Aviral Kumar Tiwari, Mihai Mutascu - 2011 - Economic Growth and FDI in Asia - A Panel-Data Approach
Aviral Kumar Tiwari, Mihai Mutascu - 2011 - Economic Growth and FDI in Asia - A Panel-Data Approach
2, september 2011
and
Mihai Mutascu2
LEO (Laboratoire d'Economie d'Orléans) UMR6221,
Faculté de Droit d'Economie et de Gestion, University of Orléans,
Rue de Blois – B.P. 6739, 45067, Orléans,
France
(Email: [email protected])
Abstract: This study examines the impact of foreign direct investment on economic growth in Asian
countries. We did our analysis in the panel framework for the period 1986 to 2008. We
also examined the nonlinearities associated with foreign direct investment and exports in
the economic growth process of Asian countries under consideration. We find that both
foreign direct investment and exports enhance the growth process. In addition, labour
and capital also play an important role in the growth of Asian countries. We suggest an
export-led growth path particularly at the initial stage of growth and in the later period,
dependence on FDI might be a feasible option.
I. Introduction
Economists, researchers and policy analysts have given considerable attention to the relationship
between economic growth and foreign direct investment (FDI), especially in developing
countries. It is a widely accepted argument that openness of an economy boosts economic
1 We thank our colleagues, Loretti Isabella Dobrescu (University of New South Wales), Claudiu Albulescu
(Research Centre on Economic and Financial Integration, Université de Poitiers) and Domenico Consoli
(University of Urbino), for their thoughtful comments and suggestions. Other thanks go to Miriam Hatoum
(Boston University). We would also like to thank the anonymous referee for his/her constructive suggestions
for improving the paper. All remaining errors are ours.
2 Corresponding author: ([email protected])
173
Economic Growth and FDI in Asia: A Panel-Data Approach
174
Aviral Kumar Tiwari and Mihai Mutascu
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section II contains the literature review.
Section III presents methodology, variables’ description and data. Section IV shows estimation
and empirical results. Section V concludes.
II. Literature
Kaldor (1963) documented mechanisms that explain economic growth. Examples of these
mechanisms are the growth in per-capita output and per-capita physical capital over time,
constant ratio of physical capital to output over time, the constant rate of return to capital,
constant share of labour and physical capital in national income, and the substantial difference
in the growth rate of output per worker across countries. Similarly, Anwara and Nguyen (2010)
identify several determinants of the link between FDI and economic growth. Some of these
determinants are, for example, human capital, learning by doing, exports, macroeconomic
stability, and level of financial development, public investment. These are in addition to those
that Shahbaz and Rehman (2010) identified as determinants of economic growth, including
foreign direct investment. They also reported that foreign direct investment, financial
development, public investment, human capital, trade openness and inflation have positive
effects on economic growth. Neuhause (2006), based on these determinants, shows that there
are three main channels through which FDI can influence the technological change, improve
the capital stocks and generate economic growth: (a) direct transmission (through “Greenfield
Investments”), (b) indirect transmission (through “Ownership Participation”), and (c) second-
round transmission (through “Technology Spillover”).
Recently, the number and quality of the analyses regarding the relationship between the
economic growth and FDI are prolific. In research focusing on China, Dees (1998) finds that
the FDI affects Chinese growth through the diffusion of ideas. FDI presents a significant
positive effect on Chinese long-term growth through its influence on technical change (this
is significant only in the 1990s).
The same potential positive effect of FDI on growth, in China’s case, was illustrated by
Berthélemy and Démurger (2000). In a Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) approach,
the authors provide new evidence on the role of human capital in Chinese provincial growth,
and stress that human capital may contribute to growth by facilitating the adoption of foreign
technologies. Moreover, the study shows that the direct impact of export growth disappears
when both exports and foreign investment are introduced in the growth regression.
Using co-integration and an error-correction model to examine the link between FDI and
economic growth in India, Chakraborty and Basu (2002) suggest that GDP in India is not
caused by FDI, and the causality runs more from GDP to FDI. In the same context, Alfaro
(2003) has made a sectoral panel OLS analysis, using cross-country data for the 1981-1999
period. The main results allow us to conclude that FDI in the primary sector tends to have a
negative effect on growth, while investment in manufacturing has a positive one.
