Indicative planning may provide a method for diagnosing such incoherent regimes, promoting
deliberation about possible solutions, and simulating likely consequences. If all the stakeholders are
involved in the patient and recurring process of planning, then a shared vision of the future is di used in
everyday decisions about private and public investment, education and research, the geographical
distribution of economic activity, and so on. In this way, the uncertainty of the future is partially but not
From a theoretical point of view, planning was presented as a tool to ght uncertainty (Massé 1965). It is not
so easy to assess its role in the rapid and fairly steady growth in France in the thirty years after 1945
(Kindleberger 1967), but a similar con guration could be observed in Japan and had remarkable outcomes.
In both countries the catching up process could be organized under the monitoring of the public authorities.
But the very success of this socio-economic regime promoted a diversi cation of production away from
basic goods, and the national economy was progressively opened up to international trade. These two
structural transformations gradually eroded the e ciency of indicative planning, because rms tend to
become the lead players in the sti ening of international competition, while public authorities lose some
key economic policy instruments, such as control over the exchange rate or the taxation of mobile capital.
When the trans-nationalization of value chains and nancial asset portfolio management became the
dominant mechanisms governing macroeconomic evolutions, French indicative planning experienced a
severe crisis and the di usion of ‘laissez-faire’ discourses convinced later governments that the state is the
problem and markets are the solution.
Under these conditions markets and states switch places. In the past, governments set medium-term
expectations through programmes, while markets provided short-run adjustment processes. Since the end
of 1990, international nance has been tasked with setting the stock market value of leading rms,
assessing the relevance of their investments and innovation decisions, and checking the viability of national
public nance. The future has become the consequence of private strategic choices, and governments are in
charge of reacting to unexpected perturbations alongside the long-term trajectories set by leading private
actors.
p. 46 Many futures markets are thus created and become the compass guiding economic actors. A large fraction of
the economic profession followed the hypothesis that these markets are e cient in the sense that they
deliver the best synthesis of scattered individual information. Nevertheless, the literature has shown that
the volatility of stock market valuations is far higher than the variability of the underlying process of pro t
generation (Shiller 2000). It might be troubling for traders to observe that the ups and downs of nancial
markets follow a pure random walk. As a result, the related erratic movements tend to be attributed to the
‘mood of the market’, according to an astonishingly anthropomorphic vision of nancial markets. Last but
not least, instead of a smooth adjustment of stock markets to new information, brutal collapses of nancial
valuation continually surprise the best experts and nancial gurus. The creation of futures markets, which
was supposed to reduce uncertainty, appears in the end to have increased it, rendering decision-making by
rms still more di cult than in the era of administered economies.
Faced with the multiplicity of transformations occurring in technological paradigms, lifestyles, geography
of production, and social strati cation, large multinational rms and investors must address the deep
uncertainty a ecting their decisions: how to invest in a changing world in which the old principles are
invalid but new ones have not yet emerged? Business plans describing expected cash ows along a series of
trajectories become mere ctions, because rms are unable to know the distribution of probability over the
successive events that will a ect the outcome of today’s decisions in terms of products, investment, and
R&D expenditures. Inventing a simple and attractive narrative cuts through the inhibiting complexity and
p. 47 uncertainty. This solution suggests that entrepreneurs are mastering their future by describing it in a
narrative and allocating resources to make it happen. The initiative shifts from government and public
agencies to charismatic entrepreneurs in the Schumpeterian sense of the term: they escape from the
management of purely repetitive decisions sustaining the exhausted productive paradigm from the past and
bet on the imagined success of new products, organizations, methods, and territories.
This should normally deliver fairly chaotic macroeconomic developments, given the intrinsic heterogeneity
generated by a market economy. Two features of contemporary societies, however, polarize the a priori
unlimited pool of possible narratives. Firstly, the stock market and, more generally, the di erent nancial
instruments coordinate heterogeneous expectations via price formation: the rapid appreciation of a
company’s stock is interpreted as a mark of the success of its visions and strategies, the more so when
theoreticians and practitioners believe that the market valuation reveals all available information about the
future. Frequently a dominant narrative emerges and becomes adopted by actors whose alternative bets
have been disappointed. A typical ction-led boom moves new industries and by extension the national
economy. Secondly, the mass media, both old and new, widely di use not only nancial valuations but also
the stories of leading entrepreneurs at the forefront of the ‘new economy’. Thus a powerful mechanism
reinforcing the role of dominant narratives is embedded in both the modern nancial system and the media
system.
