SFIFertilityand TPAccepted Version
SFIFertilityand TPAccepted Version
net/publication/387718326
Sexual Freedom, Fertility, and Time Preferences: Panel Data Analysis From 1960
to 2010
CITATIONS READS
0 22
2 authors:
All content following this page was uploaded by Feler Bose on 08 January 2025.
Feler Bose*
School of Business and Economics
Indiana University, East
Richmond, IN 47374, USA
Email: [email protected]
Jeffry Jacob
Department of Business and Economics,
Bethel University,
St. Paul, MN 55112, USA
Email: [email protected]
Key Words: Sexual Freedom Index; Panel Data Analysis; Fertility; Time Preferences; Citizen
Ideology; Sorokin Thesis;
JEL Code: K36, K42, K49
*corresponding author.
Disclosures:
-The authors have no relevant financial or non-financial interests to disclose.
-The authors did not receive support from any organization for the submitted work.
-This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the
authors.
- The data supporting this study's findings are available from the corresponding author, FB, upon
reasonable request.
--All authors have equally contributed to this paper.
1
Sexual Freedom, Fertility, and Time Preferences: Panel Data Analysis from 1960 to 2010
Abstract:
Standard economic theory offers a demand-and-supply view of fertility. With increasing
economic development, higher income levels, dropping mortality rates, and increases in
education levels resulting in increased female labor force participation, there is a decreased
demand for children. These determinants of fertility could also be seen as ‘backward-looking’
determinants since they deal with variables that have already happened to the person. Another
theory for explaining decreased fertility could be the time preference theory, which is a ‘forward-
looking’ variable based on a person’s future expectations (Bellani et al., 2021). Sexual freedom
is seen as a measure of time preference (Banfield 1974) and is expected to affect fertility
(Sorokin, 1956). For this reason, we will study the impact of increasing sexual freedom on
fertility, controlling for various state-level characteristics. To control for endogeneity between
fertility and other explanatory variables, we will use fixed effects instrumental variable
estimation.
2
1. Introduction
Standard economic theory offers a demand-and-supply view of fertility. With increasing
economic development, higher income levels, dropping mortality rates, and increases in
education levels resulting in increased female labor force participation, there is a decreased
demand for children. This results in a reduced fertility rate. These determinants of fertility could
also be seen as ‘backward-looking’ determinants since they deal with variables that have already
happened to the person. Another theory for explaining decreased fertility could be the theory of
between income or wages and fertility (Jones et al., 2010), the relationship between the fertility
of successive generations (Murphy & Wang, 2001), the relationship between the later onset of
adult activities and its implications for fertility and also economic opportunities (Billari &
Tabellini, 2010), the impact of having children vs. being childless on having future children
(Dommermuth et al., 2015), the relationship between status (education, class, rank, etc.) on
fertility (Skirbekk, 2008), the impact of different types of debt levels on fertility (Nau et al.,
Further, the naturalist theories of fertility come into three categories. The first category
theorizes that reduced fertility is because of the change in the environment, i.e., our modern
industrial environment is different than the primitive environment of our forebears. The second
theory is a substitution theory that in the current environment parents invest more in their
children and hence they produce fewer kids, a tradeoff between quantity and quality. The final
theory is focused on cultural evolution resulting from an arms race. When influential people
3
adopt a trait, others rush to copy it. In this case, getting and valuing more education results in the
reduction of mortality (increased survivability) and fertility, which then gets transmitted to others
momentum built in fertility as past fertility affects present fertility. On the other hand, fertility
decisions are also forward-looking since a decision to have a child impacts many future
decisions. Hence time preferences play a role in fertility. Time Preference is a psychological
concept that suggests that people, when all other factors are equal, generally prefer to achieve a
particular outcome sooner rather than later. This preference can be seen as a reflection of an
People with High Time Preferences (high discount rates) are often characterized as those
who live in the moment. They are typically impulsive and impatient, preferring immediate
satisfaction over delayed rewards (Peters & Büchel, 2011). On the other hand, individuals with
Low Time Preferences (low discount rates) are those who can delay gratification and plan for the
future. They are often seen as patient and strategic, willing to forgo immediate satisfaction in
When tying time preferences to fertility, a person with high time preference might make
hazardous choices, choose a poor partner, and hence might be viewed by their partners as
inadequate parents and hence not have children. Further, having children would be seen as
having immediate costs both in terms of time and money, hence discouraging having children
(Folbre, 2008). Low time preferences individuals take more time to search for a life partner,
seek a good job, then seek to have children. Further, they will be concerned about long-term
costs and benefits instead of short-term net benefits. These long-term benefits could be for
4
example, a child’s support to one’s parents as one gets older (Dykstra & Fokkema, 2011). This
line of reasoning would suggest that higher time preference would mean less fertility and lower
and attachment (Hill, 1988), high time preference individuals might desire to have children right
away resulting in for example teenage pregnancy (Golsteyn et al., 2014). Those with low time
preferences could wait for the perfect job, the perfect partner, and procrastinate having children
resulting in the inability to have children due to the reproductive opportunity window closing.