In Thailand’s case, using data from 1970 to 1999, and the vector error correction approach,
Kohpaiboon (2003) has introduced the export variable in the growth-FDI equation. He finds a
unidirectional causality from FDI to GDP and shows that the impact of growth on FDI tends
to be greater under an export-promotion (EP) trade regime compared to an import-substitution
175
Economic Growth and FDI in Asia: A Panel-Data Approach
(IS) regime. Balamurali and Bogahawatte (2004) also found the same results for Sri-Lanka.
They emphasize that trade policy reforms (promotion of FDI and domestic investment) and
restoring international competitiveness to expand and diversify the country’s exports, have
the potential of accelerating economic growth in the future.
In a vector autoregressive model, using seasonally adjusted quarterly data of Mexico,
Brazil, and Argentina, from late 1970 to 2000, Cuadros et al. (2004) illustrate the same
unidirectional causalities from real FDI and real exports to real GDP in Mexico and Argentina,
and unidirectional causality from real GDP to real exports in Brazil. Cho (2005) has applied
the panel-data causality for nine East and Southeast Asian economies (plus Indonesia), from
1970 to 2001. The results stress a strong unidirectional causality from FDI to exports among
the three variables.
Hsiao and Hsiao (2006) set up a panel vector autoregressive model in the case of China,
Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, Singapore, Malaysia, Philippines, and Thailand. Their results
reveal that FDI has unidirectional effects on GDP directly and also indirectly through exports,
and there exists bidirectional causality between exports and GDP for the group. Baharumshah
and Thanoon (2006), by using dynamic-panel models, demonstrated the positive contribution
of FDI on the growth process of East Asian economies. In other words, the countries that are
successful in attracting FDI can finance more investments and grow faster than those that
deter FDI.
Alfaro et al. (2006), using an extended dataset, found that the same amount of increase
in FDI, regardless of the reason of the increase, generates three times more additional growth
in financially well-developed countries than in financially poorly-developed countries. In the
case of East European countries, similar results were found by Bhandari et al. (2007), based
on a panel-GLS model. The conclusions are that an increase in the stock of domestic capital
and inflow of FDI are main factors that positively affect economic growth.
Won et al. (2008) have analyzed the case of newly industrialized Asian economies by
using panel-vector autoregressive models and show that the openness of the economy is, as
manifested by exports and inward FDI, among others, the most important economic factor
attributed to the rapid growth of these economies. Shahbaz et al. (2008) use Pakistani data after
the SAP (structural adjustment program) to fix the main determinants of economic growth.
The ARDL-bounds testing approach to cointegration was applied to investigate long- term
relationships. The empirical evidence confirms the existence of cointegration i.e., long- term
relationships exist between the variables. The impact of foreign direct investment, financial
development, remittances and public investment is positive on economic growth, while trade
openness and inflation slow the pace of economic growth. Moreover, in the case of Gulf
Cooperation Council (GCC) countries,3 the OLS panel approach of Faras and Ghali (2009)
stress that, for most of the GCC countries, there is a weak but statistically significant causal
impact of FDI inflows on economic growth.
Karimi and Yusop (2009), based on a simple OLS regression, studied Malaysia’s “growth-
FDI” link. According to them, there is a range of possible factors that ensures that FDI promotes
or hinders economic growth. At the same time, these determinants are likely to differ between
3 Gulf Cooperation Council is a political and economic alliance of six Middle Eastern countries: Saudi Arabia,
Kuwait, the United Arab Emirates, Qatar, Bahrain, and Oman.
176
Aviral Kumar Tiwari and Mihai Mutascu
countries and between types of FDI and sectors of destination. The GMM estimation of Anwara
and Nguyen (2010), who focused on the Vietnamese “growth-FDI” connection, showed the
importance of the role of education and training. The results suggest that the impact of FDI
on economic growth in Vietnam will be larger if more resources are invested in education and
training, and financial market development, and also invested in reducing the technology gap
between foreign and local firms.
Similar conclusions were reached by Jayachandran and Seilan (2010) in the case of India,
concluding that FDI and exports are among the factors affecting economic growth. However,
the reciprocal does not apply. The high or low economic growth rate does not have an effect
on the presence of FDI and exports in India. Further, Wijeweera et al. (2010) argued that FDI
inflows exert a positive impact on economic growth, however, only in the presence of highly
skilled labour. Moreover, they found that corruption has a negative impact on economic growth,
and trade openness increases economic growth by means of efficiency gains.
