The Politics of Disciplining Water Right
The Politics of Disciplining Water Right
Rutgerd Boelens
ABSTRACT
This article examines how the legal systems of Andean countries have dealt
with the region’s huge plurality of local water rights, and how official poli-
cies to ‘recognize’ local rights and identities harbour increasingly subtle
politics of codification, confinement and disciplining. The autonomy and
diversity of local water rights are a major hindrance for water companies,
elites and formal rule-enforcers, since State and market institutions require
a predictable, uniform playing field. Complex local rights orders are seen
as irrational, ill-defined and disordered. Officialdom cannot simply ignore
or oppress the ‘unruliness and disobedience’ of local rights systems: rather
it ‘incorporates’ local normative orders that have the capacity to adequately
respond to context-based needs. This article examines a number of evolving,
overlapping legal domination strategies, such as the ‘marrying’ of local and
official legal systems in ways that do not challenge the legal and power hier-
archy; and reviews the ways in which official regulation and legal strategies
deny or take into consideration local water rights repertoires, and the politics
of recognition that these entail. Post-colonial recognition policies are not
simply responses to demands by subjugated groups for greater autonomy.
Rather, they facilitate the water bureaucracy’s political control and help ne-
oliberal sectors to incorporate local water users’ rights and organizations into
the market system — even though many communities refuse to accept these
policies of recognition and politics of containment.
INTRODUCTION
‘The colonialist specialists do not recognize that the culture has changed and they hasten to
support the traditions of the indigenous society. It is the colonialists who have become the
defenders of the native lifestyle’ (Frantz Fanon, The Wretched of the Earth, 1961).
The huge diversity of existing water rights and the dynamic features of
local water control systems constitute a fundamental problem for law and
policy makers, water resource planners and commercial water industries.
In general, State and market institutions require a well established, uniform
playing field. Local water rights systems are not just incomprehensible and
I thank Margreet Zwarteveen, Hans Achterhuis, Jan Douwe van der Ploeg, Armando Guevara,
Patricia Urteaga, Irit Eguavoen, Peter Mollinga, Francis Cleaver, Jan Hendriks, Flip Wester,
Edwin Rap and the anonymous reviewers of this journal for their insightful contributions to
earlier versions of this paper.
As things stand, the creation of one integrated property system in non-Western nations is
impossible. Extralegal property arrangements are dispersed among dozens, sometimes hun-
dreds, of communities; rights and other information are known only to insiders or neighbours.
All the separate, loose extralegal property arrangements characteristic of most Third World
and former communist nations must be woven into a single system from which general
principles of law can be drawn. (De Soto, 2000: 162)
1. To delimit the contents, this article deals with the tenets of legal strategies to discipline
water rights. I refer to the academic series Agua y Sociedad – WALIR for the analysis
of other domains of Andean water rights contestation (www.iep.org.pe). Neither does the
paper deal with the contents and mechanisms of Andean water rights (see e.g., Boelens
and Hoogendam, 2002; Roth et al., 2005); or resistance strategies by Andean communities
(e.g., Bennett et al., 2005; Boelens and Gelles, 2005; Gelles, 2000).
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 309
These words, which provide the background against which I will for-
mulate my analysis and critique, are not new and are embedded in a long
history of liberal policy efforts in the region. These days, however, they
form part of a new neoliberal policy wave of participatory, inclusive power
strategies that ‘recognize the local and extralegal’. Recognition policies get
increasingly subtle. As I will show, unlike their liberal forerunners, socialist
opponents and most of their contemporary neoliberal colleagues, these new
neoliberal policy makers do not see local law as irrational. In that sense,
unlike most mainstream law and policy makers in water affairs who used to
(and continue to) simply deny local property constructs, they — with their
plea for profoundly understanding the manifestations of extralegal complex-
ity — are analytically far more ‘advanced’ and politically far more subtle
and problematic for collective rights systems in the Andes.
I say ‘problematic’, because the standpoint I take in this article is situated
(Haraway, 1991). It looks at how the continuity of Andean collective wa-
ter rights repertoires is threatened, thereby endangering the self-sustained
reproduction of the water management collectives themselves. This ‘situat-
edness’ is political in a sense that it concentrates on the position of those user
groups in the Andean water world who find social and political-economic
shelter and livelihood security within collective water rights systems. Such
collectives are complex, multi-layered entities whose members, although
differentiated by class, gender, status and often by ethnicity, try to construct
and re-affirm social, territorial and water resource bonds because of mutual
dependence: the continuation and improvement of their livelihoods requires
shared institutions for collective action to defend and control their individual
and common water resources.
