Causes of Financial Distress Following Leveraged Recapitalizations - 1995
Causes of Financial Distress Following Leveraged Recapitalizations - 1995
Fhanclal
ELSEYIER Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 129-157
ECONOMICS
Abstract
1. Introduction
We are grateful for helpful comments received from Ben Branch, Leroy Brooks, Dave Brown, Rob
Hansen, Scott Harrington, Michael Jensen, Greg Kadlec, Wayne Mikkelson (the editor), Greg
Niehaus, Tim Opler, Meir Schneller, Vijay Singal, Michael Vetsuypens (the referee), Ralph Walkling,
and Marc Zenner. The paper has also benefited from presentations at the University of Florida, the
NBER, the University of Pittsburgh, the University of South Carolina, the 1993 FMA meetings, and
the 1994 AFA meetings.
evidence that such transactions improve firm value and operating efficiency.’
More recently, however, many highly-levered firms have encountered financial
distress. For example, Kaplan and Stein (1993) report that 36% of firms
completing management buyouts between 1985 and 1989 subsequently de-
faulted on their debt. This high rate of default has led many to question whether
the benefits from highly-leveraged transactions have been overstated.
Two hypotheses can explain the recent surge in failed transactions. First, the
market for these transactions may have become overheated in the latter part of
the decade, resulting in deals that were overpriced and poorly structured and,
thus, should not have been undertaken. Kaplan and Stein (1993) present evi-
dence of changes in the structure of large management buyouts in the 1980s
that is consistent with this hypothesis.
An alternative, but not mutually exclusive, hypothesis is that problems with
highly-leveraged transactions in the late 1980s stemmed from macroeconomic
and regulatory developments such as the recession, the collapse of the junk bond
market, and the credit crunch of 1990. Thus, transactions that were value-
increasing ex ante may have failed for reasons outside the control of those who
designed them. For example, the economic recession of 1990-91 is likely to have
reduced operating cash flows, thereby increasing the likelihood that a
highly-levered firm would be unable to meet its debt obligations. The recession
may also have had a second, less obvious, effect. Shleifer and Vishny (1992)
argue that asset markets are less liquid during an economic downturn. An
unexpected decline in asset liquidity is particularly damaging to firms for which
asset sales are necessary in order to meet their debt obligations, as is the case in
many highly-leveraged transactions. In addition, Jensen (1991) argues that
several developments, including regulatory restrictions on investments in high-
yield instruments, the prosecution of Drexel Burnham Lambert, and a reduction
in net new lending to the corporate sector by commercial banks (Putnam, 1991,
reports that net new lending to the nonfinancial corporate sector by commercial
banks collapsed from $33 billion in 1989 to $2 billion in 1990), not only reduced
funding available for the purchase of corporate assets but also made it more
difficult for distressed firms to recontract with debt claimants.
We provide evidence on the causes of financial distress following highly-
leveraged transactions by examining a sample of 29 leveraged recapitalizations
(recaps) completed between 1985 and 1988. Unlike firms that complete
leveraged buyouts, firms that undergo leveraged recapitalizations remain
publicly traded. This makes them well-suited for studying the long-run conse-
quences of highly-leveraged transactions because more complete post-transac-
tion data is available through published financial statements.
‘See Kaplan (1989), Muscarella and Vetsuypens (1990), Opler (1992), and Smith (1990) for evidence
on improvements in operating efficiency and equity value following leveraged buyouts. See Denis
and Denis (1993) and Palepu and Wruck (1992) for the effects of leveraged recapitalizations.
D.J. Denis, D.K. DenislJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 129-157 131
2. Sample description
We examine the Wall Street Journal and its index for any indications of
financial distress for our sample firms from the time of the completion of the
recap through December 31, 1991. We define distress as either a restructuring of
debt claims for the purposes of avoiding or resolving default or a filing for
Chapter 11 under the U.S. Bankruptcy Code. Debt restructurings are defined as
in Gilson (1989) and include (a) reductions in stated interest or principal,
ZWe are unable to search the Dow Jones News Retrieval prior to 1984. However, to our knowledge,
there were few (if any) leveraged recaps prior to 1984. Indeed, only one of our sample recaps is
announced in 1984. Ending the sampling period in 1988 allows for at least three post-recap years of
data for each transaction.
D.J. Denis, D.K. DenisjJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 129-157 133
W is possible that our examination of the Wall Street Journal fails to identify some cases of financial
distress and we therefore misclassify some firms. To examine this possibility, we also defined distress
on the basis of interest coverage ratios. Following Asquith, Gertner, and Scharfstein (1992), a firm is
classified as financially distressed if in any two consecutive years its ratio of operating earnings to
interest expense is less than 1.0 or if in any single year this ratio is less than 0.8. The use of this
definition did not identify any additional distressed firms. In fact, only one other firm (Newmont
Mining) had a coverage ratio of less than 1.5 in any year. Newmont’s ratio was 1.2 in the first year
following its recap, but rose to 2.1 by the following year. On the other hand, one of the firms that we
classify as distressed (Holiday) on the basis of an offer to exchange new debt for old would not be
classified as distressed on the basis of its coverage ratio. Our results are not sensitive to the inclusion
of this firm among the distressed firms.