We observe that several studies have focused on the case of developing countries and
for the major part, stress that FDI, adjusted to other determinants, has a significant positive
effect on economic growth. However, none of these studies has analyzed the nonlinearities
associated with FDI that affect the economic growth process of the host country. Therefore,
we have moved ahead in this direction and have also provided the case of export-led growth
or FDI led-growth.
where Y denotes the output level (i.e., GDP per capita), K denotes the amount of capital (which
is measured by Gross Capital Formation (GCF) as percentage of GDP), and L denotes the
amount of labour (measured by labour force of the country). Assuming constant technology,
any increase in the amount of labour and/or capital will increase the level of output in the
economy. This production function is expanded according to the new growth theory by following
Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995).4
To this respect, Mankiw (2004) states that international trade affects economic growth
and can indeed be regarded as a type of technology in that it converts non-specialized
4 There are several channels for promoting economic growth such as encouraging domestic saving and investment,
foreign investment, education, R&D and free trade.
177
Economic Growth and FDI in Asia: A Panel-Data Approach
production into specialized production. Hence, according to the new growth theory, export
expansion improves economy-wide efficiency in the allocation of inputs, and leads to total
factor productivity growth. From a demand-side point of view, an inward-oriented policy is
not sustainable since domestic demand is limited and domestic resources may remain idle and
hence, domestic economic growth cannot be enhanced.
Agosin (1999) and Boriss and Herzer (2006) illustrate that, in an outward-oriented country
with free trade, exports are the engine of growth through the expansion of external demand, as
a component of the aggregate demand function. On the supply-side, Grossman and Helpman
(1991) demonstrate that exports can positively contribute to economic growth through different
means, such as facilitating the exploitation of economies of scale, or promoting the diffusion
of technical knowledge.
Therefore, production function can be expanded by adding exports (denoted by X) as
an extra variable. Additionally, Ögütçü (2002) argues that FDI is a major catalyst for the
development and the integration of developing countries in the global economy. According
to Chen (1992), the positive developmental role of FDI, in general, is well documented. FDI
produces a positive effect on economic growth in host countries.
One convincing argument for that is that FDI consists of a package of capital, technology
management, and market access. FDI tends to be directed at those manufacturing sectors and
key infrastructures that enjoy actual and potential comparative advantage. In those sectors with
comparative advantage, FDI would create economies of scale and linkage effects, and raise
productivity. For FDI, repayment is required only if investors make a profit and when they
make profit, they tend to reinvest their profit rather than remit abroad. Another benefit of FDI
is a confidence-building effect. While the local economic environment determines the overall
degree of investment confidence in a country, inflows of FDI could reinforce the confidence,
contributing to the creation of a robust cycle that affects not only local and foreign investment
but also foreign trade and production.
Based on the results of Blömstrom et al. (2000), the experience of many countries suggests
that a significant quantity of FDI alone is not sufficient to generate economic growth and bring
economic prosperity to a host country.
Therefore, we have also added FDI in the production function to analyse its impact on
economic growth. The augmented production function can be written as follows:
The most commonly used ways of assessing the relationship between economic growth and
its determinants as mentioned in equation (2), is the static panel data models. In this study,
based on the result of Dielman (1989), we have preferred the panel-data analysis technique as
it has an advantage of containing the information necessary to deal with both the intertemporal
dynamics and the individuality of the entities being investigated.
There are basically three types of panel-data models namely, a pooled Ordinary Least
Squire (OLS) regression, panel model with random effects and panel model with fixed effects.5
5 We accessed data of FDI from UNCTAD (www.unctad.org), GDP per capita from Historical Statistics of
the World Economy: 1-2008, AD from Angus Maddison and other variables from World Bank Development
Indicators data base of World Bank. Study period is 1986 to 2008.
178
Aviral Kumar Tiwari and Mihai Mutascu
Considering the extended production function of equation (2), the evaluation of a pooled OLS
regression can be specified as follows:
where i denotes country, t denotes time and remainder εit is the error term which is assumed to
be white noised and varies over both country and time. However, while using a pooled OLS
regression, countries’ unobservable individual effects are therefore not controlled. According
to Bevan and Danbolt (2004), heterogeneity of the countries under consideration for analysis
can influence measurements of the estimated parameters.
