How Finance Works Notes
How Finance Works Notes
Summary Notes
Weihan Huang
January 1, 2024
Contents
1 Financial Analysis 4
1.1 Assets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
1.1.1 Cash and marketable securities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
1.1.2 Accounts receivable . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
1.1.3 Inventories . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
1.1.4 Property, plant, and equipment (PP&E) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
1.1.5 Other assets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
1.2 Liabilities and Shareholders’ Equity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
1.2.1 Accounts payable and notes payable . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
1.2.2 Accrued items . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
1.2.3 Long-term debt . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
1.2.4 Preferred and common stock . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
1.3 Understanding Ratios . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
1.3.1 Liquidity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
1.3.2 Profitability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
1.3.3 Financing and Leverage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
1.3.4 Productivity or Efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
1.3.5 The DuPont Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
2
3.3.2 Salespeople . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
3.3.3 Investment Bankers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
3.4 The Media . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
3.5 Incentives for Equity Analysts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
3.6 The Problem at the Heart of Capital Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
3.6.1 The Principal-Agent Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
6 Capital Allocation 52
6.1 Capital Allocation Decision Tree . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52
6.2 Retaining Cash . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
6.2.1 The perils of inorganic growth . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
6.2.2 Conglomerates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
6.3 Distributing Cash to Shareholders . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
6.3.1 The decision to distribute cash . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57
6.4 Myths and Realities in Financing Decisions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58
6.4.1 Equity issuance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58
6.4.2 Stock splits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
6.4.3 Leveraged recapitalization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60
6.4.4 Venture financing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
6.4.5 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62
6.5 Cash on Balance Sheets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62
6.6 Six Major Mistakes in Capital Allocation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62
3
Chapter 1
Financial Analysis
Operating prof it = Gross prof it − Selling, general, and administrative expenses (1.2)
1.1 Assets
• Assets are what a company owns
• Often ordered by the degree to which they can be changed into cash
• Assets that can easily be changed into cash are called current assets
4
1.1.1 Cash and marketable securities
• Marketable securiteis are assets that can be quickly converted to cash e.g. stocks, bonds,
preferred shares and ETFs
• This is known as extending credit, where business allow their customers, often other businesses,
to pay after 30, 60, or 90 days.
• Thus, B2B businesses often have a higher amount of their sales reflected as receivables on their
balance sheet (more so than B2C businesses).
1.1.3 Inventories
• The goods (or the inputs that become those goods) that a company intends to sell.
• Companies with no inventories are those that provide services e.g. law firms, advertising
companies or medical practices.
• Accountants won’t assign value to intangible assets unless they those values precisely e.g. Coca
Cola has a very valuable brand, possibly the most valuable thing it owns but its exact value is
unknown, so accountants ignore it (makes people in finance distrust accounting)
• When a company buys another company, many intangible assets that couldn’t be valued pre-
cisely now have a value according to accounting, as someone actually paid for it as part of an
acquisition.
5
• When a company acquires another company for more than the value of its assets on their
balance sheet, that difference is typically recorded on the acquiring company’s balance sheets
as good will.
• Thus, companies with lots of other assets and good will are likely those that have bought other
companies with many intangible assets that were previously unrecorded because of conservatism
e.g. Microsoft acquisition of LinkedIn for $19.2 billion more than the book value will be under
“Other assets” in Microsoft’s balance sheet (could benefit from information on 433 million
LinkedIn users)
• Overall, the rising importance of both cash and other assets are two dominant trends in finance
• There are two sources of finance for purchasing assets - lenders and owners.
• Liabilities are the amounts financed by lenders to whom the company owes amounts.
- Liabilities are ordered by the length of time companies have to repay them.
- Liabilities that need to be paid back soon are labelled “current”.
• Shareholders’ equity or net worth corresponds to the funds that shareholders provide.
• The difference between your assets and liabilities is your shareholders’ equity or net worth.
• One company’s accounts payable frequently corresponds to another company’s amounts receiv-
able.
• Notes payable are a short-term financial obligation, written contracts that typically serve the
purpose of paying debts through credit companies and financial institutions.
• A balance sheet may be produced in the middle of a pay period, and the company may owe
salaries that have not been paid yet.
• Unlike other liabilities, debt is distinctive because it has an explicit interest rate.
• Some companies borrow a lot with 30-40% of their assets financed by debt.
6
1.2.4 Preferred and common stock
• Shareholders’ equity represents an ownership claim with variable returns - the owners get all
residual cash from the business after costs and liabilities.
- Debt has a fixed return (interest rate) and no ownership claim, but it gets paid first before
equity holders in the event of a bankruptcy.
- Typically, shareholders’ equity, net worth, owner’s equity and common stock are all effec-
tively synonyms.
- Shareholders’ equity is not only the amount originally invested in a company by the
owners.
- As a company earns net profits, those profits can be paid out as dividends or reinvested
in the company.
- These retained earnings are a component of shareholders’ equity because it is as if the
owners received a dividend and reinvested it in the company.
• Preferred stock is a hybrid instrument because it combines elements of both debt and equity
claims.
- Like debt, a preferred dividend can be fixed and paid before common stock dividends.
- But like equity, preferred stock is associated with ownership and is paid after debt in the
event of a bankruptcy.
- When the world goes bad, preferred stockholders get paid before common stockholders.
- When things go well, they get to benefit from the upside, unlike debt holders, as share-
holders.
- Companies issue such a security to finance themselves during precarious times.
- If a company has hit hard times and faces a risky future, investors would not want to
invest in their common stock if failure is a real possibility.
- And debtors would not want to lend it money and only get a fixed return that might not
correspond to the riskiness of the business.
- VCs often provide funding to entrepreneurs in exchange for preferred stock that allows
them to protect their investment in the event that the company does poorly, whilst still
participating in the upside if the company does well by converting their preferred stock
into common stock when things go well.
1.3.1 Liquidity
Most companies go bankrupt because they run out cash. Liquidity ratios measure this risk by
emphasizing the company’s ability to meet short-term obligations with assets that can quickly be
converted into cash. Suppliers prefer high liquidity ratios because they want to ensure that their
customers can pay them. Meanwhile, for shareholders, greater liquidity creates a trade-off: acts as
an insurance against bankruptcy, but highly liquid assets (cash and marketable securities) may not
provide much of a return.
7
Current Ratio
Current assets
(1.5)
Current liabilities
The current ratio asks a question on behalf of a company’s suppliers:
• Will its current assets be sufficient to pay off its current liabilities (including those owed to
suppliers)?
The ratio helps to determine if a supplier should extend credit to a company and if a company
will be able to survive the next 6-12 months.
Quick Ratio
Current assets − Inventory
(1.6)
Current liabilities
Similar to the current ratio, except it excludes inventories from the numerator. Inventories
represent risk that needs to be financed. Inventories can be very risky e.g. BlackBerry releases were
declared obsolete and its inventory was effectively zeroed. For companies with high-risk inventory
without a spot market (where financial instruments, such as commodities, currencies and securities
are traded for immediate delivery), the quick ratio provides a more skeptical view of their liquidity.
1.3.2 Profitability
Profit Margin
N et prof it
(1.7)
Revenue
Compare income after all costs and expenses to sales to represent the margin
Return on Assets
N et prof it
(1.9)
T otal assets
This ratio asks: How much profit does a company generate for every dollar of assets? This
corresponds to asking how effectively a company’s assets are generating profits.
8
EBITDA Margin
EBIT DA
(1.10)
Revenue
• EBIT - Earnings Before Interest and Taxes
- Depreciation refers to how physical assets, such as vehicles and equipment, lose value over
time.
- Amortization refers to that same phenomenon but for intangible assets.
- DA is emphasized because they are expenses that are not associated with the outlay of
cash - it is an approximation of the loss of value of an asset.
- In accounting, you have to depreciate assets and charge yourself an expense for that
depreciation.
- But in finance, we emphasize cash and there was no cash outlay, so EBITDA is a measure
of the cash generated by operations.
Debt to Assets
T otal debt
(1.11)
T otal assets
Measures the proportion of all assets financed by debt. It provides a balance sheet perspective
on leverage.
Debt to Capitalization
Debt
(1.12)
Debt + Shareholders′ equity
• The ratio of long-term debt to capitalization provides a more subtle measure of leverage by
emphasizing the mix of debt and equity.
9
• The denominator is capitalization - the combination of a company’s debt and equity.
• Debt has a fixed associated interest cost, whilst equity hold a variable rate of return along with
ownership rights.
• This ratio tracks what proportion of a company’s financing comes from debt and therefore
diverts attention from liabilities that are part of operations.
• Leverage provides the ability to control more assets than an owner would otherwise have the
right to control.
• This ratio tells us precisely how many more assets an owner can control relative to their own
equity capital.
• Thus, it also measures how returns are magnified through the use of leverage.
• The 3 previous measures were constructed from balance sheets, but the critical question is often
the degree to which a company can make its interest payments.
• The ratio of EBIT to interest expense measures a company’s ability to fund interest payments
from its operations and uses only data from the income statement.
• E.g. a ratio of 1 indicates that a company is just able to make its interest payments with its
current operations.
• The comparison between monthly income and any mortgage payments is an analogous measure.
Asset Turnover
Revenue
(1.15)
T otal assets
• This ratio measures how effectively a company is using its assets to generate revenue.
10
Inventory Turnover
Cost of goods sold
(1.16)
Inventory
• Measures how many times a company turns over or sells all its inventory in a given year.