Additionally, their long-term calculation with awareness of the increasing costs of having
children (Craig et al., 2014) might hinder them from having children. This would suggest that
higher time preference means more fertility and lower time preference individuals have lower
fertility. Because of these two possible pathways, the relationship between time preferences and
Pitirim Sorokin, the founder of the sociology department at Harvard University, in his
book “The American Sex Revolution” has suggested that societies that increase sexual freedom
or “sexual anarchy” experience various social ills including lower fertility rates. He finds
support for his hypothesis after surveying several cultures (e.g., Rome and Greece) and royal
families. “As a rule, communities preoccupied by the hunt for promiscuous sex pleasure are
little, if at all, about having children, for they are obstacles to the full enjoyment of libertinism.
This viewpoint prompts sex devotees to resort to contraceptives, abortions, and other means for
preventing childbirth” (Sorokin, 1956, pp. 78-79). Even if people in these cultures marry, their
marriages are either childless or produce one or two children resulting in the “voluntary suicide”
of the society.
5
In this paper, we introduce a new index of sexual freedom. This unique dataset tracks
laws that allow for sexual relationships beyond that of a man and woman in marriage as the only
legal sexual arrangement. The data spans 51 years from 1960 to 2010 for all 50 states of the
United States (U.S.). Historically, in the U.S. both family law and criminal law have supported
limiting sexual activity to the realm of marriage (Murray, 2009) but this has changed over the
last few decades. Our goal in this paper is to study the impact of sexual freedom on fertility rates
(Sorokin’s thesis) using the novel dataset and show the link with the time preference literature on
fertility.
Section 2 discusses the issue of time preferences and their relation to sexual freedom.
Section 3 details the data collection process, section 4 provides our empirical strategy, section 5
fertility decisions. Various factors affect people’s time preferences. They include “external,
biological, personal, and social or institutional ones” (Hoppe, 2001, p. 3). Biological factors
include just the aging process. When one is a child, one will have high time preferences, and this
tends to decline as one ages and increases as one nears death. External factors affecting time
preference include “property-right security, physical security generally, and observed behavior of
Religion also affects time preferences. Max Weber noted Calvinism encourages low
time preferences. “When the limitation of consumption is combined with this release of
acquisitive activity, the inevitable practical result is obvious: accumulation of capital through
6
ascetic compulsion to save. The restraints which were imposed upon the consumption of wealth
naturally served to increase it by making possible the productive investment of capital… the
greater simplicity of life in the more seriously religious circles, in combination with great wealth,
groups/sects like messianic and millenarian sects can encourage high time preferences as they
Time preferences affect social and economic outcomes. Even measuring discount rates
of individuals when they are teenagers can be used to predict the future in terms of “school
performance, health, labour supply and lifetime income” (Golsteyn et al., 2014). The further in
the future one goes, the discrepancy caused by different discount rates is more obvious. The
Moreover, those with high discount rates (high time preference) correlate with sexual behaviors
and outcomes related to sexual health. These include instances of engaging in sexual activity, the
onset of sexual activity at an earlier age, and teenage pregnancy (Chesson et al., 2006). Even at
the macro-level, a paper finds that countries that exhibit more patience (more future-oriented) are
Time preferences are related to the issue of self-control. Hence the lack of self-control
“can manifest itself in many ways, including elevated emotional lability [sic], tendency to fly off
the handle, low tolerance for frustration, lack of persistence, short attention span, high
distractibility, frequent shifting from activity to activity, being restless, being overactive, acting
before thinking, having problems waiting for something good, and having difficulty taking turns”
which impacts one's actions in the sexual marketplace resulting in unsafe sex (Belsky et al.,
2020).