134 D.J. Denis, D.K. DenislJournal of Financial Economics 37 (199.5) 129-157
sample firms. Similar to Kaplan and Stein (1990) and Palepu and Wruck (1992) we
do not find large increases in beta estimates following our sample transactions.
Moreover, there are no statistically significant differences in beta estimates between
the distressed and nondistressed firms either before or after the sample recapitaliza-
tions. We obtain similar results computing abnormal holding period returns rather
than cumulative abnormal returns and annualizing post-recap abnormal returns to
account for the variation in the length of the post-recap period across firms.
Interestingly, there is no significant difference in the cumulative abnormal
returns of the distressed and nondistressed firms over the recap period. Median
cumulative abnormal returns are 25.8% for the nondistressed firms and 32.9%
for the distressed firms. Not surprisingly, however, there is a large difference in
post-recap abnormal returns. Over the period from completion of the recap
through December 31, 1991, median cumulative abnormal returns are an
insignificant - 0.9% for the nondistressed firms and a significant (at the 10%
level) - 56.3% for the distressed firms. The large positive market response to
the recaps of the distressed firms and their strongly negative cumulative abnor-
mal returns in the post-recap period suggest that the market did not view the
distressed firms’ recaps as being poorly structured, ex ante.
Table 1
Average and median (in parentheses) debt service requirements for 29 leveraged recapitalizations
completed between 1985 and 1988
Year 0 is defined as the year the recapitalization is completed. Panel A presents coverage and debt
ratios. Panel B presents the additional cash required to meet year + 1 interest and principal
payments, holding year - 1 operating income and capital expenditures constant, and the percent-
age changes in operating income, total assets, or capital expenditures required to meet these
additional cash needs. P-values denote the significance of the diffe:.mce between the distressed and
nondistressed firms, using a t-test for averages and a Wilcoxon signed-ranks test for medians.
***,**, * denote significance at the 0.01, 0.05, 0.10 levels, respectively.
“Coverage ratios are measured as operating income for the year prior to the recap divided by interest
and principal payments due in the first year after the recap.
‘Debt ratios are measured as of the end of the fiscal year in which the recap is completed.
‘We calculate the additional cash requirement as the interest expense and principal payments
required in the first full year after the recap less operating income net of capital expenditures in the
last full prior to the recap.
dComputed as the percentage change necessary to generate the additional cash required if changes
in this variable were the only way to generate additional cash.
136 D.J. Denis, D.K. DenislJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 129-157
operating income and capital expenditures) in the last full year prior to the recap.
In other words, holding operating income and capital expenditures constant at
pre-recap levels, we calculate how much additional cash is required to meet
post-recap interest and principal payments, ignoring any additional borrowing.
The sample firms require a median $34.5 million additional cash to meet
post-recap debt payments. The median firm could generate this amount by
either increasing operating income by a median 34.7%, selling a median 5.3% of
the total assets of the firm (if the assets are sold for their book value), or reducing
capital expenditures by a median 50.4% (or, of course, by some combination of
these actions). By way of comparison, Kaplan (1989) reports median changes of
15.6% in operating income and - 21.1% in capital expenditures from the year
before to the year after management buyouts. He does not report changes in
total assets but does indicate that 20 of his 48 sample firms divest assets worth
more than 5% of the total value of the buyout.
The results also indicate that the distressed firms require significantly more
drastic post-recap changes than do the nondistressed firms. The median re-
quired change in operating income is 41.8% for the distressed firms and 18.9%
for the nondistressed firms. Alternatively, the median distressed firm could meet
its cash needs by selling 6.3% of its total assets, whereas the median nondis-
tressed firm would only have to sell 3.6% of its assets. Finally, the median
capital expenditure reduction required by the distressed firms is 73.9%, versus
26.1% for the nondistressed firms.
Overall, the findings in Table 1 suggest that the distressed firms structure their
recaps such that they are financially more vulnerable than the nondistressed
firms, on average. One explanation for this difference is that the distressed firms
took on unreasonably high levels of debt in their recaps, consistent with an
overheated market. Alternatively, the distressed firms may have expected to
engage in a greater amount of post-recap restructuring, such as through asset
sales, but unfavorable post-recap events limited the extent of this activity.
4Denis and Denis (1993) and Palepu and Wruck (1992) also provide evidence on changes in
operating income, total assets, and capital expenditures following leveraged recapitalizations. This
D.J. Denis, D.K. Denis/Joumal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 129-157 131
Table 2
Post-recap changes in operating characteristics for the sample of 29 leveraged recapitalizations
completed between 1985 and 1988
Changes are measured from the year prior to through the third full year following each recapitali-
zation (year - 1 to year + 3). Median percentage changes are listed for the 20 firms not experienc-
ing financial distress through the end of 1991 and the nine firms experiencing some form of financial
distress over the same period. P-values denote the significance of the Wilcoxon signed-ranks test
comparing the median values for each of the two subsamples. ***. **, *denote significance at the
0.01, 0.05, 0.10 levels, respectively.
Percentage changes
Year - 1
level c - 1, 11 c- 421 I: - L31
“Industry-adjusted change equals the percentage change in the ratio for the sample firm minus the
median percentage change for its control firms over the same period. For each sample firm, a control
set of firms is defined as those firms listed on Compustat that have the same two-digit SIC code and
have a book value of total assets within 25% of that of the sample firm. If this results in fewer than
three control firms, we include the industry firms that are next closest in book value of total assets
until we have three control firms.
study differs in that we (i) provide evidence on differences between distressed and nondistressed
firms, (ii) present industry comparisons, and (iii) measure changes through three years following the
recap. Denis and Denis (1993) do not provide evidence on (i) and (iii) while Palepu and Wruck do not
provide evidence on (i) and (ii).