Further, using a panel-data model with incorporation of individual effects, has a number
of benefits, for example, among others, it allows us to account for individual heterogeneity.
Indeed, Serrasqueiro and Nunes (2008) and Tiwari and Kalita (2011) mentioned that developing
countries differ in terms of their colonial history, their political regimes, their ideologies and
religious affiliations, their geographical locations and climatic conditions, not to mention a
wide range of other country-specific variables. And, if this heterogeneity is not taken into
account, it will inevitably bias the results, no matter how large the sample is.
Therefore, by incorporating countries’ unobservable individual effects in equation (3) the
model to be estimated is as follows:
where wit = μi + Eit with μi being countries’ unobservable individual effects. The difference
between a polled OLS regression and a model considering unobservable individual effects,
lies precisely in μi. When we consider the random-effect model, equation (4) will be same.
However, in that case, μi is presumed have the property of zero mean, independent of individual
observation error term εit, has constant variances σ ε2 , and is independent of the explanatory
variables.
However, there may be a correlation between countries’ unobservable individual effects
and growth determinants. If there is no correlation between countries’ unobservable individual
effects and growth determinants, the most appropriate way of carrying out the analysis is using
a panel model of random effects. On the contrary, if there is a correlation between countries’
individual effects and growth determinants, the most appropriate way of carrying out the
analysis is to use a panel model of fixed effects.
To test for the possible existence of a correlation we use the Hausman test. This test tests
the null hypothesis of non-existence of a correlation between unobservable individual effects
and the growth determinants, against the alternative hypothesis of an existence of a correlation.
If the null hypothesis is not rejected we can conclude that correlation is not relevant and
therefore a panel model of random effects is the most correct way of carrying out the analysis
of the relationship between economic growth and its determinants. On the contrary, if the
null hypothesis is rejected, we can conclude that correlation is relevant and therefore a panel
model of fixed effects is the most appropriate way to carry out the analysis of the relationship
between economic growth and its determinants.
Further, unlike previous studies which have analyzed the impact of FDI and exports on
179
Economic Growth and FDI in Asia: A Panel-Data Approach
economic growth by using only the one-way error component model (i.e., either fixed effect
or random effect is present in the model), we have analyzed the model in which two-way error
components are present. Therefore, by expanding equation (4) to incorporate the two-way
error component model, the equation becomes as follows:
where µit = wit + λt = µi + λt + εit , µi denotes the unobservable individual effect, λt denotes
the unobservable time effect, and εit is the remainder stochastic disturbance term. Note that
λt is individual-invariant and it accounts for any time-specific effect that is not included in
the regression. For example, it could account for strike-year effects that disrupt production;
oil-embargo effects that disrupt the supply of oil and affect its price; Surgeon General reports
on the ill-effects of smoking; or government laws restricting smoking in public places, all of
which could affect consumption behaviour. If µi and λt are assumed to be fixed parameters to
be estimated, and the reminder disturbance is stochastic with εit IID (0,σ ε2 ) , then equation
(4) represents a two-way fixed effect error component model.6
Similarly, nonlinearity of exports-growth relationship has also been incorporated in the
model.