7
In the sexual marketplace, the notion of time preference also applies. Banfield writes
that the “lower classes” (those with high time preferences) have no sense of the future. A higher
time preference individual considers his “bodily needs (especially for sex)…take precedence
over everything else—certainly over any work routine” (1974, p. 61). Further, future-oriented
(lower time preference) cultures teach “the individual that he would be cheating himself if he
allowed gratification of his impulses (for example, for sex or violence) to interfere with his
Some empirical work regarding sexual freedom has been completed. One study has
found that when men see pretty women, they discount the future more as it has to do with mating
opportunities (Wilson & Daly, 2004). However, it is not clear whether showing cues of pretty
women changes underlying time preferences, i.e., do men want to copulate now or are they
willing to wait till say marriage to consummate the relationship? Two Papers (Bose, 2015; Bose
& Jacob, 2018) use the Sexual Freedom Index for a shorter time frame of 21 years to determine
the factors that determine sexual freedom and one key finding is that citizen ideology has a
The psychology literature shows that citizen ideology is tied to time preferences. Right
ideology shows greater self-control than the left i.e., those on the right have lower time
preferences. These seem to be mediated by the role freewill beliefs play for the individual.
However, in some instances, those on the left can use external factors to display self-control and
achieve results (Clarkson et al., 2015). Left-wing political ideology is also a predictor in crime,
which indicates high time preference. This could be due to the left’s openness to new and
exciting experiences. In contrast, those on the right prefer law and order and respect for authority
(Wright et al., 2017). Adventurous and risky sexual activity, including the use of toys and one-
8
night stands, is strongly correlated with left-wing political ideology, while right-leaning ideology
tends to report engaging in a narrower and more traditional scope of sexual activity (missionary
position and romantic kissing) (Hatemi et al., 2017). This ties in with Sorokin’s thesis, that
sexually free societies will be made up of high time preference individuals, which will then
Bose and Van Duyn (2020) analyze party platforms for 22 OECD countries and find that
right parties tended to emphasize more economic freedom vs. sexual freedom when compared to
left parties. They hypothesize that these differences between the parties are because the left
parties attract people with higher time preferences whereas the right parties attract individuals
Becker and Mulligan also try to understand how people might be able to change their
time preferences. They suggest that an individual can change their time preferences by spending
time and effort appreciating future pleasures (1997, p. 734). Education is one method of
children learn the art of scenario simulation. Thus, educated people should be more productive at
In this paper, we study the impact of increasing sexual freedom and citizen ideology on
fertility in the United States using state-level panel data from 1950-2010. We will use fixed
effects instrumental variable estimation to control for endogeneity between fertility and other
explanatory variables.
To our knowledge, this is the first study investigating Sorokin’s thesis, in which we
investigate the impact of sexual freedom on fertility in the U.S. at the state level.
9
3. Data
Our variables have been collected from 1960 to 2010 at the state level for all 50 states.
One of the challenges in historical data collection is dealing with missing data and ensuring the
quality of the available data. We addressed these issues as best as possible, but challenges
continue to remain.
fornication, pimp laws, prostitution laws, age of consent, adultery, homosexual marriage and its
recognition, polygamy, divorce, cohabitation, miscegenation, and marrying close blood. Each
variable/law was coded on a four-point scale (0, 1, 2, 3). A value of 0 reflects the lowest
possible amount of freedom or the most regulation, and a three represents the greatest amount of
freedom or no regulation. We use a similar coding method as found in Bose’s paper (2021).