• The higher the number, the more effectively the company is managing its inventory as it sells
products.
• Because inventory is essentially a risky asset that needs to be financed, a higher inventory
turnover is financially valuable.
Days of Inventory
365 ÷ Inventory turnover (1.17)
Dividing the number of days in a year by the inventory turnover provides the average number of
days a piece of inventory is kept inside a company before it is sold.
• The lower this figure (sales > receivables), the faster a company is getting cash from its sales
(most customers pay immediately).
• Lower figures tend to indicate a B2C (retailers) business whilst higher figures tend to indicate
a B2B business (commodities).
Many financial analysts focus on return on equity (ROE) as the most important ratio since
it measures the return to owners. The DuPont framework (Figure 1.1), a method to analyse a
company’s financial health, help us understand the factors that contribute to an ROE, breaking it
down algebraically into three ingredients:
1. Profitability - how profitable a company is, for every dollar of revenue, how much does it earn
in net profit (profit margin).
11
2. Productivity - ROE can be bolstered by productivity as well, represented by the asset turnover
ratio that measures how efficiently a company can use its assets to generate sales.
1. Includes the effects of leverage, thus does not purely measure operational performance. Hence,
some people prefer a return on capital, that compares EBIT to a firm’s capitalization (debt
+ equity).
Some observations regarding these key metrics within the DuPont Framework:
• High performing companies all tend to have a similar ROE despite coming from different
industries. This is because they don’t compete in product markets, they all compete in capital
markets. Hence, their ROE can’t be too different otherwise capital will be driven away from
lower performers towards better performers.
• ROE will differ when the risk associated with the company is different. If the shareholders bear
more risk, they are going to demand a higher return. Thus, capital markets and the competition
across companies drive returns to shareholders together and risk drives them apart.
• Profitability depends on the real value added e.g. food retailers don’t add much value, thus
they have lower profit margins than chipmakers that turns sand into computers.
• Varying levels of leverage reflect the amount of business risk because it is unwise to pile financial
risk on top of business risk. Thus, it is usually the case that the higher the business risk the
lower the leverage/financial risk.
• As mentioned before the inclusion of leverage is a major problem as leverage tends to infect the
final calculation as companies overcome poor operational performance (inefficient deployment
of capital - debt + equity) by making its owners bear more risk.
12
Chapter 2
Using accounting statements to understand corporate performance has its drawbacks as it places an
emphasis on net profit when measuring economic returns. Finance professionals turn towards cash
as a better measure of economic returns. There are three alternative definition of cash - earnings
before interest, taxes, debt, and amortization (EBITDA); operating cash flow; and free
cash flow.
In addition, the field of finance is fundamentally forward looking, leading us to consider the
time value of money and methods for translating future cash flows into the present, which will be
foundational in thinking about any investment or valuation decision.
2.1 Cash
Disadvantages of using net profit to measure corporate performance:
• Net profit subtracts interest payments, which makes it hard to compare companies that finance
themselves in different ways even though their operations could be quite similar.
• Managerial decisions are involved in calculating profits. Accounting asks managers to make
decisions in order to smooth returns, as accountants consider that to be more consistent with
reality. E.g. Up-front payment for equipment has to be capitalized, placed on the balance sheet
and then depreciated over time. Revenue similarly may need to be recognized over time. This
smoothing process is subjective which allows managers to manipulate profits unlike cash that
is less susceptible to managerial discretion.
2.1.1 EBIT
Net profit
+ interest
+ taxes
EBIT
• EBIT (operating profit) gives a clearer view of how efficient and profitable a company is rel-
ative to net profit by not subtracting interest and taxes which are not related to operational
performance.
13
• EBIT isn’t quite a measure of cash, as it is calculated after subtracting non-cash expenses such
as depreciation and amortization.
2.1.2 EBITDA
Hence, for a fuller picture, finance professionals use EBITDA:
Net profit
+ interest
+ taxes
+ depreciation and amortization
EBITDA
Amazon in 2014 provides a compelling distinction between the three different measures:
The difference of $419 million between EBIT and net profit represents taxes, interest, and currency
adjustments. Overall, Amazon generated lots of cash, as measured by EBITDA, but had losses
according to profitability measures due to $4.746 billion in depreciation and amortization.
EBITDA can be more relevant for some industries than others. One way to appreciate the
difference that depreciation makes is to compare it to net profit.
For instance, unlike EA, a software company, Comcast has invested heavily to create cable and
internet networks. Hence, because of those heavy investments, using net profit as a measure of
performance can result in a distorted picture and flawed comparisons, as Comcast will naturally
experience much more depreciation given its infrastructure-heavy industry. The Michael Companies
is somewhere between EA and Comcast, given its brick-and-mortar footprint.
14
Net profit
+ depreciation and amortization
- increases in accounts receivable
- increases in inventory
+ increases in unearned revenue
+ increases in accounts payable
Operating cash flow
Depreciation and amortization, increases in unearned revenue, and increases in accounts payable
are added to the net profit, as they are non-cash expenses. Meanwhile, increases in accounts receivable
and inventory are subtracted, as they are non-cash revenue. Operating cash flow is different from
EBITDA in several ways:
• It considers the cost of working capital (inventory, accounts receivable, accounts payable).
• It accounts for tax and interest payments by beginning with net profit.
• It includes non-cash expenses other than depreciation and amortization, such as share-based
compensation.
For the rest of the cash flow statement, the investing section emphasizes ongoing investments that
bypass the income statement and go straight into the balance sheet, such as capital expenditures
and acquisitions. Meanwhile, the financing section examines whether a company has offered debt or
paid back debt or issued equity or bought back stock, and reveals the cash consequences of doing so.
Operating activities
Net profit
+ depreciation and amortization
± cash provided by changes in operating assets and liabilities
= Net cash provided by operating activities
Investing activities
- Additions to property, plant, and equipment
± mergers/divestments
= Net cash provided by investing activities
Financing activities
- Cash dividend
- repurchase of common stock
+ issuance of debt or equity
= Net cash provided by financing activities
Net increase/decrease in cash and cash equivalents
As Figure 2.1, the statement maps how cash positions changes over the course of the year because
of operating performance along with investing and financing decisions.
15
Figure 2.1: Starbucks’ Cash Flow Statement, 2017
1. Accounts receivable - amounts that customers, typically other businesses, owe a company.
The dollar amount can be re-framed as a receivables collection period, which shows the average
number of days it takes for customers to pay the company.
2. Inventory - the goods, and the associated inputs, held by a company prior to sale. Based on
inventory, you can generate a days inventory, which shows the average number of days that the
company holds inputs and goods.
3. Accounts payable - the amounts a company owes to suppliers. Based on that, you can
generate a days payable, which indicates the average number of days the company takes to pay
the suppliers.
16
Figure 2.2: The cash conversion cycle
Thus, 110 days elapse between the time the hammer is bought to getting cash for it. In addition,
the store only pays cash for the hammer 30 days after buying it. From a cash perspective, cash needs
to be generated to pay for the hammer 80 days before receiving the cash, a funding gap (Figure 2.2).
To reduce the financing gap there are a number of options:
• Reduce the days inventory - can be done easily by stocking less inventory. The store will sell
out faster and need less financing. However, the danger is if customers can’t find the product
they want they will go to rivals.
• Reduce the receivables collection period - done by extending less credit to customers.
However, this may lead to customers going to other rivals, losing the competitive edge.
• Increase the payable period - paying suppliers late may erode relationships, they may
become reluctant to supply products or be less willing to extend credit.
During a recession, companies hold on to their inventory longer and customers take longer to
pay up. Thus, the whole cash conversion cycle expands as the days inventory and collection periods
increase, creating a larger gap that cannot be financed as banks recoil. This leads to a decrease in
global trade.
Vendors can offer companies discounts in exchange for paying faster (shortening the days payable).
If a company pays vendors in 40 days and the prevailing interest rate is 20% and a supplier offers a
1% discount if the company meets the obligation within 10 days:
• The supplier is charging an implicit interest rate of 1% for a 30 day loan.
• The bank will charge an interest rate of well over 1% for 30 days (20 / 365 * 30 = 1.64).
• The supplier’s financing is cheaper, so the company should take financing from the supplier,
not the bank.
• Hence, don’t take the deal as that would force the company to take the more expensive financing
from the bank to fund the extra 30 day gap.
There can be certain special business models that lead to special cash conversion cycles:
• Salesforce - software-as-a-service (SaaS) business that sells subscriptions. Thus, business
customers pay in advance and receive the use of software for the period they’ve paid for.
Hence, Salesforce will have a negative receivable collection period because it gets paid before it
provides services. It has no inventory and thus no days inventory, and it will not pay suppliers
immediately, creating a payables period. By taking payment first and then providing services,
Salesforce is getting customers and suppliers to finance its operations.
17
• Dell - first takes the order from a customer and then starts manufacturing the product (just-
in-time manufacturing), thus decreasing it cash conversion cycle by lowering its days inventory
and leading to a reduction in the financing costs of its working capital.
• Tesla - takes deposit from customers for future models, although it may not be the full price
of a car, it still represents the customer financing of Tesla’s operations. Hence, customers help
reduce the amount that Tesla must rely on capital providers.
• Amazon averaged 46 days of inventory, and it collected from its customers after 21 days on
average.
• Due to its market dominance, Amazon can exert a large amount of power over its suppliers to
make them wait before getting paid. It averaged 91 days to pay its suppliers.