138 D.J. Denis, D.K. DenislJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995/ 129-157
order to avoid default. In spite of this, however, Table 2 indicates that the
financially distressed firms do not sell a greater fraction of their assets than do
the nondistressed firms. The percentage change in total assets over the
[ - 1, + 31 window is - 8.8% for the distressed firms and - 7.3% for the
nondistressed firms. Over the [ - 1, -t 21 window, the distressed firms actually
increase their total assets by 3.3%. We address the issue of asset sales in more
detail in the following section.
Table 2 also presents evidence on the magnitude of capital expenditure
reductions for the distressed and nondistressed firms. We measure percentage
changes in both the level of capital expenditures and the ratio of capital
expenditures to total assets. While the capital expenditure reductions are gener-
ally greater for the distressed firms, they are significant only over the [ - 1, + 31
window for the ratio of capital expenditures to total assets. The percentage
change in this ratio over the [ - 1, + 33 window is - 61.8% for the distressed
firms and - 19.7% for the nondistressed firms (with the difference significant at
the 0.07 level).
It is interesting to note that the distressed firms appear to make cuts in capital
expenditures similar to those of the nondistressed firms in the year immediately
following the recapitalization and then make further cuts in years + 2 and + 3.
In contrast, the nondistressed firms do not make further capital expenditure
reductions following year + 1, suggesting that the distressed firms are forced
into making deeper capital expenditure cuts than they had initially planned,
perhaps due to unexpectedly poor operating performance and/or lower-than-
expected proceeds from asset sales (for an example, see the Appendix entry for
Carter Hawley Hale).
The recession and several legal and regulatory events may have led to
a reduction in the liquidity of asset markets in the late 1980s and early 1990s. If
there is such a reduction in liquidity, firms attempting to sell assets will suffer
two effects. First, some assets will not be sold because the price obtained for
them would be lower than the expected benefits of retaining the assets, resulting
in actual levels of asset sales that are lower than planned levels. Second, those
assets that are sold may be sold for a lower price than was initially expected. If
the latter is the case, we would expect a negative market reaction to asset sale
announcements even if the sales themselves are value-enhancing.5
51f our distressed firms tend to be smaller, single-division firms, or if they have a greater fraction of
intangible assets, they may have more difficulty selling assets regardless of the liquidity of the asset
sales market (Brown, James, and Mooradian, 1991). However, we find that the distressed and
nondistressed firms do not differ significantly in any of these characteristics.
140 D.J. Denis, D.K. DenislJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 129-157
We search the Wall Street Journal for each sample firm for qualitative
evidence that the distressed firms are more likely to experience difficulty com-
pleting planned asset sales. Four of the nine distressed firms are the subject of at
least one article indicating that the firm either was unable to complete a planned
asset sale or received a disappointing price for assets sold (see the Appendix
entries for Carter Hawley Hale, Goodyear, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, and
Interco). There are no such references for any of the 20 nondistressed firms.
We further examine whether the prices received for sold assets were disap-
pointing by examining stock price reactions to announcements related to
specific asset sales subsequent to each firm’s recapitalization. We search the
Wall Street Journal Index and 8-K reports for each firm for the period extending
from the completion of the firm’s recap through the end of 1991. This process
results in a sample of 177 announcements related to asset sales, 127 by the
nondistressed firms and 50 by the distressed firms.6 Of the 29 sample firms,
25 announce asset sales following completion of their recaps. The median
number of announcements per firm is six, with a range of 0 to 22. However, we
do not have stock return data for two of the firms. (Colt Industries went private
prior to its asset sale announcements and Metromedia could not be found on
the CRSP tapes.) Thus, our analysis focuses on 172 announcements made by 23
firms.
Our sample of asset sale announcements differs from those of previous studies
in two important ways. First, our sample firms have all recently undergone
a highly-leveraged transaction, thus raising the probability that they will at-
tempt to sell assets. In most cases, the firms explicitly state that they will sell
assets in the near future and that the proceeds from these sales will be used to
pay down debt. Thus, most of our asset sales will be at least partially anticipated.
Second, we examine a time period, 1989-1991, in which, for reasons mentioned
previously, there may have been significant shocks to asset liquidity.
Panel A of Table 3 summarizes the abnormal returns associated with our
sample of asset sale announcements. For each announcement we cumulate
market model abnormal returns over a three-day interval centered on the
announcement. For our full sample of 172 announcements, we observe an
average three-day [ - 1, l] abnormal return of 0.07%, insignificantly different
from zero. However, similar to previous studies of asset sales (e.g., Hite, Owers,
and Rogers, 1987), announcements by the nondistressed firms are characterized
by significant positive average abnormal returns averaging 0.69% (Z = 2.52).
In contrast, the announcements of the distressed firms are characterized by
6The number of announcements does not directly correspond to the number of distinct divestitures.
There is occasionally more than one announcement relative to a given divestiture; all of these
announcements are included in our analysis. On the other hand, one announcement occasionally
concerns more than one distinct divestiture.