The citizen ideology measure comes from Richard Fording’s website1. The citizen
ideology is the ‘revised 1960-2010 citizen ideology series’ (Berry et al., 1998). The larger the
number, the more leftist/liberal the active electorate of the state. We did not use the state
government ideology measure of Berry et al., (2010) as it measures the ideal points of the state’s
congressional delegation and not the state government directly. Instead, we use the modified
Ranney Index. The modified Ranney index is an index that averages percent Democrats in the
House and Senate, and the percentage of votes for the Democrat’s gubernatorial candidate,
accounting further for whether they have control of all three institutions of governance (house,
senate, and governor’s office) in the state. The Ranney Index formula is below. We obtained the
1
http://rcfording.wordpress.com/state-ideology-data/ (accessed June 1, 2013).
10
data to create the Ranney Index from Klarner (2013) and used current-year information instead
Ranney Index = [(Percent Vote for Democrat’s Candidate for Governor) + (Percent
Democrats in House) + (Percent Democrats in Senate) + (Control Variable)] / 4 (1)
Control Variable: If democrats control house, senate, and governorship: = 1 (100%),
Otherwise = 0 (0%). If democrats have control of only some branches: = .5 (50%)
A Ranney Index closer to 1 indicates full Democrat control of the state, whereas, a
number closer to 0 indicates Republican control. Per the party platform literature, full Democrat
control indicates that the voters in the state have high time preferences, as the party platform of
the state Democrat party would be focused on sexual liberty and other high time preference
Other state variables include real gross state product per capita and shares of Catholics,
and protestants in the state’s population. This data comes from the Association of Religion Data
Archives2. We also include the share of whites in the total population to control for the effect of
race on fertility. Tables 1 and 2 show the summary statistics and the correlation coefficients
respectively.
2
Thearda.com (accessed October 1, 2013).
11
Table 2: Correlation Coefficients
Log
General Sexual GSP
Fertility Freedom Citizen Ranney per % of % of % of
Rate Index Ideology Index capita Catholics Protestants whites
General Fertility Rate 1
Sexual Freedom Index -0.014 1.000
Citizen Ideology -0.429 0.215 1.000
Ranney Index -0.141 -0.066 0.174 1.000
Log GSP per capita -0.003 0.209 0.047 -0.175 1.000
% of catholic -0.265 0.109 0.630 -0.042 0.068 1.000
% of protestants -0.218 -0.041 0.085 -0.143 -0.263 -0.015 1.000
% of whites -0.200 -0.171 0.015 -0.399 -0.319 0.106 0.390 1.000
(Lucas, 2018; Mosley, 2006). The crude birth rate is the only data that goes back to 1960. The
crude birth rate is an estimate of fertility defined as the number of live births per 1000 total
population in a given year. It is not good for comparing fertility across populations, as variations
𝑁𝑢𝑚𝑏𝑒𝑟 𝑜𝑓 𝐵𝑖𝑟𝑡ℎ𝑠/𝑌𝑒𝑎𝑟
Crude Birth Rate=. × 1000
𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑀𝑖𝑑−𝑦𝑒𝑎𝑟 𝑃𝑜𝑝𝑢𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛
Only a “crude” estimate of fertility, all of the population included in the denominator is
The general fertility rate is of higher quality measure as it is the number of live births per
1000 women ages 15-49 within a given year. It is approximately 4 times the crude birth rate. It
also allows for better comparison across populations. The data for the general fertility rate was
𝑁𝑢𝑚𝑏𝑒𝑟 𝑜𝑓 𝐵𝑖𝑟𝑡ℎ𝑠/𝑌𝑒𝑎𝑟
General Fertility Rate= 𝑁𝑢𝑚𝑏𝑒𝑟 𝑜𝑓 𝑤𝑜𝑚𝑒𝑛 𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑠 15 𝑡𝑜 49 × 1000
12
The total fertility rate is the best single measure of fertility across populations. It is the
expected births to a woman by the time she ended childbearing if she were to pass through all her
childbearing years conforming to the age-specific fertility rates of a given year. Five is the width
of the age group interval. This data was available from 1990. All variables are averaged over
five-year periods.