Such statements can be self-ful lling if su cient people invest money in the story. Instead of trying to
decipher an obscure future, actors take decisions designed to make an imagined future real. ‘The new
economy is the future’, ‘Capitalism has moved to Asia’, ‘Quantitative nance allows us to master risk and deliver
an unprecedented rate of return’, or ‘The Euro is irreversible’ are all good examples of the contemporary
narrative approach to uncertain futures; and these stories have to a considerable extent structured recent
economic behaviour.
The narratives told to the nancial markets by government agencies also di er from the government
policies prevailing at the time of indicative planning. The key public actor is no longer the ministry of
nance, which is too slow and cumbersome to react to unexpected events, but rather the central banker: she
or he has the task of interacting with nanciers’ narratives by issuing statements designed to maintain trust
in the positive evolution of nancial markets (Greenspan 2013; see also the chapters by Braun and Holmes
in this volume). This is a novelty in the long history of central banking (Blinder 1997). Governments are
Because most imaginaries are unable to deliver the expected transformations in the economy, they
generally end up with a brutal readjustment of expectations. In some cases, there is a long period of
contestation between competing grand narratives and one eventually gains temporary dominance. In some
other con gurations, after a period of doubt and uncertainty, an alternative vision of the future emerges,
becomes hegemonic, and leads to the recovery of investors’ ‘animal spirits’.
Japan Invents the Machine that was Supposed to Change the World
The debate shifted in the 1980s to analysis of the juxtaposed trajectories followed by the United States and
p. 49 Japan: industrial decline of typically Fordist industries, on one hand, and the invention of a new
production paradigm, on the other. The Asian ‘dragons’ and Japan in particular seemed to have discovered a
way of avoiding the stagnation of productivity observed in North America.
In practice, of course, the Asian emerging industrial economies displayed many di erences with American
and European capitalisms in terms of the interplay between state and market, social strati cation, and
integration in the world economy. Institutional theorists have pointed out the complementarity between the
various institutional forms and di erent coherent development modes (Hollingsworth and Boyer 1997),
which implies that successful institutional architectures cannot easily be imported (Amable 2003).
Despite this, American and European managers harnessed the power of narrative to propose shortcuts that
promised to resolve a complex web of causalities. The post-war ‘golden age’ was reinterpreted as a direct
consequence of the breakthrough of mass production and the di usion of the assembly line, inherited from
This vision became quite e ective in mobilizing managers and shaping macrodynamics. All over the world,
business schools were teaching how to implement the so-called ‘Japanese model’, and many authors
anticipated its domination at the global level—especially in terms of rms’ organization of production—as
evidenced by the opening of Japanese plants in the United States and Europe. The belief in the superiority of
the Japanese brand of capitalism created an unprecedented speculative stock market and real estate bubble,
in an overreaction to what was perceived to be Japan’s bright future, with its possible replacement of the
United States as the leading industrial power.
This speculation had to be reassessed, however, because the simple narrative of lean production turned out
to be an unjusti ed generalization, given the diversity of production models within the same sector and
country (Boyer and Freyssenet 2002). Furthermore, Japanese macroeconomic performance had to be
attributed to many other distinctive features, such as the wage–labour nexus, the nature of competition,
and the nancial system. Moreover, foreign admirers of Japanese capitalism totally missed the growing
tensions and disequilibria generated by the very success of past strategies of rms and successive
governments (Boyer and Yamada 2000). The lean production ction has long been discarded, but it
nevertheless achieved a partial transformation of the industrial world while it lasted.