D.J. Denis, D.K. Denis/Joumal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 129-157 141
Table 3
Three-day announcement-period abnormal returns for 172 post-recap announcements related to
asset sales made by the sample of 29 firms completing leveraged recapitalizations between 1985 and
1988
Panel A presents summary measures for the sample of 172 announcements. Panel B presents
summary measures of abnormal returns per firm. Panel C presents summary measures of the
cumulative abnormal return for each firm’s announcements. Abnormal returns are estimated using
the standard market model procedure with parameters estimated over the 250-trading-day period
beginning 290 days prior to each announcement day. Significance of mean abnormal returns is
measured using Z-values. P-values measure the significance of differences in average and median
abnormal returns for the two subsamples using two-sample t-tests for averages and the Wilcoxon
signed-ranks test for medians. ***, **, *denote significance at the 0.01, 0.05, 0.10 levels, respectively.
distressed firms. Median abnormal returns for the nondistressed and distressed
firms are 0.19% and - 1.60%; the latter is significant at the 0.05 level.
We also compute each sample firm’s average abnormal return as the average
of the three-day abnormal returns associated with each of that firm’s asset sale
announcements. The results in panel B suggest that the negative abnormal
returns surrounding the announcements of the distressed firms are not limited to
just a few firms. The mean average abnormal return for the distressed firms is
- 2.07% (2 = - 1.87) and 71.4% of the observations are negative. In contrast,
the mean average abnormal return is 0.63% (2 = 2.11) for the nondistressed
firms and only 31.2% of the observations are negative.
Finally, for each firm, we cumulate the three-day abnormal returns associated
with the firm’s asset sale announcements. The results in panel C of Table 3
suggest that the cumulative effects of the asset sale announcements for the
distressed firms are economically quite large. The average cumulative abnormal
return for the distressed firms is - 11.87% (2 = - 1.87). In contrast, the
average cumulative abnormal return is 5.33% (2 = 2.11) for the nondistressed
firms.
The share price declines associated with the asset sale announcements of the
distressed firms are consistent with the hypothesis that, on average, the prices
received by the distressed firms are unexpectedly low due to a reduction in the
liquidity of asset markets. Alternatively, however, the distressed firms’ an-
nouncements may simply convey information about the firms’ unexpected need
for funds. Although this seems unlikely given that the large additional cash
requirements estimated in Table 1 are known at the time of the recap and that
most of the sample firms publicly state that they will sell assets following the
completion of their recapitalization, we examine a subsample of five asset sales
by distressed firms for which there is an announcement of the intent to sell an
asset followed by a separate announcement that terms of a sale have been agreed
upon. If the distressed firms’ negative abnormal returns are due to the negative
information implied by the need to raise additional funds, the reaction to the
announcement of intent should be negative. We find, however, that the orig-
inal-intent announcements are met with an insignificant median abnormal
return of 0.2%, while the announcements of the terms of the sales are associated
with a significant (at the 0.07 level) median abnormal return of - 2.39%. These
results suggest that the negative abnormal returns of the full sample of distressed
firms’ announcements are not due to the market inferring negative information
about the need to raise cash.
Another interpretation of the negative abnormal returns associated with
the distressed firms’ asset sales is that the poor financial condition of the
distressed firms weakens their bargaining position and thus reduces the prices
received for the assets sold regardless of the liquidity of asset markets. For
example, creditors may force inefficient liquidations that enhance the value of
their claim but damage equity value. Gilson (1990) notes that creditors in
D.J. Denis, D.K. Denis/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 129-157 143
Table 4
Three-day announcement-period abnormal returns for post-recap announcements of asset sales,
partitioned by the coverage ratio of the sample firm and the performance of the industry
Troubled industries are defined as those in which the median control firm experiences a negative
change in operating earnings in the period from one year prior to two years after the recapitalization
of the sample firm. The sample firm’s coverage ratio is defined as the ratio of operating earnings to
interest and principal obligations for the year ending just prior to the asset sale announcement. In
each cell, we compute an average abnormal return associated with each firm’s announcements so
that there is at most one observation per firm in each cell. We then report the mean average
abnormal return, the median average abnormal return, the Z-statistic in parentheses, the fraction
negative in brackets, and the number of observations. Abnormal returns are estimated using the
standard market model procedure with parameters estimated over the 250-trading-day period
beginning 290 days prior to each announcement day.
Troubled Healthy
industries industries Difference
of the buying firm, 88 are in the same industry as the seller. The fraction of
buyers outside the industry does not differ significantly between the distressed
and nondistressed firms, nor are there any significant differences between the
stock price reactions of asset sales to industry and nonindustry buyers.
In Table 5 we address the extent to which the distressed firms could have
avoided distress had they had fewer problems selling assets. We compute
a measure of the total cash shortfall from asset sales for each distressed firm.