• Thus, Amazon had a negative cash conversion cycle of -24 days in 2014.
• Hence, it’s operations became a source of cash, allowing the company to grow rapidly without
seeking external financing.
• The cash they generate from their working capital becomes a powerful part of their business
model i.e. their suppliers are financing their growth.
• Amazon has stock-based compensation, that is recorded as an expense in the income statement
and lowers net profit. However, it is not a cash change, thus it is added back to operating cash
flows as a non-cash expense.
• When Amazon issues stock to fund its server farms, it will show up in the financing section of
the cash flow statement.
• Amazon’s working capital for 2014 seems to be a drain of cash as it’s cash conversion cycle fell
from -27 to -23 days, thus it’s working capital required a cash investment during that period
as the negative working capital cycle became less negative.
• Removes the distorting effects of non-cash expenses such as depreciation and amortization like
EBITDA.
• Acknowledges that capital expenditures are required for growth and have been avoided so far.
18
In summary, free cash flow isolates the cash that is truly free to be distributed or used however
the company sees fit.
EBIT
- taxes
= EBIAT
+ depreciation and amortization
± changes in working capital
- capital expenditures
Free cash flow
Figure 2.3, a simplified balance sheet, provides an alternate way to visualize free cash flow:
• The net assets side of the balance sheet is divided between the working capital (e.g. inventories
and accounts receivables less accounts payable) and fixed assets (e.g. property, plant, and
equipment).
• The financing side of the balance sheet is divided between debt and equity.
• This modified balance sheet now distinguishes between the operations (left-hand side) and the
capital providers (right-hand side).
• The flow that operations generate that end up with the capital providers are the free cash
flows, calculated as follows.
19
- The operations of a business generate EBIT, but the government takes its share to make
it EBIAT.
- From there, you must consider the company’s ongoing investments into working
capital and fixed assets (capital expenditure) as it grows.
- Finally, non-cash expenses such as depreciation and amortization that should never
have been expensed must be added back.
- Whatever is left is free cash flow (can also be calculated by subtracting capital
expenditure from operating cash flow).
Finance has slowly been moving towards free cash flow (Figure 2.4) for evaluating returns over
the last 50 years because it captures all the cash consequences of a business, and it ensures that the
underlying flows are free to the capital providers.
Figure 2.4: The shift from revenues to free cash flows, 1960s-2020s
2.2.1 Discounting
The equation below illustrates the effect of the discount rate, r, when you wait a year:
Cash f low
(2.3)
(1 + r)
For example, to determine how much $1,000 received one year from now is worth today:
• Thus, a $1,000 payment received one year in the future has present value of 1000
1+0.05
= $952.38.
20
• In other words, if you give the bank $952.38 today, it will give you $1,000 next year.
• If the interest rate is 10%, you would need to deposit $909.09 in the bank, instead of $952.38
to receive $1,000 in a year.
• Meanwhile, if interest rates fell to 2%, you would need to deposit $980.39 to get $1,000 a year
later.
• You punish future cash flows much more in the 10% interest rate scenario because your oppor-
tunity cost is higher whilst you punish the future cash flows much less in the 2% scenario.
For cash flows over multiple years into the future, the one-year discounting process has to be
repeated:
Cash f low1 cash f low2 cash f low3
+ + ... (2.4)
(1 + r) (1 + r)2 (1 + r)3
where r is still the annual discount or interest rate and the subscripts next to the cash flow
indicates the year that the cash will be received. In this case, if the bank offers a $1,000 payment
for each of the next three years with an interest rate of 5 %:
1, 000 1, 000 1, 000
+ 2
+ = $952.38 + $907.03 + $863.84 = $2, 723.25
(1 + 0.05) (1 + 0.05) (1 + 0.05)3
2. Think about what incremental cash flows will be generated over time.
3. Discount them back to the present using the notion of an opportunity cost of capital.
Working out the present value of a project involves adding up all the potential cash flows,
positive and negative, after they’ve been discounted today:
cash f low1 cash f low2 cash f low3 cash f low4
P resent value0 = + + + ... (2.5)
(1 + r) (1 + r)2 (1 + r)3 (1 + r)4
Determining the net present value entails the same calculations, but it includes the initial cost
of the project:
If managers care about value creation, then the most important financial decision rule they should
follow is to undertake only positive NPV projects.
21
Nike Factory Case Study
If Nike is building a new show factory at a cost of $75 million, assuming the plant will produce
$25 million in cash every year for the next 5 years with a 10% discount rate:
25 25 25 25 25
1
+ 2
+ 3
+ 4
+ = $94.8M
(1.10) (1.10) (1.10) (1.10) (1.10)5
The present value of the project is $94.8 million and by paying $75 million, Nike will generate
$19.8 million in net present value. Thus, Nike should go ahead and build the factory.
However, after the next year, Nike has only made $10 million and expects this trend to continue
for the next 4 years:
10 10 10 10
1
+ 2
+ 3
+ = $31.7M
(1.10) (1.10) (1.10) (1.10)4
If a rival company offers Nike $40 million to buy the factory, Nike should take the offer. This is
because despite spending $75 million, that is a sunk cost that cannot be recovered and is irrelevant
to the current decision. Meanwhile, the offer has a positive NPV of $8.3 million.
22
Chapter 3
Capital markets critical for the growth of the economy and increasingly guide policymakers and
managers. However, these markets have also caused great skepticism about their value and wisdom.
For a simple version of capital markets (Figure 3.1), there will be individuals and households on
one side that have savings that they want to invest. On the other side are companies that need
capital to build new projects and grow. However, in reality there are many more intermediaries that
make the world of finance much more complex (Figure 3.2):
23
Centring our perspective from that of an equity research analyst we can analyse the capital mar-
kets. The analyst’s job is to value companies by creating forecasts and then make recommendations
to investors.
24
3.2.2 Pension Funds
• Large pools of money that represent the retirement assets of workers from a particular company,
union, or government entity.
• Defined Benefit (DB) Plans - employees receive payments after retirement from their em-
ployers, which are funded by pension plans run by those companies or organisations.
• The shift away from DB plans towards DC plans has fueled massive growth in mutual funds.
• These foundations and endowments are now large innovative players in capital markets e.g.
Harvard controls a $37.1 billion endowment (2017).
• E.g. Norwegian sovereign wealth fund manages more than $1 trillion (2017).
• Although similar to mutual funds, they are differentiated by their lower level of regulation, use
of leverage and their different approach to managing risk.
• Hedge funds which include many pension, endowment and sovereign wealth funds as customers,
have lower levels of regulation because only rich investors can buy them.
• Hence, managers are less constrained in their attitude towards risk and can use leverage to
amplify returns.
• Unlike mutual funds, hedge funds can also take more concentrated positions in companies,
which allows them to become activist shareholders that promote policies and strategies most
beneficial to their investors.
- Going long - buying the stock, expecting its value to increase and then selling it at a
higher price to earn a profit.
- Going short - borrow shares from another investor, such as a mutual fund, which charges
a fee for lending the shares to you. Once you’ve borrowed the shares, you sell them. At
some point in the future, you buy back the shares hopefully at a lower price and return
them.
25
Figure 3.3: Comparison of stock prices for Merck and Pfizer, Dec 2011-Dec 2014
- For example, a hedge fund that invests in Merck, a global pharmaceutical company, man-
ages the risk of that investment by shorting Pfizer, another pharmaceutical company to
manage its exposure.
- During 2012, both stocks were moving together quite tightly and had gone up 20% by
December. If you sold your Merck shares and repurchased Pfizer shares at year end you
would end up at the same place, as the gains from you long position (+20%) are offset by
the losses on your short position (-20%).
- In 2014, Merck outperformed Pfizer, it rose 70% whilst Pfizer rose 60%. Because your
long outperformed your short, you made money (+10%).
- Hedging can help insulate an investor from sector-wide or market-wide movements and
isolate the relative performance of a given company.
- Thus, risk is effectively managed as you are now only exposed to the relative out-performance
or under-performance of a given company’s stock.
• Hedge fund managers also receive carried interest, allowing them to participate in the economic
returns of their funds.
3.3.1 Traders
• Ensure that there are buyers and sellers for various financial instruments.
• They make money largely from the gap known as the bid-ask spread.
• A bid is the highest price an investor is willing to pay for a share, while the ask is the lowest
price that a seller is willing to sell a share for.
• Those on the buy side don’t pay analysts directly for their reports, rather they can choose to
trade through the trader associated with equity analyst they like, who then makes commissions
on those trade. However, these commissions have narrowed significantly over time and don’t
form a large part of an analyst compensation.
26
• Despite declining commissions, it is still valuable for broker-dealers to process trades, as it is
valuable to know the trading activity of large institutional investors because these transactions
contain information.
• Thus, good equity analysts ensure that their traders get a share of trade flow.
3.3.2 Salespeople
• Salespeople sell financial instruments to investors on the buy side.
• Analysts might talk directly to the larger institutional investors, but salespeople disseminate
the analyst’s ideas to the broader community to woo the buy side more directly.
• Financing arranged by investment banks, such as initial public offerings (IPOs), equity offerings,
and debt offerings, allows companies to access new funding.
• The mergers and acquisitions (M&A) departments help companies divest portions of their
businesses or acquire new businesses.
• Both IPOs and M&As are extremely lucrative, fees for equity financings can be as high as
7% of the proceeds for an IPO, whilst advisory fees on M&A can be close to 1%. These fees
typically dwarf other trading revenue streams.