180
Table 1: Regression Results of First Specification
Panel data Models: Dependent variable GDP per capita
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 6 Model 7
Independent
variables Two way RE
FE RE FE RE RE-CS: PR-FE Two way RE RE with AR(1)
And CSW
80.00*** 77.47*** 72.16** 68.99** -78.00** 69.9975** 69.99745** 19.66703
FDI
(17.1451) (17.1151) (32.151) (32.053) (32.1017) (32.52973) (31.24509) (15.61716)
-99.14*** -95.84*** -67.46** -96.24*** -96.24*** -24.304***
D(FDI) ------- -------
(22.1377) (22.098) (20.5664) (22.4216) (23.689) (7.981435)
3.224** 3.054** 6.78*** 3.05321** 3.053212* 0.7767105*
FDI*FDI ------- -------
(1.368299) (1.36211) (1.2951) (1.382451) (1.641654) (0.4305877)
-3.642*** -3.389*** -3.564*** -3.4122*** -3.412199** -0.5623656
D(FDI)*D(FDI) ----------- ----------
(1.242249) (1.23551) (1.14377) (1.254283) (1.367031) (.4014784)
77.50*** 81.19*** 72.33*** 78.31*** 46.72*** 77.556*** 77.556*** 30.17081***
X
(5.2153) (5.011174) (5.469286) (5.1424) (5.5688) (5.265174) (5.553573) (4.601944)
1.11E-05*** 4.99E-06* 1.29E-05*** 3.91E-06 -2.91E-06 4.79E-06* 4.79E-06** 9.33e-07
LF
(3.81e-06) (2.91E-06) (3.93E-06) (2.67E-06) (2.65E-06) (2.86E-06) (1.88E-06) (4.12e-06)
-14.67502 -11.18523 -13.44261 -7.883985 -27.019** -8.603529 -8.603529 30.3044***
GCF
(11.305) (11.22578) (11.21285) (11.091) (10.783) (11.26808) (11.02927) (6.656886)
2319.127 2448.03*** 2408.4*** 2563.42 5156.41*** 2558.9*** 2558.9*** 4381.65***
Constant
(374.131) (783.7958) (385.7225) (672.788) (408.3752) (739.8539) (701.871) (857.6249)
Model summary
R2 0.939031 0.430405 0.946816 0.458357 0.573270 0.458075 0.458075 0.5024
Wald chi2 395.96*** 74.61***
F-test 297.37*** 98.988*** 292.21*** 60.20*** 22.89*** 60.14*** 60.14***
Hausman test 10.165** 13.35**
Fixed effect F(22, 502) = F(22, 476) =
(F-test) 141.00*** 141.74***
Countries
Aviral Kumar Tiwari and Mihai Mutascu
23 23 23 23 23 23 23 23
included
Total panel
529 529 529 529 529 529 529 529
observations
Notes:
1. The Hausman test has χ2 distribution and tests the null hypothesis that unobservable individual effects are not correlated with the explanatory variables, against the null
hypothesis of correlation between unobservable individual effects and the explanatory variables.
2. The Wald test has χ2 distribution and tests the null hypothesis of insignificance as a whole of the parameters of the explanatory variables, against the alternative hypothesis
of significance as a whole of the parameters of the explanatory variables.
3. The F-test has normal distribution N(0,1) and tests the null hypothesis of insignificance as a whole of the estimated parameters, against the alternative hypothesis of
significance as a whole of the estimated parameters.
4. ***, **, and *denote significance at 1, 5 and 10 % level of significance, respectively.
5. EF, CS, SD denotes fixed-effect, cross-section and standard deviation, respectively.
6. [----] denotes results are not computed.
7. @ denotes that model is estimated with Panel EGLS (Cross-section SUR) method.
181
Source: Author’s calculation
Economic Growth and FDI in Asia: A Panel-Data Approach
case also suggests that the random-effect model is the preferred way of analysis. So, from the
results of model 4, we can say that FDI and its higher inflow in the group of panel countries,
contribute to higher growth.
In addition, we have analysed another model in which random effect is present but we
have fixed period-specific effects, and results are reported under model 5. Model 5 reports
that exports and high level of FDI will increase the growth, otherwise FDI decreases growth
of the panel countries.
We also analyze the random-effect model by assuming the period-specific effect which
is also random (we call it the two-way random-effect model) and we report the results under
model 6. We find that in this case FDI, square of FDI, exports and labour force, are all found to
have positive impact on the economic growth in the panel of countries. Further, by providing
cross-section weights in the two-way random-effect model we find that results reported by
model 5 are robust to the inclusion of cross-section weights.
In the final step, in model 7, we used a random-effect model with the presence of a first-
order autoregressive scheme. The results of model 7 reveal that higher inflows of FDI, exports,
and capital have positive and significant effect on the economic growth of our panel countries.
Further, we have proceeded to analyse the nonlinear impact of exports in the panel countries.
Results of nonlinear impact analysis of exports are presented in Table 2.
In Table 2, the results of the Hausman test show that the random-effect model is an
appropriate test for the analysis. The results of this model are reported under model 2. It is
evident from model 2 that FDI, exports, squared exports and labour force have positive and
significant impact on the economic growth of the panel countries. It also implies that when we
analyse the nonlinearity in both cases i.e., exports and FDI, we find a significant and positive
impact of exports only on the economic growth of panel countries. This also suggests the
preference of the export-led growth hypothesis against the FDI-led growth hypothesis (a long
debated topic) in our panel countries.7
Further, we have analyzed a model of random effect in which the period-specific effect is
assumed fixed and results are reported under model 3. We find very surprising results from
model 3. In this case, exports and FDI are significant with a negative coefficient, while the
coefficients of the square of exports and FDI are significant with a positive sign. Further, if
we compare the coefficient of exports and FDI, we find that the negative impact of FDI is
much higher with respect to the negative impact of exports. Similarly, the positive impact of
the square of FDI is also much higher vis-à-vis the positive impact of the square of exports.