As communication and information technologies were di used, it became clear that pro ts can only be
earned in the longer term if the bulk of information is converted into knowledge. This led to the rise of the
second generation of internet companies, specializing in software (Boyer 2004). The narrative of the new
economy permeated society as a whole: intangible capital frequently eclipsed typical equipment goods;
start-ups dictated the speed of the economy; and when they were converted into public rms quoted on the
stock market, their capitalization exploded and often superseded those of the old economy. Companies that
never earned any pro t enjoyed high stock prices because they explored the future and were destined (so the
narrative went) to encounter success ‘eventually’. Silicon Valley and the newly created Nasdaq were allies
that jointly bet on the bright future of the New Economy: they channelled a ow of investments into new
companies out of typical goods production. The enthusiasm was so frantic that in the 1990s some experts
even speculated that ‘economic laws’ had now been invalidated.
Very early on, dissenters challenged the anticipated impact of ICT on productivity, but they were not
Paradoxically, some conceptual continuity prevailed with the previous periods: scienti c progress was
invoked to justify the hegemony of nance that developed. The specialists in statistical physics or
engineering shifted from industry to nance and became so-called ‘quants’: old-style nanciers could not
assess the nature and risks of these new businesses and were unable to challenge the legitimacy of quants
because they did not share the prestige of such high calibre scientists (see also Besedovsky in this volume).
Dissenters who stressed that the whole nancial industry was built upon erroneous calculations of
probability distributions that exclude the ‘fat tails’ associated with crises were not listened to (Mandelbrot
and Hudson 2005; Taleb 2010).
A new grand narrative was born. It stated that any economic or social issue can be overcome by an ad hoc
nancial instrument, whose introduction is a better strategy than implementing painful reforms and
unpopular policies (Shiller 2003, 2008). Are developing countries su ering from recurring exchange rate
adjustments and nancial crises? Let us design a sophisticated insurance contract that obviates the need to
change either the currency regime or economic policy! Is a rock star su ering a liquidity constraint but rich
p. 52 in terms of future royalties? Let us convert the ow of income into a security that can be sold to an
investor and cashed-in immediately. Do minority and low-income families face persistent di culties
purchasing housing? Why not reduce personal income and asset requirements for mortgages, and securitize
these credits to ‘spread’ the risk? If this opportunity is widely exploited by banks, a housing boom generates
price increases that sustain the illusion that gains from speculation can replace income. Unfortunately from
a macroeconomic point of view, this is impossible in the long run, and the strategy was bound to end in a
dramatic collapse of a nancial system that had fully embraced the narrative that systemic risk was now
under control (Boyer 2008, 2011a).
The subsequent crisis was far more severe than most previous ones. This was because the accumulation
regime was totally nance-led, with few breakthroughs in the real economy that might lead to productivity
The Green Economy: The Most Recent Narrative to Move Financial Markets
Once the risk of a cumulative depression and de ation was removed in the 2010s, governments and
nanciers faced a daunting question: what will be the next engine of growth? The very active Chinese
economic policy achieved a return to rapid growth fuelled by a credit boom that reverberated all over the
world. The strong dependency of Chinese manufacturing on imported natural resources triggered a
commodity boom and a spectacular reversal of the terms of trade between manufactured goods and natural
resources. This was, for a time, interpreted as a con rmation of the possible blocking of growth by the
exhaustion of oil, metals, and even food in some regions of the world.
p. 53 But this was not a mere repetition of the oil shocks of the 1970s (Meadows et al. 1972, 2004). On one hand,
the debate on climate change reinserts world economic activity into the biosphere and the physical barriers
to continuing the past modes of development: economists and policy-makers have to take this structural
change into account (Stern 2006). On the other hand, the market for oil futures fed intense speculation
because the expectation of future scarcity drives the spot market: primary commodity prices were quoted as
nancial assets (Cournot Center 2016). This invasion of the domain of natural resources by nance was the
explicit strategy of some investors and it was designed immediately after Lehman Brothers’ collapse
(MacCall 2009). A new narrative emerged around the green economy and it permeated the redeployment of
investment, innovation, environment regulations, taxation, and public infrastructure. One variant of this
project proposed that sustainability and prosperity should replace growth as governments’ key concern
(Jackson 2009).