Whenever available, we use the difference between the price received for the
asset and the expected price as reported in the Wall Street Journal. Alternatively,
we estimate the cash shortfall as the abnormal return on the announcement of
the asset sale times the market value of the firm’s equity. Where possible, we
include the cash shortfall from asset sales not completed; the total shortfall will
be understated to the extent that we are unable to obtain an expected price for
assets not sold. We compare this total asset sale shortfall to the additional cash
D.J. Denis, D.K. Denis/Journal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 129-157 145
Table 5
A comparison of the total cash shortfall from asset sales and the additional cash required to avoid
default in the year of the first indication of financial distress for the nine distressed firms
The total asset sale shortfall is the sum of the shortfall from completed asset sales and the shortfall
from sales not completed. We measure both shortfalls as the difference between the price received for
the asset (zero in the case of an asset sale that was not completed) and the expected price as stated in
press reports. When this quantity is unavailable, we measure the shortfall as the abnormal return
over the three days centered on the announcement of the sale multiplied by the market value of the
firm’s equity. The additional cash required in the first year of distress is the difference between the
firm’s interest and principal obligations and its net cash flow (operating income less capita1
expenditures) for that year.
“Carter Hawley Hale’s total shortfall includes $650 million from asset sales not completed. Similarly,
Goodyear’s total includes $750 million, and Harcourt Brace Jovanovich’s includes $33.9 million
from sales not completed.
required to avoid default in the year in which we have the first indication of
distress. (Of course, our estimates implicitly assume that any additional cash
flow from asset sales could be used to pay the current year’s required interest
and principal. However, bank loan covenants may require the firm to use the
proceeds from asset sales to pay down bank debt rather than to make interest or
principal payments on any other debt claims.)
The results in Table 5 indicate that the shortfalls from asset sales are of
sufficient magnitude to have had a meaningful impact on the probability of
distress. The median shortfall is $140.7 million, nearly identical to the median
$139.5 million required to avoid default. Five of the nine distressed firms exhibit
shortfalls from attempted asset sales that are greater in magnitude than the
additional cash needed to avoid default. For a sixth firm, the shortfall is
approximately 85% of the additional cash needed. These findings suggest that
the majority of the distressed firms could have remained solvent had asset sales
produced the anticipated proceeds.
146 D.J. Denis, D.K. DenislJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 129-157
We search the Dow Jones News Retrieval for announcements of the events
discussed above. This process results in a sample of seven event dates related to
reductions in funding available for corporate control transactions. If the above
events have an adverse effect on the ability of our sample firms to sell the assets
necessary to meet debt obligations or to recontract with debt claimants, we
expect to observe negative stock price reactions to the event announcements.
Moreover, we expect more-negative announcement effects for the distressed
firms because they are financially more vulnerable at the time of the announce-
ments. Recall that all but one of the distressed firms’ recaps were completed in
1987 and 1988. The distressed firms thus had little time to pay down debt prior
to these legal and regulatory developments. Consistent with this, the median
ratio of operating income to interest and principal obligations as of year-end
1988 is 0.98 for the distressed firms and 2.57 for the nondistressed firms.
We are unable to include two potentially important events in our analysis
because we could not identify precise announcement dates. First, in 1990, the
National Association of Insurance Commissioners (NAIC) imposed tougher
reserve requirements for insurers’ junk bond holdings. Since insurers historically
account for about 30% of junk bond purchases (see ‘Insurance Firms’ Junk
Bond Holdings Likely to Face Tougher Rules By States’, Wall Street Journal,
April 30, 1990), this action was expected to further damage the market for
high-yield debt. Second, shortly after the collapse of the UAL buyout, bank
regulators imposed new accounting standards for loans made in leveraged
transactions. A loan was now classified as an HLT loan if it more than doubled
the firm’s debt and made debt equal to at least 50% of total assets. Previously,
a bank loan was classified as an HLT only if debt exceeded 75% of total assets.
These new standards were expected to have a ‘substantial effect on the level of
HLTs’ (see ‘Bank Stocks Face Headache From Loan List’, Wall Street Journul,
November 30, 1989).
Table 6 provides a brief description of each event and reports average and
median abnormal returns over the three-day period centered on the announce-
ment of each event. Panel A indicates that average abnormal returns for the full
sample are significantly negative for five of the seven event periods. Panel B
presents the average and median total cumulative abnormal returns over the
seven events for the sample firms. For comparison purposes, panel B also
presents total cumulative abnormal returns for the control firms over these same
seven events. The results indicate that the sample firms’ cumulative abnormal
return over all seven events averages - 10.69% (median = - 9.81%). In
contrast, the control firms’ mean and median cumulative abnormal returns do
not differ significantly from zero. Thus, these events have a negative impact on
the sample firms that is not experienced by similar firms that have not under-
gone highly-leveraged transactions.
Although both the distressed and nondistressed firms exhibit cumulative
abnormal returns that are significantly negative, Table 6 indicates that there is
\
Table 6 6
Average and median (in parentheses) three-day abnormal returns surrounding announcements related to the decline of the market for highly-leveraged $
transactions %
%
Results are presented for the full sample of 29 firms completing leveraged recapitalizations between 1985 and 1988, the 20 firms not experiencing financial 2
distress through the end of 1991, and the nine firms experiencing some form of financial distress. P-values test for differences in abnormal returns between $
the two subsamples. ***, **, * denote significance at the 0.01, 0.05, 0.10 levels, respectively. k’
Full Non- s
sample distressed Distressed
3.