4. Model
In this paper, we study the effect of the sexual freedom index, citizen ideology, and
government ideology (as measured by the Ranney Index) on fertility across the fifty states in the
US. We begin our analysis by examining this issue using static panel data models.
where gfrit is the general fertility rate for state i at time period t, sfiit is the index of state i’s
sexual freedom, X 1it is the set of state ideology variables and X 2 it is the set of other state
control variables i is a state-specific fixed effect, and it is the idiosyncratic error term. We
begin by reporting random and fixed effects models. One potential problem in the estimation of
(1) is that several of the right-side variables could be endogenous. For example, not only could
ideology and SFI variables affect fertility, but be in turn determined by it. This is especially true
in a panel data context where people may move in and out of states based on their attitudes
toward these issues. Typically, endogeneity in the model can be addressed by finding external
instruments. Finding appropriate instruments for the endogenous variables in our context is very
difficult. One alternative to external instruments is to employ internal instruments from the
model. One such approach is suggested by Lewbel (1997) which exploits the curvature of the
13
variable by using as instruments different orders of centered moments of the endogenous
variable (i.e., the deviation of the variable from its global mean, raised to the power two, three,
As a robustness check, we also estimate our model using a dynamic panel data approach
which allows for general fertility rates to be influenced by past periods' values. The estimating
equation is:
Where gfrit −1 is the past period’s fertility rate. The problem of endogeneity of the
explanatory variables can easily be addressed in a dynamic panel data context as well, where
The standard approach is to estimate the models like the ones in equation 2 in the first
differences thus eliminating the individual fixed effects. Specifically, the estimating model thus
becomes:
The problem in estimating Eq. (3) is the endogeneity introduced by the lag-dependent variable
Eakin et al., (1988) and Arellano and Bond (1991) addresses this issue by using two periods or
more lags of the dependent variable as instruments for the differenced lagged dependent variable
since
14
Blundell and Bond (1998) show that this difference estimator may not perform well when there
is persistence in the lagged dependent variable and demonstrate at the systems GMM estimator,
initially proposed by Arellano and Bover (1995), may be better suited. The systems GMM
estimator is based on the idea that additional moment conditions can be introduced by adding a
level equation to the differenced equation and using lagged differences of the explanatory
variables as instruments for the level equation since E[i,t ( yi,t −1 − yi,t −2 )] = 0, for t = 3, 4...T .
To avoid the problem of instrument proliferation, which can overfit the model, we use a
collapsed instrument set as developed by Roodman (2009). Two-step dynamic panel data models
can result in inefficient standard errors in finite samples. We report bias-corrected robust
5. Analysis
Table 3 reports the base model examining the association between the general fertility
rate and the time preference variables measured by the Sexual Freedom Index (SFI) and the two
ideology variables- Citizen’s ideology and Ranney Index. In all our tables, we begin by reporting
random and fixed effects models. As noted in the previous section, our model can potentially
suffer from simultaneity bias. In column 3, we instrument the independent variables by their first
and second lag values. This approach is done as it is very hard to find external instruments for
these variables. Finally, in column 4, we allow for both endogeneity as well as the dynamic
nature of the determination of fertility by including its lag value as an additional explanatory
variable. This model is estimated using Arrelano-Bond two-step systems estimator. We also
provide various diagnostic tests for IV and dynamic panel data estimators, showing the
appropriateness of the instrument set and model choice. In all our models, we allow for a non-
15
linear relationship between SFI and fertility by including a linear as well as the quadratic term of
the former.
We start by reporting results from a random effects model. The linear term of SFI is
negative while the square term is positive and significant. This indicates that there is a non-linear
association between SFI and fertility. Increased SFI is associated with a reduction in fertility rate.