As in previous cases, this new narrative triggered a modest economic boom, but it failed to allow the
e ective implementation of the new growth regime based on long-term ecological sustainability, as
anticipated by governments and reiterated by the Paris Conference on Climate Change. The transformation
of the real economy was far slower than the unfolding of the speculative bubble in oil and natural resources.
Furthermore, the narrative of the greening of national economies is a drastic simpli cation, given the
complexity of ongoing and interrelated structural transformations: the maturing of the e-economy, the
development of new services, the constant rise of health-care demand, the delocalization of polluting
industries, an uncertain exit policy from quantitative easing, and recurring protectionist temptations. The
con ict of time horizons between nance and the economy and the extreme simpli cation associated with
the concept of the Green Economy explain the brutal reversal of oil prices seen since 2014, its repercussion
on stock markets, and the re-emergence of major uncertainties concerning the direction of investment and
the future regime for oil prices (Garnier and Sølna 2017).
This brief historical perspective on developments since the 1970s—summarized in Table 2.1—suggests the
existence of some crucial and invariant mechanisms that explain both the reasons for narratives and their
power to determine the dynamics of capitalist economies. It seems to con rm the importance of
representations of the future as stressed by recent theoretical breakthroughs: widely shared imaginaries
p. 54 and associated grand narratives are one of the (imperfect) responses to the uncertainty of modern
economies (Beckert 2013, 2016; Bronk and Jacoby 2016).
Table 2.1. A synoptic view of the chronology of imaginaries and expectation regimes in the contemporary period
Japan no. 1 (1980s) Decline of American hegemony, Transition towards Misreading of the source of Japanese
Japanization of the world another socio- growth
economic regime
The New Economy A Schumpeterian technological Technological Conflict of time horizons between
(1990s) revolution impatience technical imaginaries and the real
economy
Finance-led Successful control of risk by Driven by storytelling Conflict of time horizons between
accumulation scientific advances in financial models and the real
(2000s) mathematical finance economy
As argued earlier in this chapter, economic institutions aim precisely at reducing this second-degree
p. 55 uncertainty. But the exhaustion and open crisis of the post-war socio-economic regime eroded belief in
institutional constructivism. Given the lack of convincing alternatives, most governments have, as a result,
delegated the exploration of the future to nancial markets. Such markets do allow for the pooling of
scattered visions and the coordination of decentralized information through the price mechanism—one
de nition of nancial market e ciency—but this does not warrant the extreme faith in market knowledge
evident before the crisis. Individuals and rms recognize that they must rely upon the price signals of
nancial markets because they have only limited knowledge. Since these markets appear to be highly
stochastic, experts have frequently gone on to attribute a clear intentionality and rationality to the ups and
downs of nancial markets. A curious personi cation of the markets occurs, with statements such as ‘the
markets think that…’, whereas in reality the ‘message of markets’ is merely the unintended consequence of
the confrontation of initially heterogeneous expectations, objectives, and nancial resources.
This introduces two entry points for narratives. As this chapter has shown, each era displays a grand vision
(or narrative) about the direction of change and the source of pro t. But in order to interpret the everyday
market process, secondary narratives have to explain the observed discrepancies with respect to the
imagined ideal future. To be convincing, both primary and secondary narratives have to be fairly simple.
Conventional economic theory sticks to the hypothesis that in equilibrium rational expectations will prevail
because agents gain economic rewards by anticipating the future correctly, while competition eliminates all
those who fail to build correct forecasts. But this neglects the fact that the learning process converges only if
the nal rational equilibrium is stable (Grandmont and Laroque 1991). Since socio-economic regimes
mature and decay repeatedly, agents are unable to deploy rational expectations during periods of dynamic
change between alternative emerging regimes characterized by radical uncertainty.
p. 56 A second standard economic solution considers the sequence of price signals on product and factor markets
as su cient for the monitoring of inter-temporal and long-term decisions about production, investment,
and innovation. Again, this assumes an ergodic and ultimately predictable system tending towards a stable
and long-term equilibrium—a contradiction in terms because technical, organizational, and institutional
innovations progressively transform the existing economic regime (Shackle 1972; and Beckert and Bronk in
the introduction to this volume).