• Analysts often provide commentary on the latest developments and will use those occasions to
communicate their more general views of a company.
• In theory, analysts should supply the buy side with the best analysis possible to make capital
markets work well. However, in reality, analysts can often be biased towards being positive,
rarely issuing “sell” recommendations and instead issuing a disproportionate share of “buy”
recommendations.
27
• If an analyst issues a negative report on a stock, which says a company is overvalued, investors
will appreciate the truth and rank the analyst highly. However, the CEO and CFO of the
company may try shut out the analyst by not engaging with them or not taking their questions
on the next conference call.
• In addition, they may also signal to the analyst’s investment banking colleagues that they won’t
work with them on future M&A and financing deals.
• Thus, analysts instead say things like “market perform” or “neutral”, which really means “sell”.
- Young research analysts at less prestigious investment banks with nothing to lose often
say crazy, extreme things. If they’re right, they shoot up in the rankings, and it they are
wrong, no one was paying attention anyway.
- Meanwhile, higher-ranked analysts may “herd” alongside closely ranked analysts to pre-
vent being overtaken. This can be done by estimating earnings to be precisely in between
the estimates of other analysts. However, this is not what analysts should be doing.
• Thus, incentives for the people at the center of the capital markets are considerably more
complicated.
• In a world of perfect information, capital markets are relatively simple - they just need to pool
resources and price risk.
• However, in a world of asymmetric information, capital markets need to figure out how to
allocate capital when you don’t know whom to believe.
• The problem of capital markets is a manifestation of an even more general problem known as
the principal-agent problem.
• The separation of ownership and control creates the problem of corporate governance: how do
shareholders ensure that managers are pursuing their interests?
• For example, if a CEO advises the owners that a large acquisition is a great idea - does she
just want to run a larger company and get the prestige that comes along with it to get a better
job with more pay? So is the acquisition great for the company or the CEO?
28
- For instance, if a CEO misses an earnings forecast by a penny and attributes it to bad
weather conditions. Is it true or does the mistake signal the beginning of the end of the
company?
- Suspicion by investors about the company helps explain the large price drops associated
with small earnings misses because those misses may be for more than one quarter. It’s
about credibility and asymmetric information.
- When a CEO announces that she is divesting part of her shareholding in a normal portfolio
rebalancing plan, it could be true. However, the reality is that someone who knows much
about the future of the company is selling shares and that is alarming.
- For companies, the problem of asymmetric information can also affect whether they finance
their projects through equity, debt, or internally generated profits, as each method signals
a different message to investors.
- For example if a company uses equity, investors may balk because: If the project is so
great, why issue new shares and share the upside if the owners are so confident about the
future? Why wouldn’t they keep the upside for themselves by issuing debt?
- This is the reason equity issuance is usually associated with stock price declines. It’s not
because of dilution or an accounting argument, it’s because it sends a negative signal.
- To some investors, the company seems unwilling to finance the project internally that no
longer seems that attractive. Thus, equity becomes the most expensive source of financing.
- Debt seems a little better as although the company is still relying on external capital
providers, it’s not giving up ownership. However, investors will always question why a
company goes to outside sources for funding.
- The best source of financing is internally generated funds, as there’s no informational cost
associated with it, but it can be a limited source.
- Lastly, when a CEO announces a stock buyback, she’s implicitly telling investors she
thinks the stock is undervalued. Hence, stock buybacks are good news, not because fewer
shares are outstanding, but because they send a powerful signal of confidence from the
managers who know more than investors.
- Punish managers more when they lie - however this can lead them to say less and less,
thus increasing the level of asymmetric information.
- Pay managers with more equity - encourage them to behave like owners want them to.
Has become more popular recently, however managers may orient their performance to
short-term results and then sell their shares at peak-level.
- Create a board of directors - above managers to monitor them. However, managers often
pick those directors, leading to conflict of interest.
- Potential solutions lead to collateral consequences that can amplify rather than alleviate
the problem.
- Private equity - can help by effectively replacing dispersed owners with one large owner
who carefully monitors, and uses leverage to constrain management. However, private
equity also creates its own issues - these investors realise profits by issuing stock to capital
markets and have incentives to make their companies appear better than they are prior
to going public.
29
Chapter 4
• Market value - measures how much a company is worth according to the financial markets (a
forward-looking assessment of the value of a company)
• The market-to-book ratio is calculated by dividing the market value by the book value
of a company.
- For instance in 2017, the market value of Facebook’s equity was $512.8 billion, whilst its
book value was much lower, $74.3 billion.
- This yielded a market-to-book ratio of 6.9.
- Given that market values emphasize future cash flows, the market clearly thought highly
of Facebook’s prospects and its ability to create value.
• The firm has a book value of $100, as it has just been capitalized with $100.
• The company is expected to reinvest 50% of its profits in the company. The re-investments
represent growth opportunities and earn similar returns to its current ROE.
• The company will end its operations after 10 years, and anything that’s left will be dis-
tributed to the shareholders. It will sell all of its assets for a onetime cash flow (assume
it can do so at the book value of those assets at that time).
• Future cash flows will be discounted at a rate of 15% because shareholders expect a
return of 15%.
The company’s book value is simply $100. To determine its market-to-book ratio, we need to
determine its market value by forecasting and discounting future cash flows:
30
1. Take the initial book value of $100, apply the 20% ROE ($20) and then distribute half to
shareholders ($10) and reinvest the other half ($10) in the company.
2. The apply the 15% discount rate to those dividends (1/1.15 = 0.87).
3. Repeat the first two steps until the 10th year, when whatever is left in the company is liquidated
and returned to the shareholders.
In this particular case, the current market value, based on future expectations is greater than 100
(Figure 4.1), giving a market-to-book ratio greater than 1.3.
• In Figure 4.2, it is evident that the market value drops to exactly 100, giving a ratio of 1.
31
• This is because the company has merely met expectations as its ROE is equal to the cost
of capital, thus the company is not creating value.
• A company only creates value if the expected return exceeds the cost of capital.
• If the ROE were to drop below 15% (the cost of capital), the ratio would be less than 1 and the
company is now destroying value as it is not providing returns commensurate with the capital
provider’s expectations.
Project Duration
Now factoring in project duration too, we examine the first section of Figure 4.2 with 30% earnings
reinvested and the discount rate remains fixed at 15%:
• The highest market-to-book ratio is at the bottom right, as the company is earnings its highest
ROE, leading to higher market values, for the longest period of time.
• Hence, high ROEs over a long time span is what what makes market-to-book ratios and
value creation significant.
• In contrast, the smallest market-to-book ratio is in the bottom left, as the company’s ROE
doesn’t beat the cost of capital (the discount rate) and this situation persists for the longest
duration (30 years), resulting in the most value destruction.
• Finally, when the ROE is 15% and equal to the cost of capital, the market-to-book ratio will
always be 1 regardless of how long the project duration is as the company is not going
to create or destroy value no matter how long it operates.
Reinvestment Rate
Investigating the effect of varying the reinvestment rates from 30% to 70% to 100%, we can observe
from all sections of Figure 4.2 that:
• The highest market-to-book ratio (by a large margin) is in the bottom right corner of the table,
as the company is consistently beating its cost of capital by a wide margin over the
longest duration (30 years), and is reinvesting all those profits at this higher rate for
the whole duration, creating lots of value.
• The worst scenario is at the bottom left, as the company is not meeting the cost of capital
and does so over a long period of time (30 years), constantly destroying value.
• Furthermore, it never distributes any money until the very end and so even more value
is being destroyed when the company invests more profits at that relatively low rate of
return.
• Similar to the previous sections, the 15% ROE scenario always gives a market-to-book
ratio of 1 because the company is just meeting its cost of capital.
• It can keep cash inside or release it, and it can do so for many years or just a few; it doesn’t
matter because value is being neither created or destroyed.
32
4.1.2 Summary
To create value, companies must do three things:
1. They must beat their cost of capital.
2. They must beat their cost of capital for many years.
3. They must reinvest additional profits at high rates through growth.
These measures correspond to business strategy, as beating a cost of capital is all about creating
a competitive advantage through innovation. Furthermore, keeping the gap open between returns
and costs of capital for longer periods is what barriers to entry, brands, and intellectual property are
all about. Finally, reinvesting more profits is all about growing an opportunity through expansions,
adjacencies, or integration.
33
4.2.1 The cost of debt
• Determining the cost of debt is fairly straightforward because debt has a fixed return, hence the
cost of capital is simply the interest rate that a lender will charge you when you are undertaking
a project.
• To determine an interest rate, a bank will examine the riskiness of the underlying business, the
stability of its cash flows, and its credit rating.
• Technically, that interest rate is the promised return and there is a probability that the issuer
will default, meaning that the expected return is slightly lower.
• The interest rate has two components that correspond to the reasons we penalise cash flows
for making us wait:
• This idea of a risk-free investment is approximated by the interest rate on government securities
such as US Treasury bonds.
• Investors still charge a cost of capital in the absence of risk because they not only dislike risk,
but also they prefer their money now rather than later, so they want to be compensated for
any expected inflation that reduces their purchasing power, incurred by delaying their wealth.
Credit spreads
• A credit spread reflects the additional cost associated with the riskiness of the debt.
• At that time, Walmart, an AA-rated company, issued $16 billion of debt and paid an interest
rate of 3.55%, implying a credit spread of 0.59%.