Citizen ideology is also negative and significant. Since citizen ideology and SFI are considered
to capture the rate of time preference, this result agrees with our general hypothesis. Ranney
Index has a statistically significant and positive effect on fertility. Random effects models,
16
however, assume that there is no correlation between the state-fixed effects and other state-level
independent variables. The fixed effect model, which relaxes this assumption indicates that SFI
continues to have a negative and non-linear association with fertility, while Ranney Index is
significant. Our main results are in column 3, where we allow for endogeneity of SFI and the
two ideology variables. Citizen Ideology is again not statistically significant. However, SFI
continues to exert a negative effect on fertility, confirming our initial hypothesis. Further, a
higher Ranney Index value suggests that more Democrat control of the state also shows a higher
fertility rate.
In column 4, we estimate a dynamic panel data model. We find that there is positive
feedback of past periods' fertility rates on the current period’s fertility rates. None of the
measures of time preference are significant. Ranney Index is positive and significant.
Table 4: Effect of SFI and ideology on General Fertility Rate, inclusion of state income
(1) (2) (3) (4) (7)
AB
Dependent Var: Gen. Random Fixed Fixed Effects Systems AB Diff
Fertility Rate Efects Effects IV Estimator± Estimator±
17
Observations 241 241 239 192
Number of stid 48 48 48 48
Robust standard errors in parentheses
±: Windmeijer bias correct robust standard errors reported
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
In Table 4, we include a state-level income measure, a log of gross state product per
capita. In column 1, SFI and Citizen’s Ideology continue to be negative and significant while is
negative and significant. In our main specification reported in column 3, while the two ideology
variables are not significant, SFI continues to have a non-linear and negative impact on fertility
rates. Increasing levels of state economic development are also associated with lowering fertility
rates. In the dynamic panel data specification, however, while the effect of SFI and Income
significant. The magnitude of the lagged fertility variable continues to be rather small. As an
alternative specification, we estimate the dynamic model with Arellano Bond Difference GMM
model. These results are in column 5. The estimate of the lagged fertility term is no longer
significant. This suggests that a static specification of the model given by Equation 1 may be
more appropriate.
race variables in our static panel data estimation. Due to the quality of the data, we only included
the majority groups, shares of Catholics, Protestants, and whites in the state population. Results
are presented in Table 5. SFI continues to have a negative and non-linear effect on fertility, while
Citizen Ideology is only significant in the random effects estimation (column 1). Taken together,
our results seems to confirm Sorokin’s thesis that increasing sexual freedom may result in lower
fertility rates and these results are robust to the inclusion of race and religion variables as well as
after allowing for endogeneity of ideology and SFI variables. In addition, state economic
18
development, measured by per capita income is also associated with lowering fertility rates. The
two ideology variables, as well as race and religion controls, are not statistically significant when
6. Conclusion
Most studies on fertility use individual-level data. Using aggregate data at the state level
comes with numerous data constraints including the reality that laws about sexual freedom lag
social norms. One persistent result is that citizen ideology negatively impacts the general
fertility rate providing evidence that time preferences play a role in fertility i.e., higher time
19
preference states have less fertility. Our main specification reveals that the SFI is negative and
statistically significant, supporting Sorokin’s thesis that sexual anarchy/freedom leads to lower
fertility. Additionally, our tests for non-linearity, represented by the SFI², show that it is positive
and significant. This indicates that while initial increases in sexual freedom may reduce fertility,
beyond a certain point, further increases might have a different impact. This finding aligns with
studies using individual-level data, suggesting a more complex relationship between sexual
Further empirical research could benefit from improved data, such as a more precise
fertility measure rather than the crude birth rate. The teen fertility rate is another important
variable, but it is only available annually for a limited number of years. Urbanization is another
key variable of interest, but its definition has evolved, and data is only available for specific
years. Similarly, the education variable is only accessible for more recent decades. These two
variables might be proxied by our GSP data. The Ranney Index shows no significance in our
main specification.
20
Referencesa
Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an
application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277-297.
https://doi.org/10.2307/2297968
Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-
components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 29-51. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-
4076(94)01642-D
Banfield, E. C. (1974). The unheavenly city revisted. Little, Brown and Company.
Becker, G. S., & Mulligan, C. B. (1997). The endogenous determination of time preference. The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 112(3), 729-758.
Bellani, D., Arpino, B., & Vignoli, D. (2021). Time preferences and fertility: Evidence from Italy.