In the final step, we have analysed a model of two-way random effect and results are
reported under model 4. The two-way random-effect model confirms the findings of the one-
way random-effect model, model 2; i.e., FDI, exports, squared exports and labour force have
positive and significant impact on the economic growth of the panel countries.
7 It is important to mention here that our findings are subject to the inability to isolate the effects of FDI and
exports on GDP of Asian countries. As such, there is a possibility that FDI inflow might bring new and
advanced technologies which might, in turn, generate the momentum of exports, and hence, enhance the
growth process. However, we have been able to provide a feel for this kind of situation. Further, we offer a
new area of research to advanced econometricians, to develop a model wherein the isolated impact of FDI,
exports and imports, can be assessed in a general equilibrium framework. As in any economy, these variables
are very interrelated, and to isolate their interaction calls for more advanced research.
182
Aviral Kumar Tiwari and Mihai Mutascu
183
Economic Growth and FDI in Asia: A Panel-Data Approach
V. Conclusions
There has been a long debate among policy makers and economists at the national and
international levels about whether FDI enhances growth in the host countries. Further, we
also analysed whether dependence on export-led growth or FDI lead-growth is preferable and
what is the evidence of nonlinearities associated with FDI and exports in economic growth.
In this study, we have attempted to answer these questions. We conducted an empirical
analysis in the framework of a panel for 23 Asian countries by employing data from 1986
to 2008. We also incorporated a two-way effect model for the analysis, as the assumptions
of fixed and random effects across countries and over time are extremely plausible. We also
examined nonlinearities associated with exports and FDI in the economic growth of Asian
countries. Further, as we have studied a large sample of Asian countries, we tried to minimise
the country-specific heterogeneity by imposing two-way dummies, i.e., in case of two-way
fixed- and random-effect models by using time-country dummies. We have also checked the
robustness of our results by analysing different models. However, by imposing dummies of
cultural aspects and religion we might have gotten more robust results, and an extended study
in this area should incorporate these issues. There are studies which have found that cultural
and religion aspects of a country have considerable impact on the economic growth on the
respective countries (see, for example, Dieckmann 1996, Griffin 1999, Casson and Godley
2000, Marini 2004, Grier 1997, Blum and Dudley 2001 and Barro and McCleary 2003).
The results of our analysis show that FDI and exports enhance the growth of Asian countries
and also that labour and capital help in that process. This implies that Asian countries that are
moving ahead for globalization might choose to go ahead. However, when we analyzed the
case of nonlinearity associated only with FDI, we find that this variable enhances growth. On
the other hand, the investigation of the nonlinearity in both cases, i.e., exports and FDI, show
a significant and positive impact of exports only on the economic growth of panel countries.
This suggests that to achieve a higher and higher growth path, moving ahead with exports
is more feasible in Asian countries. This is true, particularly for countries that do not have
sufficient resources to bring more advanced technology to private homes. The more advanced
technology would create an attractive environment for FDI, but would also require an extensive
investment for large improvements in the country’s infrastructure.
Further, there are studies that have found that FDI has a negative impact on economic
growth and income distribution. Hence, we suggest an export-led growth path, particularly at
the initial stage of growth, in the later period, dependence on FDI might be feasible option.
This finding can be defended based on two arguments (see Afzal 2010). First, the exports-
promotion incentives determine a specialization of the economy accompanied by the scale
benefices. Second, the augmented exports may stimulate the country to import high-value
inputs, products and technologies. By consequence, these elements may have a positive impact
on the productive capacity of the economy.
184
Aviral Kumar Tiwari and Mihai Mutascu
References
Agosin, M. (1999). Trade and Growth in Chile, Cepal Review. 68: 79-100.
Alfaro, L., A. Chanda, S. Kalemli-Ozcan, and S. Sayek (2006). How Does Foreign Direct Investment
Promote Economic Growth? Exploring the Effects of Financial Markets on Linkages, Harvard
Business School.