The overwhelming role of nance in contemporary capitalist regimes opens up a more relevant solution.
The futures markets guide decentralized individual strategies by proposing not only prices but also shared
representations of the future. When uncertainty increases, agents tend to rely more on the expectations of
others than on their own, and this rational mimetic behaviour may move the price of assets away from so-
called fundamental value, computed as the discounted value of future incomes (Orléan 1990). Indeed, two
Conclusion
Figure 2.1
An interpretation of economic evolution: the emerging, maturing, and crisis of successive narratives
Three basic features of monetary and capitalist economies render powerless any economic calculus
assuming rational expectations. First, at the individual level, investment and innovation face radical
uncertainty because not all possible states of the world can be known. A second category of uncertainty
relates to the reaction of other agents that belong to the same sector and sphere of competition. Finally, the
relevant web of interactions is di cult to decipher, given the deepening of divisions of labour within and
across national borders.
This central problem of uncertainty for modern economies has been dealt with since the immediate post-
war period by applying two di erent strategic approaches. During the epoch of constructivism that followed
the Second World War, core socio-political compromises and indicative planning led to the emergence of fairly
coherent socio-economic regimes, and a remarkable reduction of the three main sources of uncertainty was
achieved. With the subsequent deregulation of product and labour markets, the dynamism of nancial
p. 57 innovation, and the move towards globalization, nancial markets
p. 58
were charged with designing an alternative regime. Ever since, the price signals on nancial markets have
been progressively complemented by grand narratives that are supposed to synchronize the strategies of
heterogeneous actors. Narratives are now the key instruments available for top managers and governments.
But the downside of this strategy has been made painfully clear by the nancial crisis of 2007 and the
instability that followed.
Behind the major di erences between di erent eras, a common dynamic pattern is operating. The invention
of narratives as an ‘anti-uncertainty device’ makes possible a wave of investments that is initially
successful but nally hits the barrier associated with an unbalanced accumulation regime, a disjunction
This chapter has described the existence of a two-way causality between a succession of key narratives and
various con gurations of capitalism. At the most basic level, narratives and socio-economic regimes co-
evolve alongside major social transformations. Across the unfolding of di erent historical eras, there are
signi cant regularities in the pattern of emergence, maturing, and crisis of socio-economic regimes, in
which narratives and expectation regimes play a crucial role.
Bibliography
Akerlof, George A., and Robert J. Shiller. 2009. Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy and Why It Matters.
Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press.
Amable, Bruno. 2003. The Diversity of Modern Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Aoki, Masahiko. 1988. Information, Incentives and Bargaining in the Japanese Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Aoki, Masahiko. 2010. Corporations in Evolving Diversity: Cognition, Governance, and Institutions. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Beckert, Jens. 2013. ʻCapitalism as a System of Expectations: Toward a Sociological Micro-Foundation of Political Economyʼ.
Politics and Society 41 (3): pp. 323–50.
Beckert, Jens. 2016. Imagined Futures: Fictional Expectations and Capitalist Dynamics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Black, Fischer, and Myron Scholes. 1973. ʻThe Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilitiesʼ. Journal of Political Economy 81 (3): pp.
637–54.
Google Scholar WorldCat
Blanchard, Olivier J. 2008. ʻThe State of Macroʼ. NBER Working Paper no 14259, August. http://www.nber.org/papers/w14259.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
p. 59 Blinder, Alan S. 1997. Central Banking in Theory and Practice, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Boyer, Robert. 2004. The Future of Economic Growth: As New Becomes Old. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Boyer, Robert. 2008. ʻHistory Repeating for Economists: An Anticipated Financial Crisisʼ. Prisme, no 13, November. Paris: Centre
Cournot pour la Recherche en Economie. http://robertboyer.org/fr/category/publi/livre/page/2/.