Demographic Research, 44, 1185-1228. https://doi.org/10.4054/DemRes.2021.44.50
Belsky, J., Caspi, A., Moffitt, T. E., & Poulton, R. (2020). The origins of you: How childhood shapes later life.
Harvard University Press.
Berry, W. D., Fording, R. C., Ringquist, E. J., Hanson, R. L., & Klarner, C. E. (2010). Measuring citizen and
government ideology in the U.S. states: A re-appraisal. State Politics & Policy Quarterly, 10(2),
117-135. https://doi.org/10.1177/153244001001000201
Berry, W. D., Ringquist, E. J., Fording, R. C., & Hanson, R. L. (1998). Measuring citizen and government
ideology in the American states, 1960-93. American Journal of Political Science, 42(1), 327-348.
https://doi.org/10.2307/2991759
Billari, F. C., & Tabellini, G. (2010). Italians are late: Does it matter? In J. B. Shoven (Ed.), Demography and
the Economy. University of Chicago Press, NBER books.
Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models.
Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115-143. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8
Bose, F. (2015). The determinants of sexual freedom from 1990 to 2010. Applied Economics Letters, 1-6.
https://doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2015.1021449
Bose, F. (2021). Policy innovativeness and sexual freedom. Social Science Quarterly, 102(4), 1496-1510.
https://doi.org/10.1111/ssqu.12984
Bose, F., & Jacob, J. A. (2018). Changing sexual regulations in the U.S. from 1990 to 2010: Spatial panel
data analysis. Review of Economics and Institutions, 9(1), 1-18.
https://doi.org/10.5202/rei.v9i1.21418
Bose, F., & Van Duyn, Z. (2020). Time preferences as partisan politics: what do party manifestos show in
twenty-two OECD countries? European Politics and Society, 1-16.
https://doi.org/10.1080/23745118.2020.1847571
Chesson, H. W., Leichliter, J. S., Zimet, G. D., Rosenthal, S. L., Bernstein, D. I., & Fife, K. H. (2006). Discount
rates and risky sexual behaviors among teenagers and young adults. Journal of Risk and
Uncertainty, 32(3), 217-230. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-006-9520-1
Clarkson, J. J., Chambers, J. R., Hirt, E. R., Otto, A. S., Kardes, F. R., & Leone, C. (2015). The self-control
consequences of political ideology. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 112(27),
8250-8253. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1503530112
Craig, L., Powell, A., & Smyth, C. (2014). Towards intensive parenting? Changes in the composition and
determinants of mothers' and fathers' time with children 1992–2006. The British Journal of
Sociology, 65(3), 555-579. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-4446.12035
Dommermuth, L., Klobas, J., & Lappegård, T. (2015). Realization of fertility intentions by different time
frames. Advances in Life Course Research, 24, 34-46. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.alcr.2015.02.001
Dykstra, P. A., & Fokkema, T. (2011). Relationships between parents and their adult children: a West
European typology of late-life families. Ageing and Society, 31(4), 545-569.
https://doi.org/10.1017/S0144686X10001108
21
Folbre, N. (2008). Valuing children: Rethinking the economics of the family. Harvard University Press.
https://doi.org/10.2307/j.ctvjnrt57
Golsteyn, B. H. H., Grönqvist, H., & Lindahl, L. (2014). Adolescent time preferences predict lifetime
outcomes. The Economic Journal, 124(580), F739-F761. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecoj.12095
Hatemi, P. K., Crabtree, C., & McDermott, R. (2017). The relationship between sexual preferences and
political orientations: Do positions in the bedroom affect positions in the ballot box? Personality
and Individual Differences, 105, 318-325. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.paid.2016.10.008
Hill, M. S. (1988). Marital stability and spouses' shared Time: A multidisciplinary hypothesis. Journal of
Family Issues, 9(4), 427-451. https://doi.org/10.1177/019251388009004001
Holtz-Eakin, D., Newey, W., & Rosen, H. S. (1988). Estimating vector autoregressions with panel data.