2
Average Average Average P-value lo
(Median) (Median) (Median) (difference) 2:
2
z
Panel A. Cumulative abnormal returns for individual events L
1. 3/16/89 SEC pressures Drexel to remove Milken from control of junk bond -0.51% -0.69% 0.33% 0.99 2
P
operations (1.25%)* (- 1.44%) ( - 1.23%) (0.96)
5
2. 6/6/89 Integrated Resources defaults on portion of commercial paper - 1.32% 1.13% - 1.68% 0.94
obligation (-1.30)** (- 1.28%)** (- 1.32%) (0.9 1)
3. 7/26/89 Congressional ban on investment in junk bonds by thrift institutions - 1.90%*** -0.77% -4 020/L?*** 0.00
(-1.75%)* (-0.96%) (-4:21%)* (0.16)
4. 9/14/89 Campeaw unable to make $50 million interest payment due next day - 199%*** -154%** (-3:02%)**
-2 90%*** 0.44
(-2:12%)*** (-1:36%)* (0.22)
5. N/16/89 Collapse of UAL buyout due to reluctance of banks to provide -307%*** -2.56%*** - 3.96%*** 0.53
financing (-2:360/o)*** (-2.43%)*** (-2.09%)** 0.98 b
6. 2/1#/90 Drexel Burnham Lambert files for bankruptcy protection - 0.11% 0.09% - 0.54% 0.76 5
( - 0.54%) (- 0.54%) (0.86%) (0.88) if
-6.15%*** 0.00 *G’
7. 10/22/90 Proposal to limit money market fund investment in low-grade -163%** 0.50%
commercial paper (- l:80%) (0.16%)
~. . ( - 6.57%)+
_______~ (0.01) ~~~ :
b
Panel B. Cumulative abnormal returns over all events 3
i;,
Sample firms - 10.69%*** -606%*"* - 19.96%*** 0.00 2
(-9.81%)*** (-8:770/a)** (- l&30%)*** (0.07) 2
3
Control firms -1.20% - 1.55% -0.05% 0.33 k
(-0.68%) (-0.72%) (0.32%) (0.50) q
P-value (difference) 0.00 0.03 0.00
(0.00) (0,06) (0.00)
(.
150 D.J. Denis, D.K. DenislJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 129-157
As expected, those firms that are financially more vulnerable at the time of the
announcements experience lower announcement returns. Moreover, the regres-
sion model explains 47% of the cross-sectional variation in cumulative abnor-
mal returns.
It is noteworthy that the losses suffered by the distressed firms’ shareholders
over just these seven event periods (21 trading days) represent a large portion of
the total shareholder losses suffered by these firms in the post-recap period. The
median ratio of the total cumulative abnormal return associated with the seven
events to the total cumulative abnormal return from completion of the recap
through December 31, 1991 is 17.7% for the nine distressed firms. If we add the
total cumulative abnormal returns associated with each distressed firm’s asset
sales announcements to the seven event-period cumulative abnormal returns we
can account for a median 53.2% of the post-recap shareholder losses even though
these event periods account for only a median 3.9% of the post-recap trading days.
D.J. Denis, D.K. DenislJournal of’Financia1 Economics 37 (1995) 129-157 151
The evidence to this point supports the hypothesis that post-recap economic
and regulatory developments are an important cause of financial distress in our
sample firms. However, it is possible that poor ex ante deal structure also
contributes to the likelihood of financial distress. Indeed, as noted earlier, one
interpretation of the evidence in Table 1 is that the distressed firms took on
unreasonably high levels of debt in their recaps. We address this issue by
examining characteristics that Kaplan and Stein (1993) and Palepu and Wruck
(1992) have previously linked with poorly-structured highly-leveraged transac-
tions.
Kaplan and Stein (1993) document a positive relation between the use ofjunk
bond financing and the incidence of financial distress in a sample of large
management buyouts completed in the 1980s. They argue that their evidence is
consistent with an overheated buyout market in which excess demand from junk
bond buyers caused some deals to be structured in a way that made them more
vulnerable to financial distress. Panel A of Table 7 indicates, however, that the
use of junk bonds is not related to the incidence of financial distress in our recap
sample; 56% of the distressed firms and 59% of the nondistressed firms issue
junk bonds to finance their recapitalizations.
Kaplan and Stein also suggest that managers who liquidate a large fraction of
their pre-buyout equity holdings may have a greater incentive to participate in
overpriced or poorly-structured transactions. We measure the ratio of the dollar
value of management’s post-recap equity holdings in the sample firms to the
dollar value of their pre-recap equity holdings. Panel A of Table 7 indicates that
this ratio is higher for the nondistressed firms, a median of 0.67 versus 0.30 for
the distressed firms, suggesting that distressed firm managers do cash out to
a greater degree. However, this difference is not statistically significant.
Finally, Palepu and Wruck (1992) suggest that defensive recaps are more
likely to be poorly structured than are voluntary recaps. They find that recaps
preceded by hostile takeover bids are followed by poor stock price performance,
while voluntary recaps are followed by positive cumulative abnormal returns.
However, panel A of Table 7 does not reveal a significant difference in the
fraction of recaps that are defensive in our distressed and nondistressed sub-
samples; 44% of the distressed recaps and 60% of the nondistressed recaps are
defensive.