• At the same time, CVS, a BBB company, issued debt with an interest rate of 4.33%, implying
a credit spread of 1.37%.
• Cequel Communications, a cable company, issued CCC debt at 7.5%, implying a credit spread
of 4.54%.
34
Bond maturity
• Rates are also influence by the amount of time until the bond will be paid, known as the bond’s
maturity date.
Figure 4.3: Yield curves for bonds with varying risk and maturities, 30 July 2018
• Yield curves normally slope upwards, as longer-term bonds typically need to offer a higher
interest rate than short-term bonds.
• A steep curve reflects that future interest rates are expected to be higher and longer-term bonds
must compensate investors for fixing their interest rates for a longer period, as future interest
rates might be expected to be higher because of future growth or inflation expectations.
• In addition, the corporate AAA and CCC bond yield curves lie above the treasury curve because
of the risk premium increasing the cost of debt, as mentioned before.
• Overall, bond yield curves change constantly in response to market expectation about the
future.
• The right capital structure varies by industry and by the relative riskiness of those industries.
• Regulated monopolies like power companies often have capital structure heavily weighted to-
wards debt because of their steady cash flows whilst high-risk companies with unpredictable
futures are weighted toward equity.
• One way to envision the decision about capital structure is to consider the offsetting incentives
to use debt based on taxation and the costs and probabilities of failure.
• Figure 4.4 below does this by first ignoring these effects and then layering them on when
depicting the relationship between capital structure and overall firm value:
35
Figure 4.4: Optimal capital structure
• Beginning with the blue line that ignores the effects of taxation and the costs of failure, the
value is invariant to capital structure, as all value comes from real operations of a firm. This
acts a reminder that the deployment of assets, not financial engineering, is the source of all
real value creation.
• However, because interest payments are deductible, they allow you shield income from taxation.
As you take on more debt relative to equity, you shield more income from the government, and
value increases, as shown by the orange line.
• Now, considering the effect of too much leverage on business operations, companies that go
bankrupt or approach bankruptcy incur significant operations costs. Customers and employees
leave, and financing becomes more of a strain. Hence, as leverage goes up, it’s more likely that
firms will experience these operational costs and value will decrease quickly given the precarious
status of the firm as shown by the green line. The way these costs begin destroying value will
vary by the nature of the business. Very stable businesses won’t incur those costs until they’re
at really high levels of leverage. In contrast, very risky businesses could incur costs of financial
distress early on.
• When combining tax effects with the costs of financial distress to produce the red line, it
is evident that weighing tax benefits relative to the costs of financial distress will provide
the value-maximising capital structure. Firms from different industries will have different
capital structures that reflect a trade-off between tax benefits and the costs of financial distress
associated with that underlying industry. The optimal capital structure for a given industry
will provide the weights for costs of equity and debt used in the WACC calculation.
36
Figure 4.5: Impact of diversification on portfolio risk
As Figure 4.6 shows, as you add more securities to a portfolio, the overall volatility of the portfolio
decreases, but there is a level above which the gains from diversification diminish. Importantly, there
is some volatility you can never fully diversify away, the system risk or the risk of holding the
market. Hence, every security’s risk is not measured by how much it moves around in general, but
rather by how much each stock moves with the market, which represents the risk that will never be
diversified away.
Betas
• The measure of how a stock moves with the market is called a beta..
• If a company has a beta of 1, it generally moves in sync with the market: if the market is up
by 10%, the stock will go up by 10%.
• If the company has a beta of 2: if the market goes up by 10%, then the company’s stock goes
up by 20%.
• If a company has a beta of -1: if the market goes up by 10%, then the stock will go down by
10%.
- Plot the monthly returns for a given company against the monthly returns for the market.
- Draw a line that best fits the data i.e. a regression line.
- The slope of that line is equal to the beta, a measure of the correlation between a given
company’s returns and the market’s returns.
37
• High-beta companies expose shareholders to larger amounts of systematic risk that they can’t
diversify away.
• Hence, investors charge them a higher cost of equity and these firms have a higher WACC.
• In contrast, for a negative beta company, the costs of equity are going to be low.
• They might even be negative, which means that their WACC will be lower, which means their
values will be higher.
• When the market goes up, this asset will perform poorly, whilst the opposite occurs when the
market does poorly.
• Overall, investors don’t demand much return from negative beta assets, leading to high values.
• The price of risk is the out-performance of equities relative to risk-free instruments like treasury
bonds, acting as the compensation investors demand for bearing equity risk, also known as the
market risk premium.
CAPM
When we put together the ideas of the price of risk and the quantity of risk, we get an equation for
the cost of equity:
• At a minimum, investors will demand at least the risk-free rate or the amount you charge when
you lend money to the government.
• In addition, there has to be some notion of a risk adjustment that will be composed of the
quantity of risk and the price of risk.
• Betas, that represent the quantity of risk, in combination with the price of risk, gives you the
expected return for a given industry or company, and thus the cost of equity.
38
• Figure 4.7 graphs the equation for expected returns to investors.
• As betas increase, expected returns increase. Note that zero beta assets have an expected
return equal to the risk-free rate.
• Active investment management is all about pursuing assets that deviate from the line and
deliver more than the expected return.
• This gap is called alpha, the source of value creation, as isolating it means you’re delivering
greater-than-expected return.
Whilst the CAPM is a really powerful theory, it’s also predicated on several assumptions that
don’t always hold:
• It assumes no transaction costs and investors that are able to borrow and lend at relatively low
rates, any many of these assumptions are inconsistent with reality.
• In addition, the theory relies on the idea that investors are highly rational - an assumption
that has proven tenuous.
• Most concerning, it does not always appear that realised returns line up with betas as suggested
by Figure 4.7.
• All various industries and investments expose their capital providers to different risks, so every
industry requires a different cost of capital.
• Consider the scenario where a conglomerate invest in three different industries - aerospace,
healthcare, and media - with three different betas using the average cost of capital:
- For the media industry, the correct use of capital is actually higher than what’s being
used. Hence, the conglomerate is giving too much to projects in that industry (the cost of
capital is actually higher than what the conglomerate thinks meaning that the discount
rate is higher/the NPV is lower, making this investment more attractive than it actually
is), and end up over-investing in those businesses.
39
- Similarly, for aerospace, the cost of capital that should have been used is lower, hence the
conglomerate is penalising those investment opportunities too much and end up under-
investing.
• Overall, the appropriate cost of capital isn’t a function who is investing but rather of what
you’re investing in.
• Risk is embedded in the asset, not the investor.
Figure 4.9: Asset betas, debt betas, and equity betas as a function of leverage
• Figure 4.9 shows what happens to betas on the vertical axis as the amount of debt used increases
on the horizontal axis:
- Asset beta doesn’t change as you use more debt as the behaviour of the assets relative to
the market doesn’t change as financing changes.
- For debt beta, when a company takes on the first dollar of debt, it’s relatively risk-free,
so debt betas are close to 0. However, as a company approaches complete debt financing,
debt betas approach the level of asset betas as the company is entirely debt-financed.
- For equity betas, when there’s little to no debt, equity betas are similar to asset betas,
but increase quickly when leverage increases, as the equity has become more risky and
therefore more expensive.
40
• However, this thinking is wrong as the right cost of capital has nothing to do with the company
or the alternative bidder.
• The right cost of capital is derived from the asset that the managers are buying, and that
should be the same for the two buyers.
• There’s no way the company can export its cost of capital to that asset, as the cost of capital
is not about who you are, but rather what you’re investing in.
• Hence, it doesn’t matter if you plan to use the cash on your balance sheet to make an acquisition
or if you have a highly levered or all-equity balance sheet, what matters is using the right cost
of capital for that investment, and that cost of capital should reflect the right capital structure
for that investment.
41
Chapter 5
5.1 Multiples
• A multiple is a ratio that compares the value of an asset to an operating metric associated with
that asset.
• A common multiple used in valuations is the price-to-earnings, or P/E, ratio, which Divides
a company’s stock price by its earnings per share.
• Alternatively, it’s the value of a company’s equity divided by its net profit.
• A P/E multiple of 15X reflects expectations of the future, you’re not just paying for $1 of
earnings, you are for a stream of future earnings that is expected to grow.
• Firms may grow earnings at very different rates and companies might be judged to have earnings
that vary in quality, hence the P/E ratio can vary across companies within an industry.
• However, earnings are a problematic measure (Chapter 2), we can use a more comprehensive
of cash, EBITDA, to construct multiples as well.
• In addition, there is another important capital to account for, a lender who provides debt, so
the multiples should reflect the fact companies can use debt as capital too.
• These two factors are considered in the use of enterprise value (EV) to EBITDA multiples
(EV/EBITDA), where EV is the sum of the market value of debt and equity, or the
value of the business.
• However, we have to be careful when using multiples for comparisons and assumptions as shown
when Twitter was valued during its IPO:
- To value Twitter, market participants emphasized its valuable user base and looked for
companies with comparable revenue models within social media.
- They turned to Facebook and calculated how much every user of Facebook was worth
(take its total stock market capitalization divided by its number of active users) and used
that multiple to value.
- At that time each Facebook user was worth slightly more than $98 and each LinkedIn
user was worth about $93.
- Right after its IPO, Twitter was trading at a valuation that indicated the market values
each of its 232 million active users at around $110.
42
- Since then, Twitter’s share price has consistently been outperformed by Facebook’s, indi-
cating that comparing the value of Facebook and Twitter users was faulty because of:
1. Varying levels of engagement with the platform
2. Different demographics of the user base
3. Different possibilities for monetizing their users for two platforms
• This example demonstrates how faulty comparisons and assumptions can lead to significant
misvaluations.