Boyer, Robert. 2011a. Les financiers détruiront-ils le capitalisme? July. Paris: Economica.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Boyer, Robert. 2011b. ʻA New Epoch but still Diversity within and between Capitalism: China in Comparative Perspectiveʼ. In
Capitalist Diversity and Diversity within Capitalism, edited by Christel Lane and Geo rey Wood, pp. 32–68. Abingdon: Routledge.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Boyer, Robert. 2013. ʻLes crises financières comme conflit de temporalitésʼ. Vingtième Siècle. Revue dʼHistoire, no 117, pp. 69–88.
https://www.cairn.info/revue-vingtieme-siecle-revue-d-histoire-2013-1-page-69.htm.
Google Scholar WorldCat
Boyer, Robert. 2015. Economie politique des capitalismes: Théorie de la régulation et des crises. Paris: La Découverte.
Boyer, Robert. 2018. ʻFrom Economics as Fiction to Fiction-Led Capitalismʼ. In Representations of Capitalism in American Fiction,
edited by Jacques-Henri Coste and Vincent Dussol. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Boyer, Robert, and Michel Freyssenet. 2002. The Productive Models: The Condition of Profitability. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Boyer, Robert, and Yves Saillard. 2001. Eds. Regulation Theory: The State of the Art. London: Routledge.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Boyer, Robert, and Toshio Yamada. 2000. Japanese Capitalism in Crisis: A Regulationist Interpretation. London: Routledge.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Bronk, Richard. 2013. ʻReflexivity Unpacked: Performativity, Uncertainty, and Analytical Monoculturesʼ. Journal of Economic
Methodology 20 (4): 343–9.
Google Scholar WorldCat
Cocteau, Jean. 1927. Les mariés de la tour Ei el, collection folio, réédition Paris: Gallimard.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Commons, John R. 1934 [1989]. Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy. London: Routledge.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Cournot Center. 2016. ʻRégime de formation des prix et volatilité: Le pétrole face au charbon et au gaz en longue périodeʼ. April.
Paris: Centre Cournot. Mimeograph.
Delorme, Robert. 2010. Deep Complexity and the Social Sciences: Experience, Modelling and Operationality. Cheltenham: Edward
Elgar.
Douglas, Mary. 1986. How Institutions Think. New York: Syracuse University Press.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Eichengreen, Barry. 2015. Hall of Mirrors: The Great Depression, The Great Recession, and the Uses—and Misuses—of History. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Garber, Peter M. 2000. Famous First Bubbles: The Fundamentals of Early Mania. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Garnier, Josselin, and Knut Sølna. 2017. ʻTime-Frequency Analysis of Oil Price Dataʼ. Prisme, no 33, Paris: Centre Cournot.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Gordon, Robert J. 2000. ʻDoes the “New Economy” Measure up to the Great Inventions of the Past?ʼ. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 14 (4): pp. 49–74.
Google Scholar WorldCat
p. 60 Gordon, Robert J. 2016. The Rise and Fall of American Growth: The U.S. Standard of Living since the Civil War. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Grandmont, Jean-Michel, and Guy Laroque. 1991. ʻEconomic Dynamics with Learning: Some Instability Examplesʼ. In Equilibrium
Theory and Applications. Proceedings of the Sixth International Symposium in Economic Theory and Econometrics, edited by
William A. Barnett, Bernard Cornet, Claude DʼAspremont, Jean Gabszewicz, and Andreu Mas-Colell, pp. 247–73. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Greenspan, Alan. 2013. The Map and the Territory: Risk, Human Nature, and the Future of Forecasting. London: Penguin Press.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Grossman, Sanford J., and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1980. ʻOn the Impossibility of Informationally E icient Marketsʼ. American Economic
Review 70: pp. 393–408.
Google Scholar WorldCat
Haldane, Andrew. 2009. ʻWhy Banks Failed the Stress Testʼ. Speech given at the Marcus-Evans Conference on Stress-Testing, 13
February 2009. http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/archive/documents/historicpubs/speeches/2009/speech374.pdf.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Heiner, Ronald A. 1983. ʻThe Origin of Predictable Behaviorʼ. American Economic Review 73 (4): pp. 560–95.