Econometrica, 56(6), 1371-1395. https://doi.org/10.2307/1913103
Hoppe, H.-H. (2001). Democracy: The God that failed. Transaction Publishers.
Jones, L. E., Schoonbroodt, A., & Tertilt, M. (2010). Fertility theories: Can they explain the negative fertility-
income relationship? In J. B. Shoven (Ed.), Demography and the Economy. University of Chicago
press, NBER Research.
Klarner, C. (2013). Other Scholars’ Competitiveness Measures https://doi.org/hdl/1902.1/22519
Lewbel, A. (1997). Constructing instruments for regressions with measurement error when no additional
data are available, with an application to patents and R&D. Econometrica, 65(5), 1201-1213.
https://doi.org/10.2307/2171884
Lucas, C. (2018). Fertility: Concepts and measures https://slideplayer.com/slide/12257487/, US Census
and USAID.
Mosley, H. (2006). Fertility and reproduction: Data sources and crude indicators of fertility
http://ocw.jhsph.edu/courses/PopulationChange/PDFs/Lecture4.pdf, Johns Hopkins Bloomberg
School of Public Health.
Mulligan, R. F. (2008). Religion as adaptation: The role of time preference In W. R. Levin (Ed.), Political
Economy Research focus (pp. 69-92). Nova Science Publishers, Inc.
Murphy, M., & Wang, D. (2001). Family-Level continuities in childbearing in low-fertility societies.
European Journal of Population, 17(1), 75-96. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1010744314362
Murray, M. (2009). Strange bedfellows: Criminal law, family law and the legal construction of intimate life.
Iowa Law Review, 94, 1253-1313.
Nau, M., Dwyer, R. E., & Hodson, R. (2015). Can't afford a baby? Debt and young Americans. Research in
social stratification and mobility, 42, 114-122. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rssm.2015.05.003
Peters, J., & Büchel, C. (2011). The neural mechanisms of inter-temporal decision-making: understanding
variability. Trends in cognitive sciences, 15(5), 227-239.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tics.2011.03.002
Roodman, D. (2009). A note on the theme of too many instruments*. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
Statistics, 71(1), 135-158. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.2008.00542.x
Skirbekk, V. (2008). Fertility trends by social status. Demographic Research, 18(5), 145-180.
https://doi.org/10.4054/DemRes.2008.18.5
Sorokin, P. A. (1956). The American sex revolution. Porter Sargent Publisher.
Sunde, U., Dohmen, T., Enke, B., Falk, A., Huffman, D., & Meyerheim, G. (2021). Patience and comparative
development. The Review of Economic Studies, 89(5), 2806-2840.
https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdab084
Weber, M. (1930 ). The protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism (T. Parsons, Trans.). Charles Scribner's
Sons. (1905)
Wilson, M., & Daly, M. (2004). Do pretty women inspire men to discount the future? Proceedings of the
Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences, 271(Suppl 4), S177-S179.
https://doi.org/10.1098/rsbl.2003.0134
22
Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM
estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126(1), 25-51.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.005
Wodarz, D., Stipp, S., Hirshleifer, D., & Komarova, N. L. (2020). Evolutionary dynamics of culturally
transmitted, fertility-reducing traits. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences,
287(1925), 1-10. https://doi.org/doi:10.1098/rspb.2019.2468
Wright, J. P., Beaver, K. M., Morgan, M. A., & Connolly, E. J. (2017). Political ideology predicts involvement
in crime. Personality and Individual Differences, 106, 236-241.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.paid.2016.10.062
23
Biographies
Feler Bose is a professor of economics and finance at Indiana University East in Richmond, Indiana. His
research spans applied microeconomics, political economy, law and economics, and the economics of
religion. He is the author of the book “Sexual Freedom and Its Impact on Economic Growth and
Prosperity.”
Jeffry Jacob is a Professor of Economics at Bethel University in St. Paul, Minnesota. He teaches a variety
of courses in economics, machine learning, and data analytics. Over the past decade, he has conducted
research examining the role of institutions in economic development. His articles have appeared in
journals such as International Review of Economics, Singapore Economic Review, Regulation and
Governance.
24