The fact that the distressed and nondistressed firms do not differ with respect
to any of the characteristics that have previously been linked to poorly-struc-
tured deals leads us to conclude that ex ante vulnerability is not the primary
explanation of financial distress in our sample. Nevertheless, the finding that the
distressed firms are not more likely to have been preceded by hostile bids is
surprising given that Palepu and Wruck (1992) document poor stock returns
following defensive recaps over virtually the same time period. We explore this
152 D.J. Denis, D.K. DenislJournal of Financial Economies 37 (1995) 129-157
Table 7
Characteristics related to the ex ante vulnerability of 29 firms that completed leveraged recapitali-
zations between 1985 and 1988
Panel A presents the fraction of firms using junk bonds, the median ratio of post- to pre-recap
managerial ownership, and the fraction of firms with hostile takeover bids prior to the recap for the
full sample and for the distressed and nondistressed subsamples. Panel B presents median post-recap
cumulative abnormal returns and median absolute and industry-adjusted changes in the ratio of
operating income before depreciation to total assets (OIBDITA) for the defensive and voluntary
subsamples. P-values denote the significance of the difference between subsamples, using a Wilcoxon
signed-ranks test and a difference in proportions test. ** denotes significance at the 0.05 level.
P-value
Defensive Voluntary (difference)
“The post-recap period extends from the completion of the recap to December 31, 1991. Abnormal
returns are computed using the standard market model technique; parameters are estimated over the
250-day period beginning 290 days prior to day 0.
‘Industry-adjusted change equals the percentage change in the ratio for the sample firm minus the
median percentage change for its control firms over the same period. For each sample firm, a control
set of firms is defined as those firms listed on Compustat that have the same two-digit SIC code and
have a book value of total assets within 25% of that of the sample firm. If this results in fewer than
three control firms, we include the industry firms that are next closest in book value of total assets
until we have three control firms.
returns over the period from completion of the recap through December 31,
1991. This result differs significantly from the positive, though insignificant,
cumulative returns following voluntary recaps.
It is puzzling that the defensive firms’ negative abnormal stock returns are
not associated with a higher incidence of financial distress. We conjecture
that the poor stock price performance may reflect unfulfilled expectations
of a subsequent takeover of the firm. Press reports indicate that six of the
11 defensive recaps that do not subsequently incur distress remain takeover
targets following the completion of the recap, but are not taken over by the
end of 1991. A seventh firm (Owens-Corning Fiberglas) loses 25% of its value
when it announces a large charge to earnings to cover the expected costs of
asbestos litigation. Moreover, panel B of Table 7 indicates that, unlike the
distressed firms, firms that undertake defensive recaps do not exhibit median
decreases in post-recap operating profitability. We conclude that the negative
stock returns following defensive recaps are not due to poor post-recap operat-
ing performance.
7. Conclusion
Appendix
This appendix provides brief case histories of the nine sample firms that
experienced financial distress following completion of their leveraged recapital-
izations. The information is obtained from annual reports, proxy statements,
10-K reports, and articles appearing in the Wall Street Journal.
Holiday Corp.
Holiday paid a special dividend of $65 per share or $2.6 billion, increasing total debt to 132% of the
book value of total assets. The recap was in response to a rumored hostile takeover attempt by
Donald Trump. Analysts generally considered the move a mistake, believing that it would leave the
firm very vulnerable to economic downturns. Approximately six months after the recap, the firm
sold its hotels outside North America to Bass PLC to relieve the pressures of its debt obligations.
Three months later, Holiday completed an exchange offer for some of the firm’s outstanding notes.
Subsequently, the firm sold its entire Holiday Inn operations to Bass PLC and spun off its remaining
properties into a new company named Promus.
Interco
Interco made a special payout of $2.4 billion in cash and securities, increasing total debt to 157% of
the book value of total assets. The recap was proposed in response to a hostile takeover attempt by
the Rales brothers. The firm intended to sell assets quickly following the recap. In the three years
following the recap, the ratio of operating income to total assets declined by 51% and the book value
of total assets was reduced by 37%. The prices received for the assets sold were generally lower than
the firm and its advisor, Wasserstein Perella, had expected. The firm’s Ethan Allen and Central
Hardware divisions were sold for a total of only $633 million when $850-$950 million had been
expected. Wasserstein Perella blamed the poor price for Ethan Allen on reduced profit expectations
and the inability of potential acquirers to find financing following the collapse of the junk bond
market. Ultimately, after failing to reach an agreement with its bondholders to restructure the firm’s
debt, Interco filed for bankruptcy under Chapter 11 in January 1991. The firm emerged from
bankruptcy in August 1992.
Quantum Chemical
Quantum Chemical paid a special dividend of $50 per share, increasing the firm’s total debt to 114%
of the book value of total assets. The firm had recently divested its wine and spirits business to focus
on its core chemical business and announced a $600 million expansion in that area to take
advantage of excess demand in the industry. In the following year prices for the firm’s products fell
by 20-30%. In addition, a fire shut down a plant responsible for 20% of the firm’s production. In the
three years following the recap, the ratio of the firm’s operating income to total assets declined by
56%. Beginning in ‘1990, Quantum delayed further expansion, closed three plants, and began
looking for nonstrategic assets to sell. Over the three-year period, however, the firm actually
increased the book value ofits assets by 24% and capital expenditures by 4%. In 1991 Quantum was
forced to write off its equity in Petrolane, a joint venture it had entered in 1989. By 1991, the third
year following its recap, Quantum’s operating profits were no longer sufficient to cover its interest
and principal obligations and the firm was forced to restructure its debt.