Google Scholar WorldCat
Jackson, Tim. 2009. Prosperity Without Growth: Economics for a Finite Planet. London: Earthscan.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Kindleberger, Charles P. 1967. ʻFrench Planningʼ. In National Economic Planning, edited by Max F. Millikan, pp. 279–303.
Cambridge, MA: NBER. http://www.nber.org/chapters/c1426.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Kindleberger, Charles P. 1978. Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises. New York: Basic Books.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Krippner, Greta R. 2011. Capitalizing on Crisis: The Political Origins of the Rise of Finance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Lordon, Frédéric. 1997. Les quadratures de la politique économique. Paris: Albin Michel.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
McCall, Matthew. 2009. The Next Great Bull Market. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
MacKenzie, Donald. 2006. An Engine, Not a Camera: How Financial Models Shape Markets. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Mandelbrot, Benoît, and Richard L. Hudson. 2005. Une approche fractale des marchés: Risquer, perdre et gagner. Paris: Odile
Jacob.
Marx, Karl. 1867 [2017]. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Vol. 1. London: Forgotten Books.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Meadows, Donella H., Dennis L. Meadows, Jørgen Randers, and William W. Behrens. 1972. The Limits to Growth. New York:
Universe Books.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Meadows, Donella H., Jorgen Randers, and Dennis L. Meadows. 2004. The Limits to Growth: The 30-Year Update. London:
Earthscan.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Merton, Robert C. 1973. ʻTheory of Rational Option Pricingʼ. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 4 (1): pp. 141–83.
Google Scholar WorldCat
p. 61 Muth, John F. 1961. ʻRational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movementsʼ. Econometrica 29 (3): pp. 315–35.
Google Scholar WorldCat
Nye, David E. 2013. Americaʼs Assembly Line. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Orléan, André. 1990. ʻLe rôle des influences interpersonnelles dans la détermination des cours boursiersʼ. Revue économique 41,
pp. 839–68.
Google Scholar WorldCat
Orléan, André. 2014. The Empire of Value: A New Foundation for Economics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogo . 2009. This Time Is Di erent: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Salmon, Christian. 2007. Storytelling: La machine à fabriquer des histoires et à formater des esprits. Paris: La Découverte.
Sapir, Jacques. 2000. Les Trous noirs de la science économique: Essai sur lʼimpossibilité de penser le temps et lʼargent. Paris: Albin
Michel.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Schumpeter, Joseph Alois. 1926. Théorie de lʼévolution économique (Theorie der wirtscha lichen Entwicklung). Translated by
Jean Jacques Anstett. 2nd edn. Dalloz: Paris.
Shackle, George L. S. 1972. Epistemics and Economics: A Critique of Economic Doctrines. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Shiller, Robert J. 2000. Irrational Exuberance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Shiller, Robert J. 2003. The New Financial Order: Risk in the 21st Century. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Shiller, Robert J. 2008. The Subprime Solution: How Todayʼs Global Financial Crisis Happened and What to Do about It. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
Simon, H. 1997. Models of Bounded Rationality: Empirically Grounded Economic Reason. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Streek, Wolfgang. 2017. Buying Time: The Delayed Crisis of Democratic Capitalism. London: Verso.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Summers, Lawrence H. 2016. ʻThe Age of Secular Stagnation: What It Is and What to Do About Itʼ. Foreign A airs 95 (2):
March/April. https://www.foreigna airs.com/articles/united-states/2016-02-15/age-secular-stagnation.
Google Scholar WorldCat
Stern, Nicholas. 2006. Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. London: HM Treasury.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Taleb, Nassim Nicholas. 2010. Le cygne noir: La puissance de lʼimprévisible (The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly
Vogel, Ezra F. 1999. Japan Number One: Lessons for America. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
West, Scott, and Mitch Anthony. 2000. Storytelling for Financial Advisors: How Top Producers Sell. Chicago, IL: Dearborn Financial
Publishing.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC
Womack, James P., Daniel T. Jones, and Daniel Roos. 1990. The Machine that Changed the World. New York: Macmillan.
Google Scholar Google Preview WorldCat COPAC