ch05
ch05
Chapter 5 equilibria
Subgame Perfection
Game in Extensive Form (Selten, 1965)
2 2 L 1, 3 1, 3 2, 0 2, 0
1
l r l r R 4, 2 0, 1 4, 2 0, 1
7 8
l r l r Enter
IBM
Telex Accommodate
1: 3 1 2 4 2, 2
2: 1 4 3 2 Stay Out
With imperfect information, each information set consisting
of a single node determines a subgame. Hence, there are 1, 5
no (proper) subgames in this example.
9 10
Telex vs. IBM, extensive form: Telex vs. IBM, normal form:
no subgame The payoff matrix
0, 0 IBM
Smash Telex Smash Accommodate
Enter
Enter 0, 0 2, 2
Accommodate 2, 2
IBM
Telex
Stay Out Smash 1, 5
Stay Out 1, 5 1, 5
Accommodate 1, 5 11 12
Telex vs. IBM, normal form: Telex vs. IBM, normal form:
Strategy for IBM Strategy for Telex
IBM IBM
Telex Smash Accommodate Telex Smash Accommodate
Enter 0, 0 2, 2 Enter 0, 0 2, 2
13 14
Telex vs. IBM, normal form: Telex vs. IBM, extensive form:
Two equilibria noncredible equilibrium
IBM
Telex Smash Accommodate 0, 0
Smash
Enter IBM
0, 0 2, 2 Enter
Telex Accommodate
2, 2
Stay Out 1, 5 1, 5 Stay Out
1, 5
15 16
Take the
money 1, 0
0, 0
Smash
IBM 1 Take the
Enter 0, 4
money
Wait
Telex Accommodate
2, 2 2
Stay Out
Split the
1, 5 money 2, 2
17 18
Centipede, normal form:
Centipede, extensive form The payoff matrix
Take the Player 2
money 1, 0 Take the Split the
Player 1 money money
2
Wait 0, 4 2, 2
Split the
money 2, 2
19 20
Wait 0, 4 2, 2 Wait 0, 4 2, 2
21 22
Wait 0, 4 2, 2
23 24
Credible Threats and
Promises Telex vs. Mean IBM
25 26
2
Wait 0, 0 2, 2
Split the
money 2, 2
27 28
Wait 0, 0 2, 2 Wait 0, 0 2, 2
29 30
Centipede with a nice opponent,
normal form: The equilibrium Mutually Assured Destruction
Player 2
Take the Split the aThe credibility issue surrounding weapons
Player 1 money money of mass destruction
aA game with two very different subgame
Take the
money 1, 0 1, 0 perfect equilibria
aSubgame perfection and the problem of
mistakes
Wait 0, 0 2, 2
31 32
0, 0
i, b 0, 0 0, 0 0, 0 0, 0
35 36
Credible Quantity Competition: Cournot-Stackelberg Equilibrium:
Cournot-Stackelberg Equilibrium firm 2’s best response
aThe first mover advantage in Cournot- X2 = q(x1)
Stackelberg competition
Monopoly
60
aOne firm sends its quantity to the market Cournot Point
first. The second firm makes its moves
40
subsequently. Stackelberg Point
39 40
41 42
Cournot-Stackelberg Equilibrium: Firm 1 The Cournot-Stackelberg
also wants to maximize its profits Equilibrium for two firms
Firm 1’s profit function is given by: The Cournot-Stackelberg equilibrium value of
u1(x) = [130 - x1 - g(x1) - 10] x1 firm 1’s shipments, x1* = 60
Substituting g(x1) into that function: Firm 2’s shipments, x2* = 60 - 60/2 = 30
u1(x) = (120 - x1 - 60 + x1/2) x1 Market Quantity, Q = 60 + 30 = 90
∴ Firm 1’s profits depend only on its Market Price, P = 130 - 90 = $40
shipment
This equilibrium is different from Cournot
Taking the first order condition for u1(x): competition’s equilibrium, where x1* = x2* = 40,
0 = 60 - x1 Q = 80 and P = $50
43 44
47 48
Two firms in a Bertrand competition Two firms in a Bertrand competition
aThe demand function faced by firm 1: aFirm 1 has profits
x1(p) = 180 - p1 - (p1 - average price) u1(p1,p2) = (p1 - 20) x1
= (p1 - 20) (180 - 2p1 + average price)
aThe demand function faced by firm 2: = (p1 - 20) (180 - 1.5p1 + 0.5p2)
x2(p) = 180 - p2 - (p2 - average price) aFirm 2’s profit function
u2(p1,p2)
= (p2 - 20) (180 - 1.5p2 + 0.5p1)
49 50
55 56
57 58
61 62
63