Project A Project B
Year 0 -$900,000 -$900,000
Year 1 500,000 0
Year 2 500,000 0
Year 3 300,000 1,670,000
• Project A has a payback period of less than 2 years, and project B has a payback period of 3
years.
43
• If payback period is your decision-making criterion, you should choose project A.
• By comparing these flows over time in this way, the time value of money is ignored. The second,
and even worse, problem is that the answer to a payback period analysis is a simple number
of years, but that’s not we are interested in - we are interested in creating value.
• The payback method could lead you to choose an investment because you get your money back
faster, but turn away from from an investment that creates much more value.
• For instance, using a discount rate of 10%, project A has a NPV of $193,160 and project B has
a NPV of $354,700.
• By using payback period, you selected the project with a considerably lower net present value,
which leads to much less value creation, reflecting why payback analysis is so problematic.
1. IRRs can give you the wrong answer because they’re focused on returns and not value creation.
You can compare 2 projects, and the higher IRR project might actually lead to less value
creation when you are interested in value creation, not in rate of return maximization.
2. If cash flows are characterized by outflows, and then inflows and outflows again, and then
inflows (as opposed to a simpler version using just ouflows and then inflows), IRRs can give
you wrong answers.
Moreover, IRRs incur these risks and don’t actually save any effort. Calculated IRRs must be
compared to a WACC using forecasted cash flows, so we need the same information as for discounting.
Referring back to the example in Table 5.1, we can illustrate the first problem:
• Assuming a discount rate of 10%, the NPV of project A was $193,160 and the NPV of project
B was $354,700.
• Ignoring NPV and focusing on IRR would have made you indifferent to the two projects.
There is a clearly dominant project choice that IRR analysis obscures. This difficulty occurs
in-part because managers are not interested in increasing returns, but should prioritize creating
value.
44
5.3 Discounted Cash Flows
The discounted cash flow method is the gold standard of valuation. We know that assets derive their
value from their ability to generate future cash flows, and those cash flows aren’t all created equal
- they requires discounting to translate them to today’s numbers. Furthermore, the appropriate
discount rate is a function of an investor’s expected returns as they translate into a manager’s cost
of capital. To perform the valuation we start with the present value formula:
This differs from Equation 2.5 with the inclusion of the terminal value, but the basic logic is the
same. All value today is derived from the expectation of future cash flows and we need to figure out
how to forecast those cash flows, decide which definition of cash, and what discount rate to use.
3. Add back non-cash expenses like depreciation and amortization because they should never have
been taken out
4. Accommodate the capital intensity of the business by penalizing it for investments in its working
capital and fixed assets
• The lab will require an initial capital expenditure of $2.5 million in year 0.
• The EBIT of $1 million is expected to increase by 5% every year thereafter. At the end
of year 5, operations will end and the assets will be sold for their salvage value of $1 million.
• During the life of the project, the assets will be depreciated and ongoing capital expenditures
will be made to maintain the assets. The net effects will be a $300,000 depreciation expense
and $300,000 in capital expenditures for years 1 to 5 to maintain the equipment.
• Working capital is required for the project and is assumed to equal 10% of EBIT. In other
wprds, in year 1, when EBIT goes from $0 to $1 million, the company will need to invest
$100,000 in working capital. In year 2, when EBIT goes from $1 million to $1.05
million, the company will need to invest $5,000 more in working capital. For simplicity,
let’s assume that all working capital associate with the project expires worthless at the end
of the five years.
45
• The company’s tax rate is 30% and there are no tax consequences to selling the asset
in year 5.
• Take the initial EBIT, grow the EBIT at the prescribed growth rate and adjust for tax payments
to get EBIAT. Then, follow the formula for free cash flows.
• The working capital calculation is not the level of working capital but rather the change in the
level of working capital.
• Lump together capital expenditures with the asset disposal in the final year, which creates a
positive cash flow in that year.
• It’s important to settle on a system of keeping track of what the inflows and outflows are e.g.,
all outflows are negative, then the totals for the free cash flows are just sum of the figures
Applying the information and steps should get you the following spreadsheet:
Figure 5.1: Calculating free cash flows for laboratory investment - figures in 1,000s
• The optimal capital structure for such investments is 35% debt and 65% equity.
46
• The beta is 1.1 - derived by calculating the gradient of the regression line from the plot of the
monthly returns for companies that capture the risk of the project against the market return
as shown in Figure 5.2.
D E
W ACC = ( )rD (1 − t) + ( )rE = 35% × 7% × (1 − 0.3) + 65% × 10.6% = 8.61% (5.4)
D+E D+E
where rd is the cost of debt, re is the cost of equity, D is the market value of the firm’s
debt, E is the market value of the firm’s equity, D + E is the total market value of the
firm’s financing (equity and debt), and t is the corporate tax rate.
The final step is to return to the forecasted free cash flows and determine net present values.
Discount factors are simply 1 divided 1 plus the WACC. Finally multiply all of the free cash flows
by the discount factors and sum them to determine the NPV as shown in Figure 5.3:
Figure 5.3: Calculating discounted cash flows and NPV for laboratory investment - figures in 1,000s
47
The NPV of this investment is $1.069 million and because it is positive, the lab project will create
value for the company, and it should be carried out. Alternatively, if you were to measure the present
value of the cash flows, it would be $3.569 million (simply exclude initial capital expenditure).
In addition, although multiples have their flaws, they can often double-check discounted cash
flow assumptions, so many companies use them as part of a multi-pronged valuation effort as a quick
short term proxy.
Multiples
The first method to get terminal values is via multiples. When you’ve reached an end point, e.g., 5
years into an investment, you could say that the company has reach a valuation of, for example, ten
times free cash flow.
Perpetuity formula
The other preferred method is to deploy the perpetuity formula that effectively calculates today’s
value for a stable set of cash flows. If you want to get the present value of a stream of cash flows
that doesn’t grow over time, you can just divide that cash flow by the discount rate:
Cash f low1
P erpetuity f ormula : (5.5)
discount rate
Meanwhile, the present value of a growing perpetuity is the initial cash flow divided by the
discount rate less the growth rate:
Cash f low1
Growing perpetuity f ormula : (5.6)
discount rarte − growth rate
• When you use this as part of a discounted cash flow analysis, the present values these formulas
provide are the present value as of the year before the initial cash flow.
• For example, if the numerator of the equation is the cash flow in year 6, the formula will produce
the present value in year 5. That means you will need to discount this value again in
order to get the present value today.
These formulas are not use more commonly, as there are many short-run dynamics that can be
very important to model - new factories, sales trajectories, cost reductions - and those dynamics can
have a large impact on value. You can only use these formulas when things settle into a steady state.
There’s a danger in this step of the valuation process, especially in the assumption of the growth
rate:
• For example, if the company is in an economy that’s growing at 3% and uses a terminal growth
of 7%, that’s an untenable assumption.
• It means that ultimately the company will take over the world, which we don’t really believe
will happen.
• As a consequence, in the long run, overall economic growth rates are a useful way to think
about what growth rates should be in a terminal value calculation.
48
Overall, one of the chief problems with discounted cash flow analysis is that so much of it depends
on the terminal value, the value for which you ultimately sell the business. So whenever you generate
a discounted cash flow analysis, you should print out what what percent of the overall valuation is
as a result of the sale of the business because then you’re not really thinking about the cash flow
generation in the business - you’re really making a bet on where you’ll be able to sell that business
ultimately.
For example, in 2013, Apple had a market value of ∼$500 billion, but it held more than $100
billion in excess cash that it didn’t require for its operations as shown in Figure 5.4. As a consequence,
the actual implicit value of the enterprise was lower than the market value. Hence, to get the value
of a company’s equity from the enterprise value, you need to think about how much debt and
cash there is.
Figure 5.4 shows Apple’s enterprise value and cash versus the market value of its debt and equity
from 2012 to 2016. In the figure, market values are used along with cash and debt levels to arrive at
implied enterprise values. When conducting a valuation of Apple’s business, you should compare
the valuation to the implied enterprise value rather than to the market value because those values
can differ by more than 30%.
49
example, if there’s a 10% chance that the value is $120 (best case), a 70% chance the value is $100
(base case), and a 20% chance of a $10 value (worst-case), what is the expected value?
Expected value = 10% × $120 + 70% × $100 + 10% × $10 = $84 (5.7)
Once you get the expected present value and know it’s associated with an enterprise value, this
should inform your bidding strategy if you’re buying a company:
• If you pay that price, your investment will have a NPV of 0, and you won’t have created any
value for yourself. Hence, it should be your final and ultimate bid.
• If you end up paying $75 for that asset, you’ve actually created $9 in value and unless you pay
less than the expected value, your purchase is not actually creating any value in expectation.
• If you pay up to the best-case scenario of $120, in the worst and base case, you have transferred
value to the seller and created no value in the best case. In expectation, you are destroying
value for your capital providers.
• Sellers of assets want acquirers to overpay and sellers control important sources of information,
including historic financial information.
• To prepare for a sale, the seller might make itself look particularly good by accelerating sales,
deferring costs, and under-investing.
• This circumstance makes due diligence a critical part of any acquisition process.
• The problem doesn’t stop with the seller. Typically, investment bankers get paid only on
completion, so they want you to make the deal.