Alfaro, L. (2003). Foreign Direct Investment and Growth: Does the Sector Matter?, Harvard University,
Harvard Business School.
Anwara, S. and L. Nguyen (2010). Foreign direct investment and economic growth in Vietnam, Asia
Pacific Business Review. 16: 183–202.
Baharumshah, A. and M. Thanoon (2006). Foreign capital flows and economic growth in East Asian
countries, China Economic Review. 17: 70-83.
Balamurali, N. and C. Bogahawatte (2004). Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Sri
Lanka, Sri Lankan Journal of Agricultural Economics. 6: 37-50.
Barro, R. (1990). Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth, Journal of Political
Economy. 98, 103-125.
Barro, R.J. and X. Sala-i-Martin (1995). Economic Growth. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Barro, R.J. and X. Sala-i-Martin (1995). Technological Diffusion, Convergence and Growth, NBER
Working Paper Series, No. 5151.
Barro, R.J. and R.M. McCleary (2003). Religion and Economic Growth Across Countries. American
Sociological Review. 68: 760-781.
Bashir, A.H. (1999). Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries:
Theory and Evidence, Prepared for the MEEA Annual Meeting in Conjunction with the ASSA,
January 3-5, New York.
Berthélemy, J.C. and S. Démurger (2000). Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth: Theory
and Application to China, Review of Development Economics. 4: 140-155.
Bevan, A. and J. Danbolt (2004). Testing for Inconsistencies in the Estimation of UK Capital Structure
Determinants, Applied Financial Economics. 14: 55-66.
Bhandari, R., D. Dhakal, G. Pradhan, and K. Upadhyaya (2007). Foreign Aid, FDI and Economic
Growth in East European Countries, Economics Bulletin. 6: 1-9.
Blömstrom, M., S. Globerman, and A. Kokko (2000). The Determinants of Host Country Spillovers
form Foreign Direct Investment, CEPR Discussion Paper 2350, Washington D.C.
Boriss, S. and D. Herzer (2006). Export-Led Growth hypothesis: Evidence for Chile, Applied Economics
Letters. 13: 319-324.
Blum, U. and L. Dudley (2001). Religion and Economic Growth: Was Weber Right? Centre
Interuniversitaire de Recherche en économie Quantitative (CIREQ), No. 05-2001.
Casson, M. and A. Godley (2000), Cultural Factors in Economic Growth. Series: Studies in Economic
Ethics and Philosophy. Berlin and Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag.
Chakraborty, C. and P. Basu (2002). Foreign direct investment and growth in India: A cointegration
approach, Applied Economics. 34: 1061–1073.
Chen, E.K.Y. (1992). Changing Pattern of Financial Flows in the Asia-Pacific Region and Policy Re
sponses, Asian Development Review. 10:46-85.
Cho, K. (2005). Studies on Knowledge Spillovers, Trade, and Foreign Direct Investment – Theory and
Empirics, Ph.D. thesis, Boulder, CO: Department of Economics, University of Colorado at Boulder.
Cuadros, A., V. Orts, and M. Alguacil (2004). Openness and Growth: Re-Examining Foreign Direct
Investment, Trade and Output Linkages in Latin America, The Journal of Development Studies.
40: 167-192.
Dees, S. (1998). Foreign Direct Investment in China: Determinants and Effects, Economics of Planning.
31: 175-194.
Dieckmann, O. (1996). Cultural determinants of economic growth: Theory and evidence. Journal of
Cultural Economics. 20: 297-320.
185
Economic Growth and FDI in Asia: A Panel-Data Approach
Dielman, T. E. (1989). Pooled Cross-Sectional and Time Series Data Analysis. New York: Marcel Dekker.
Faras, R. and K. Ghali (2009). Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth: The Case of the GCC
Countries, International Research Journal of Finance and Economics, 29: 134-145.
Grier, R. (1997). The Effect of Religion on Economic Development: A Cross National Study of 63
Former Colonies, Kyklos. 50: 47-62.
Griffin, K. (1999). Culture and Economic Growth: A General Argument with Illustrations from the
Islamic World, Journal of Islamic Studies. 10: 126-141.
Grossman, G.M. and E. Helpman (1991). Innovation and growth in the global economy. Cambridge:
MIT Press.