Swank
Swank paid a special dividend of $18.10 per share to all nonmanagement and non-ESOP shares,
increasing total debt to 77% of the book value of total assets. In the three years following the recap,
the ratio of operating income to total assets increased 62% and the book value of total assets was
reduced by 51%. Nevertheless, in each of the three years following the recap, the firm’s operating
156 D.J. Denis, D.K. DenisjJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 129-157
income was insufficient to cover its interest and principal obligations and the firm was in violation of
some covenants of its credit agreements. The credit agreements were subsequently amended.
USG Corp.
Following the acquisition of a 9.8% stake in the firm by Desert Partners, USG made a special
payout of cash, debt, and stock totaling $37 per share or $2.15 billion. At the time of Desert’s
acquisition, competition for the firm’s major product was increasing and its price structure was
weakening. The recap increased total debt to 181% of the book value of total assets. USG
announced its intention to sell assets, institute cost cutting measures, and cut capital expenditures by
more than 50%. In the three years following the recap, the ratio of operating income to total assets
declined by 54%, the book value of total assets was reduced by 22%, and capital expenditures were
cut by 73%. The firm defaulted on its junk bond interest obligations in 1991 and declared
bankruptcy under Chapter 11 in 1992. At that time, every one of USGS major competitors were also
operating in Chapter 11.
References
Asquith, Paul, Robert Gertner, and David Scharfstein, 1992, Anatomy of financial distress: An
examination of junk bond issuers, Working paper (Massachusetts Institute of Technology,
Cambridge, MA).
Benveniste, Lawrence M., Manoj Singh, and William J. Wilhelm, 1992, The failure of Drexel
Burnham Lambert: Evidence on the implications for commercial banks, Working paper (Boston
College, Chestnut Hill, MA).
Brown, David T., Christopher M. James, and Robert M. Mooradian, 1991, Asset sales by financially
distressed firms, Working paper (University of Florida, Gainesville, FL).
Brown, David T., Christopher M. James, and Robert M. Mooradian, 1993, Asset sales by financially
distressed firms, Working paper (University of Florida, Gainesville, FL).
Brown, David T., Christopher M. James, and Michael Ryngaert, 1992, The effects of leverage on
operating performance: An analysis of firms’ responses to poor performance, Working paper
(University of Florida, Gainesville, FL).
Comment, Robert and G. William Schwert, 1993, Poison or placebo? Evidence on the deterrent and
wealth effects of modern antitakeover measures, Working paper (University of Rochester,
Rochester, NY).
Denis, David J. and Diane K. Denis, 1993, Managerial discretion, organizational structure, and
corporate performance: A study of leveraged recapitalizations, Journal of Accounting and
Economics 16, 209-236.
Gilson, Stuart, 1989, Management turnover and financial distress, Journal of Financial Economics
25, 241-262.
Gilson, Stuart, 1990, Bankruptcy, boards, banks, and blockholders, Journal of Financial Economics
27, 355-388.
Hite, Gailen L., James E. Owers, and Ronald C. Rogers, 1987, The market for interfirm asset sales:
Partial sell-offs and total liquidations, Journal of Financial Economics 18, 229-252.
Jensen, Michael C., 1991, Corporate control and the politics of finance, Journal of Applied
Corporate Finance 4, 13-33.
John, Kose, Larry H.P. Lang, and Jeffry Netter, 1992, The voluntary restructuring of large firms in
response to performance decline, Journal of Finance 47, 891-918.
Kaplan, Steven, 1989, The effects of management buyouts on operations and value, Journal of
Financial Economics 24, 217-254.
Kaplan, Steven and Jeremy Stein, 1993, The evolution of buyout pricing and financial structure in
the 198Os, Quarterly Journal of Economics, May, 313-357.
D.J. Denis, D.K. DenislJournal of Financial Economics 37 (1995) 129-157 151
Kaplan, Steven and Jeremy Stein, 1990, How risky is the debt in highly leveraged transactions?,
Journal of Financial Economics 27, 215-245.
Muscarella, Chris J. and Michael R. Vetsuypens, 1990, Efficiency and organizational structure:
A study of reverse LBOs, Journal of Finance 45, 138991413.
Ofek, Eli, 1993, Capital structure and firm response to poor performance: An empirical analysis,
Journal of Financial Economics 34, 3-30.
Opler, Tim, 1992, Operating performance in leveraged buyouts: Evidence from 1985-1989, Financial
Management 21, 27-34.
Palepu, Krishna G. and Karen H. Wruck, 1992, Consequences of leveraged shareholder payouts:
Defensive versus voluntary recapitalizations, Working paper (Harvard University, Cambridge,
MA).
Putnam, Bluford H., 1991, Regulation and capital market efficiency: Some evidence from the U.S.
credit crunch of 1990, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 4, 92-95.
Shleifer, Andrei and Robert Vishny, 1992, Liquidation values and debt capacity: A market equilib-
rium approach, Journal of Finance 47, 1343-1366.
Smith, Abbie, 1990, Corporate ownership structure and performance: The case of management
buyouts, Journal of Financial Economics 27, 143-164.
Waite, Stephen R., 1991, The eclipse of growth capital, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 4,
77-85.
Weston, J. Fred, 1989, Divestitures: Mistakes or learning, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 2,
68-76.
Yago, Glenn, 1991, The credit crunch: A regulatory squeeze on growth capital, Journal of Applied
Corporate Finance 4,96-100.