• Even people within your company who have analysed the transaction have perverse incentives.
They may well anticipate getting a promotion to run the new division just acquired.
• Everyone involved in the transaction wants the transaction to happen and may subtly change
assumptions or forecasts to help make that outcome a reality.
50
5.4.2 Exaggerating synergies and ignoring integration costs
• Synergy is the idea that once merged, the value of the two companies will be greater than the
sum of the values of each individual company.
• On the surface, the idea of synergies isn’t unreasonable. For example, if you bring together two
sales forces and rationalize them, this should result in cost savings. If you bring two companies
together, you could control more capacity within the industry and gain more pricing power.
• The problem with synergies is that people tend to overestimate how quickly those synergies
will work and overestimate the magnitude of their effects.
• They ignore the fact that changing cultures and workforces takes time.
• The second, related problem is that, even if the synergies are legitimate, people will often
incorporate all those synergies into the price they pay for a company.
• That too can lead to over-payment since the rewards from the value creation of synergies are
transferred to the acquired company’s shareholders instead of being part of the value creation
the merger brings to the acquiring company.
• Ongoing growth in EBIT or free cash flows typically requires increasing the asset base through
capital expenditures, but those capital expenditures reduce free cash flows dollar-for-dollar and
are conveniently ignored by people anxious to do deals.
• For example, terminal values will assume perpetual growth rates but in the final year you are
modelling (which serves as the basis of the terminal value), capital expenditures will just equal
depreciation, indicating no growth in assets.
• Hence, the valuation of company such as Tesla hinges not just on customer growth - it must
build factories to satisy that demand - so understating capital intensity can lead to incorrect
valuations.
51
Chapter 6
Capital Allocation
Generating free cash flows is critical for thinking about how and if companies create value. But that
leads to a few questions:
• Once a company is generating free cash flows, what should management do with that cash?
• Should managers invest that cash in new projects?
• Should they acquire companies?
• Or should they distribute the cash to their shareholders?
• In recent years, we’ve seen a large increase in share buybacks, sometimes called repurchases.
Why are companies undertaking repurchases?
Together these questions determine the capital allocation process. Capital providers entrust
managers with their capital and consider the fulfillment of the related obligation as a central indicator
of how well management is doing their job.
52
• The capital allocation problem is best understood as a nested series of decisions as seen in
Figure 6.1.
• The first question a manager has to address involved the availability of positive net present
value (NPV) projects to spend money on. Creating value is central to a manager’s task, and
that process involves beating the cost of capital, year over year, and growing.
• If positive NPV projects are available to you then you should undertake them.
• Those projects may involve organic growth - e.g., introducing new products or buying new
PP&E - or inorganic growth via M&A.
• If there aren’t value-creating opportunities (projects with positive NPVs) then a manager
should distribute the cash to shareholders through dividends or share buybacks.
• If you choose dividends, you’ll need to decide if you will create a regular dividend or issue a
special one-time dividend.
• First, you need to calculate the NPV of a number of options in order to identify the best
value-creation opportunities.
• They could be organic or inorganic, and although the simple rule is to pursue the option with
the highest NPV, there are a number of trade-offs to consider.
• For example, there are many problems to consider when undergoing M&A, which can compli-
cate present value assessments.
• Buyers need to understand the assets they’re acquiring, but in the end, they have to remember
that the seller has a large information advantage.
• Approaching a sale, buyers might under-invest in assets to understate the capital intensity
of the business. They might accelerate revenues and delay costs and bury problems such as
bankrupt customers who owe them by declaring those receivables still open.
• Intermediaries, like consultants and investment banks, can help buyers with these problems,
and the buyer’s own deal teams can find out where the bodies are buried.
53
• Unfortunately, everyone involved, from the seller to the intermediaries to the people within the
buyer’s organization who are on those deal teams, are incentivized to complete a transaction -
often leading to over-paying for assets.
• Hence, the notion that M&A is safer than organic investment is far from well-grounded, and
the data on the failure rates of mergers directly contradict their supposed safety.
• At the time of a merger, it’s common to overestimate synergies, underestimate the time to
realize them, and underestimate the onetime costs to realize the synergies.
• Even worse, the acquirer can end up retaining two separate capacities for various functions for
along time, resulting in significantly higher costs than it had anticipated. The time it takes to
realize synergies can have a massive impact on the value creation of the merger.
• Finally, cultural issues in bringing in two organizations together must be considered. While the
difficulty of cultural integration is easy to ignore on a spreadsheet, the issues raised by cultural
differences are paramount and have significant financial consequences. Those assumptions in
the cells in spreadsheets are contingent on human actions, so ignoring them can be fatal.
• Overall, these issues signal why the seeming speed and safety of M&A versus organic growth
can be illusory.
6.2.2 Conglomerates
• Aggressive M&A strategies can also lead to conglomerates or multi-divisional companies with
broadly diversified holdings with little shared between the holdings.
- The first is a cost-of-capital argument: by doing the diversifying acquisition, you will bring
your cost of capital to that target.
- For example, you have a 10% discount rate and the target company has a cost of capital
closer to 15% - meaning that it will get revalued higher upon acquisition because of your
10% cost of capital, creating value.
- However, this reasoning is flawed, as the correct cost of capital to use is a function of
that business, you can’t export your cost of capital.
- The second finance rationale for diversifying is to manage risk.
- By owning different types of companies in different industries, shareholders are thought
to benefit from diversification.
- The thinking equates acquisitions to stock portfolios: of one company goes south, then
the other companies in your portfolio will prop it up.
- This line of inquiry is faulty and ignores the fact that managers are undertaking diversi-
fication, while shareholders could arguably achieve that risk management themselves.
- The logic of finance is that you shouldn’t do something for your shareholders that they
can do for themselves and diversification at the corporate level is exactly that.
54
• Conglomerates appear to destroy value rather than create it. Hence, they often trade at a
discount, which means that their combined values is less than if the businesses were traded
separately.
• This is because capital allocation within a conglomerate is distorted by the pressure to treat
all divisions equally. In the process, capital is distributed equally rather than allocated toward
the best opportunities - weak divisions expand and promising divisions are starved.
• Dividends are more intuitive, a company simply pays cash to its shareholders on a pro-rata
basis.
• Dividends can be part of a predictable flow or they can be larger, one-off events (special
dividends).
• Meanwhile, a share buy-back is less intuitive, a company buys back its own shares in the open
market and retires them.
• As a result, investors who choose not to sell their shares will own a slightly larger fraction of
the company, and cash has been distributed.
• Share buybacks have become tremendously popular over the last decade as shown in Figure
6.2.
In terms of the raw mechanics, the choice between dividends and buybacks is irrelevant, but
each method potentially sends a different signal to the market, and that can matter. However, some
misconceptions of distributing cash include:
55
• Stock prices rise after buybacks because the remaining shareholders own more of the company
afterward.
• Dividends are bad for shareholders because their shares will be worth less.
To debunk these ideas and clarify the nature of the decision, we will show that whether a
company chooses to distribute cash shouldn’t matter.
The company in Figure 6.3 has a large amount of cash and is considering distributing some via
a dividend or buyback. Because this balance sheet is market-based, the equity values can easily
be translated to share prices and the value of operating assets are market values. If the company
distributed $70 of that cash as a dividend to shareholders the following will happen to the market
value balance sheet:
• Given that there are 100 shares outstanding, that’s a $0.70 per share dividend,
• The company’s cash holdings drop $70 from $100 to $30, but the value of the operating assets
remains the same.
• Because the debt remains the same, the equity value also has to drop $70 for the balance sheet
to balance.
• The price per share would fall from $1.40 per share to $0.70 per share.
• As a shareholder, you might seem to be taking a hit, but when you factor in the $0.70 in cash
you received, you’re left with $1.40.
• Shareholders are economically in the same position as they were before - it’s completely
value-neutral.
• They could return to where they began by buying one share with that $0.70 in cash, and they
would be left with $1.40 in shares, just as before.
Meanwhile, if the company distributes $70 of its cash by buying back $70 worth of shares:
56
• Again, its cash drops to $30, and the operating assets and debt remains the same.
• The equity value drops to $70. The $70 used to buy shares retired 50 shares, given the stock
price of $1.40.
• Now that the total equity value is $70, and there are now 50 shares outstanding, that provides
a $1.40 share price.
• The shareholders who sold to the company are left with $1.40 in cash, and the shareholders
who stayed have a share worth $1.40.
This example has an important core intuition - value doesn’t arise from taking cash from one
pocket and placing it in the other. Value arises from pursuing positive NPV projects. Hence, neither
keeping nor distributing cash results in changed value.
- For example, during a share buyback, investors have to sell their shares and incur a capital
gain that may be taxed at a lower rate, while a dividend can be taxed at higher rates.
- Hence, many people think that these tax consequences are one reason to prefer share
buybacks over dividends.
• Another critical element in the real world is the asymmetric information and incentives.
- All actions are judged by the information they are thought to reveal.
- If the people with all the information about the company are buying back shares, they must
think the firm is undervalued and are willing to put real money behind that sentiment.
- This decision is a very strong signal and helps explain why buybacks have become so
popular and are often greeted with a price rise.
- Price reactions to share buybacks are driven by that signaling interpretation, not by the
mechanics of dilution.
• Dividend initiations can sometimes be met with the opposite reaction, even though dividends
effectuate the same outcome as buybacks:
- Individuals with all the information about the company’s prospects are saying that they
can’t find good investments and they don’t think the company is undervalued.