Hsiao, F. and M.C. Hsiao (2006). FDI, exports, and GDP in East and Southeast Asia – Panel data versus
time-series causality analyses, Journal of Asian Economics. 17: 1082-1106.
Jayachandran, G. and A. Seilan (2010). A Causal Relationship between Trade, Foreign Direct Investment
and Economic Growth for India, International Research Journal of Finance and Economics. 42:
74-88.
Kaldor, M. (1963). Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth, in Proceedings of a Conference Held
by the International Economics Association, in: Friedrich A. Lutz and Douglas C. Hague (eds.),
Theory of Capital. London: Macmillan.
Karimi, M. and Z. Yusop (2009). FDI and Economic Growth in Malaysia, MPRA Paper No. 14999.
Kohpaiboon, A. (2003). Foreign Trade Regime and FDI – Growth Nexus: A Case Study of Thailand.
Journal of Development Studies. 40: 55-69.
Lucas, R. (1988). On the Mechanics of Economic Development, Journal of Monetary Economics. 22:
3-42.
Mankiw, N. G. (2004). Principles of economics. Mason, USA: Thomson, South-Western.
Marini, M. (2004). Cultural evolution and economic growth: a theoretical hypothesis with some empirical
evidence, The Journal of Socio-Economics. 33: 765-784.
Neuhause, M. (2006). The impact of FDI on economic growth: an analysis for the transition countries
of Central and Eastern Europe. Heidelberg: Physica Verlag.
Ögütçü, M. (2002). Foreign Direct Investment and Regional Development: Sharing experiences from
Brazil, China, Russia and Turkey, OECD Paper, Paris.
Romer, P. (1986a). Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth, Journal of Political Economy. 94:
1002–1037.
Schutz, E. (2001). Encyclopedia of Political Economy, Edited by Phillip O’Hara, Volume 1, A-K. New
York: Routledge: 241.
Serrasqueiro, Z. and P.M. Nunes (2008). Determinants of Capital Structure: Comparison of Empirical
Evidence from the Use of Different Estimators, International Journal of Applied Economics. 5: 14-29.
Shahbaz, M. and M.M. Rehman (2010). Foreign Capital Inflows-Growth Nexus and Role of Domestic
Financial Sector: An ARDL Cointegration Approach for Pakistan, Journal of Economic Research.
35: 207-231.
Shahbaz, M., K. Ahmad, and A.R. Chaudhary (2008). Economic Growth and Its Determinants in
Pakistan, The Pakistan Development Review. 47: 471-486
Solow, R. (1956). A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth, The Quarterly Journal of
Economics. 70: 65-94.
Swan, T. (1956). Economic Growth and Capital Accumulation, Economic Record. 32: 334–361.
Tiwari, A.K. (2010a). Globalization and Wage Inequality: A Revisit of Empirical Evidences with New
Approach, Journal of Asian Business Management. 2: 173-187.
Tiwari, A.K. (2010b). Liberalization and Wage Inequality: Evidence from Indian Manufacturing Sector:
A Review of Literature, Asian Economic Review (forthcoming).
Tiwari, A.K. and M. Aruna (2011). Is direction of trade is responsible for wage inequality in India? An
empirical verification, Indian Journal of Economics and Business. 10: 73-91.
Tiwari, A.K. and M. Kalita (2011). Governance and Foreign Aid in ASIAN Countries, Economics
Bulletin. 31: 453-465.
186
Aviral Kumar Tiwari and Mihai Mutascu
Wijeweera, A., R. Villano, and B. Dollery (2010). Economic Growth and FDI Inflows: A Stochastic
Frontier Analysis, The Journal of Developing Areas. 43: 143-158.
Won, Y., F. Hsiao, and D. Yang (2008). FDI Inflows, Exports and Economic Growth in First and Second
Generation ANIEs: Panel Data Causality Analyses, KIEP Working Paper, 08-02: 11-86.
Appendix
List of Analysed Countries
No. Country No. Country
1 Bahrain 13 Oman
2 Bangladesh 14 Pakistan
3 China 15 Philippines
4 China HK 16 Qatar
5 India 17 Saudi Arabia
6 Iran 18 Sri Lanka
7 Jordan 19 Syria
8 Korea Republic 20 Thailand
9 Kuwait 21 Turkey
10 Lebanon 22 United Arab Emirates
11 Malaysia 23 Vietnam
12 Myanmar
187