- In effect, they don’t have anything better to do with your money, so they’re giving it back
to you - not the most positive signal.
- Since dividends are fairly sticky (once a company starts paying dividends, it’s hard to
stop), increasing dividends may mean the company has faith in the ongoing, increased
profitability of the enterprise.
57
- Furthermore, if the company is going to maintain that dividend, it also binds manage-
ment’s hands to some degree, which some investors think reduces the principal-agent
problem.
• Indeed, agency considerations are the other reason cash distribution decisions can have value
consequences:
- Managers can use cash inside companies to pursue their won agendas, which may not
coincide with shareholder interests.
- For example, as cash piles up, a CEO may be tempted by an acquisition that enhances
their position in the CEO labour market but actually destroys value.
- So getting cash out of the corporation can have value consequences, not because of the
mechanics of the distribution, but because it alleviates agency considerations.
- If the signaling argument was all to consider, we’d expect managers to time buybacks well
and to be buying at low points in the market.
- As seen in Figure 6.2, this does not seem to be happening in aggregate, as the last market
peak was also the peak for buybacks.
- So clearly some firms are doing buybacks well and some are doing it poorly.
- Adopting an agency perspective can help explain this phenomenon - share buybacks can
also be used to achieve various operating metrics.
- Let’s say a manager is a penny short on earnings per share (EPS) for a given quarter and
knows that he’ll be punished by the market for the error, possibly making him miss out
on a bonus.
- A share buyback can be done to reduce the number of shares outstanding and increase
EPS, but the short-run illusion of higher EPS is likely not in the best interests of share-
holders.
Overall, the mechanics of cash distribution often lead people to mistake arguments about value
consequences associated with dilution or share counts. The raw mechanics of buybacks and dividends
are all value-neutral. The reason these decisions attract so much attention is because they provide
information and address the principal-agent problem.
58
Figure 6.4: Post-financing, market-based balance sheet
Looking at the market-based balance sheet of the sample company as shown in Figure 6.4, we
can see how equity issuance works when the company decides to issue $70 more in equity:
• After the company issues $70 in equity, it will have $70 more in cash for a total of $170; its
operating assets and debt level are unchanged, so the market value of equity is now $210.
• To determine how much the shares are worth, we need to know how many shares are outstanding
after the issuance.
• Shares are selling at $1.40 each, so raising $70 would require the company to issue 50 shares
($70 ÷ $1.40 = 50).
• Shares must therefore be selling for $1.40 per share ($210 ÷ 150 = $1.40), just as before.
• Hence, issuing equity has not diminished the price of the company’ stock - it is exactly the
same - in line with the fact that value creation comes from the assets side of the balance sheet,
not from financing.
• With regards to dilution, shareholders may now have a smaller percentage share, but it is of a
larger pie.
Even so, when companies issue stock, the stock price often does declines, as when companies
are issuing shares, they are sellers of shares. This inevitably leads to questions about why they are
choosing to raise funds by selling shares as opposed to using debt or internally generated profits. In
short, equity issuance sends a negative signal.
• There are no changes to the market-based balance sheet because there have been no changes
in operations or to financing sources.
59
• However, each share is now worth $0.70, as there’s still $140 worth of equity, but now it’s split
over 200 shares ($140 ÷ 200 = $0.70).
• Investors haven’t lost value. Each investor used to have one share worth $1.40. Now they have
2 shares worth $0.70 each, for a total of $1.40.
• No value has been created or destroyed by this stock split.
Some companies split their stock in order to make their stock price more enticing to smaller
investors. However, some companies refuse to ever split their stock, as they think that stock splits
are meaningless and only encourage short-term interest in a stock through a seemingly cheaper price.
These kind of actions can remove frictions in some circumstances too:
• In 2011, Citigroup performed a reverse stock split: for every 10 shares of stock held, investors
received one share.
• Citigroup did this because its stock price had fallen to $4, and many institutional investors
have guidelines that prevent them from purchasing stock for less than $5.
• By performing the reverse stock split, Citigroup raised its price to $40 and was able to access
an important group of investors for its shares.
Stock splits do not create value per se but can have value consequences because of market imper-
fections, just like stock issuance.
• Debt will increase by $60 to $120, and cash will increase by $60 to $160.
• Then, cash will decrease by $100, because it is used to pay a dividend.
• Adding up the market value of the operating assets and remaining cash and subtracting debt,
we’re left with $40 of equity value.
• For the shareholders, 100 shares are now worth $0.40 per share ($40 ÷ 100 = $0.40), but
shareholders have also received a dividend of $100, split up across those shares ($100 ÷ 100 =
$1 each).
• That adds up to the same $1.40 per share the fund had before.
The mechanics of this transaction don’t necessarily yield value consequences, but there can be
value consequences because of other factors. Specifically, the equity is now substantially riskier (as
there is more debt that gets paid out before equity), and that should be associated with higher
expected returns and lower values.
60
6.4.4 Venture financing
As companies grow and require more funding, their founders find investors, called angel investors,
to provide funding. This process often happens more than once, and the different rounds of funding
are called Series A, Series B, and so on, and can also feature professional VC firms.
Instead of the previous sample company, imagine a brand-new enterprise. Before the first round
of external financing (Series A), its balance sheet is a little ambiguous. The founders own the equity,
and the founders’ ideas are the assets of the company. The founders have allocated a hundred shares
of company stock to themselves, but the company is still entirely private.
The company needs an additional $100 to invest in a positive NPV project and goes to a venture
capitalist for that funding. The venture capitalist offers the $100 for 20% of the company in return.
By making that offer, the venture capitalist has implicitly valued the company:
• If 20% of the company’s equity is worth $100, then 100% of the company’s equity must be
worth $500.
• The balance sheets have to balance, this $500 is the value of all assets as well.
• Since the company will have $100 in cash immediately after the financing, this means the
remaining asset (the business the founders have built so far) is worth $400.
• The $500 on the equity side is split between the founders (80%) and the venture capitalists
(20%), so the founders’ stake is worth $400 (80% × $500 = $400) and the venture capitalists’
stake is worth $100 (20% × $500 = $100).
• 25 shares are issued to the venture capitalists to represent their share of the equity for a total
of 125 shares (100 ÷ 80% = 125).
As Figure 6.7 shows, this round of funding implicitly values the business before the funding
(pre-money value) by valuing the business after the funding (the post-money value).
Let’s imagine that the company returns a few years later for a second round of financing (Series
B). The company doesn’t have any more cash on hand (cash balance is $0), and it’s asking for $1,000
in investment. The Series B investors ask for 50% of the company in return for the $1,000 investment
(Figure 6.7), resulting in the following changes to the balance sheet:
• After the investment, there will be $1,000 in cash and the existing business.
• If the $1,000 represents 50% of the company, then all of the equity is now worth $2,000.
• This implies that the enterprise is now worth $1,000 ($2,000 total asset value - $1,000 cash).
61
• The founders have 100 shares and the Series A investors have 25 shares.
• These 125 shares are worth $1,000 or $8 per share ($1,000 ÷ 125 = $8).
• The founders’ shares are now worth $800 ($8 × 100 = $800) and the Series A investors’ shares
are now worth $200 ($8 × 25 = $200).
• 125 shares are issued to Series B investors to represent their 50% ownership that is worth
$1,000.
• The founders have gone from owning 100% of the company and holding stock worth an unknown
amount to owning 80% (post-Series A) and holding stock worth $4 per share ($400), to owning
40% of the company (post-Series B) and holding stock worth $8 per share ($800).
• With each round of financing, their equity is diluted, but their stakes grow in value because
the pie is growing larger as well.
6.4.5 Summary
The process of share issuance is particularly fraught in the case of new ventures because those
financings actually involve telling a founder what they are worth. But the mechanics of equity
financings do not give rise to value consequences. Similarly, distributions per se don’t change value,
but distributions that change the riskiness of shares, like leveraged recapitalization, can have an
impact on value because they change risk, expected returns, and prices.
• There have been significant tax penalties to US companies for paying out cash if that cash is
held abroad (these penalties were lessened by Congress at the end of 2017).
• It’s possible that companies are just waiting to find the right investment.
• Not making capital allocation decisions results in rising cash levels on corporate balance
sheets.
• These rising cash levels typically frustrate shareholders as they questions why managers
are unable to deploy capital.
• Moreover, cash on balance sheets can attract the attention of activist investors who can
use that cash as financing to take that company private.
62
• Managers sometimes justify share buybacks by claiming that they create value for share-
holders by buying shares cheaply.
• In fact, value can’t be created through share buybacks.
• At best, share buybacks transfer value across shareholders, depending on the buyback
prices for shares.
• Managers can only create value by investing in positive NPV projects.
3. Preferring acquisitions over organic investment because acquisitions are faster and
safer
• Acquisitions appear to be faster and safer but can actually prove to be the opposite.
• Because of the informational problems between sellers and buyers, it can be risky to
acquire companies, and the integration issues associated with acquisitions can offset any
purported gains.
4. Preferring buybacks over dividends because buybacks are discretionary while div-
idends are not
• Size, rather than value creation, can quickly become an objective of managers as it’s more
fun to run a larger business.
• Building empires can become a major objective for managers that can contradict their
mandate to be good stewards of capitals.
• Overlooking positive NPV projects is as problematic as pursuing size over value creation.
• Short-term earnings goals and pressure from shareholders who care only about these short-
term earnings metrics can cause a manager to overlook good investments.
63