The article is based on action-research with the WALIR Water Law and
Indigenous Rights programme in the Andean countries, analysing local wa-
ter rights, norms and practices and their discrimination or undermining by
official water legislation and policies. Desk studies and field work were con-
ducted in the period 2001–07, with water users’ organizations, peasant and
indigenous federations2 and civil society water platforms in Peru, Bolivia,
Ecuador and Chile (comparative country cases: Mexico and the USA).
The article concentrates on modern (that is, post-colonial) forms of rights’
disciplining, all of which, in different ways, are based on liberal inclusive,
equality ideologies. It does not focus on the ancient (but continuing) forms
of domination and disciplining based on inequality, segregation and exclu-
sion, which in everyday practice complement the modern efforts (as strategic
twins). The following section analyses the centralized, ‘equalizing’ policies
and legal systems of Andean countries, which monopolize rule-making ‘for
Local water rights, organizational norms and operational rules in the Andean
region are not only dynamic, extremely diverse, puzzlingly intertwined and
even mutually contradictory; often they also stand in clear contradiction to
national legislation (Cremers et al., 2005). From a legal point of view this
adds to a lack of clarity and order. However, from local points of view,
the rules of the game are commonly not perceived at all as unclear, unruly
or intangible.3 Context-based socio-legal repertoires link water benefits and
burdens in particular ways. Instead of reflecting general principles of ‘Right-
ness’ or positivist Justice, they correspond to diverse spheres and layers of
social justice as negotiated and constructed over time in place-specific set-
tings and power contexts: the local conceptions of fairness or equity. Unlike
engineering principles that see equitable rights in terms of water allotment
proportional to landholding and crop water requirements, and unlike the de-
politicized notion of equity that is moulded by the mainstream development
triangle of Equity–Democracy–Sustainability, I use the notion of equity to
refer to location-, time-, and group-specific political constructs of fairness.4
According to the locality, (sub)culture, historical development and position
in prevailing power structures, equity perceptions differ enormously. As
such they cannot be reified or romanticized and constitute a power relation
in themselves.
3. Despite their higher degree of adaptation to agro-physical, historical knowledge and social
community contexts (if compared to policy-driven rights frameworks), I do not argue that
local water rights are intrinsically ‘better’ in terms of equity and democracy.
4. See also von Benda-Beckmann and von Benda-Beckmann (2001); Ingram (2008); Roth
et al. (2005).
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 311
7. Cf. Anderson (1983); Assies (2006); Baud (2003); Gelles (2000); Stavenhagen (2002).
314 Rutgerd Boelens
8. See, for example, Guevara (2006); Hendriks (1998), Mayer (2002); van der Ploeg (2006);
WALIR (2007) Bakker (2007).
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 315
they will be included though training and enhancing legal and institutional
access. There is an assumed need to educate the ‘uneducated’, and raise
consciousness for the ‘unconscious’, in order to include the ‘excluded’.
‘Humanity does not gradually progress from combat to combat until it arrives at universal
reciprocity, where the rule of law finally replaces warfare; humanity installs each of its
violences in a system of rules and thus proceeds from domination to domination’ (Michel
Foucault, 1977: 1351).
third parties. The fact that it is a special law only applicable to (and within)
a special group of the national population (in Chile strongly essentialized)
has left most indigenous claims unanswered (Gentes, 2006). Moreover, the
Indigenous Law has proven to be extremely weak, whenever indigenous
communities had to face the powerful Water and Mining Codes, which are
called upon by the water-owning elites. The Law stresses special protec-
tion of water for indigenous groups but at the same time it establishes that,
in any event, this must not interfere with water rights that have already
been registered pursuant to the Water Code. As Gentes observes, a funda-
mental problem involves the difficulty of protecting collective community
laws in an overall neoliberal framework that destroys collective organiza-
tion and favours individual and private rights. Government agencies and
international trade law assume that indigenous groups must either fit into
the market or count themselves out of the process of globalization (Gentes,
2006).
The flip-side of the recognition question is the well-known danger of
curtailing local autonomy, chaining local rights groups to new strict rules
and boxing them into a generalizing State law system. The dynamics and
multiple manifestations of local water rights systems cannot be codified into
blanket legal terms without jeopardizing their foundations. They refer to a
broad range of diverse ‘living’ rights systems and cultures that constantly
reorganize their rules precisely to maintain their identity, and their capacity
to negotiate and solve problems.
In the Andean region, law makers, policy makers and scholars have long
used different approaches to analyse the issue of peasant communities and
regulate ‘the indigenous question’. As Guevara (2006: 131) observes, ‘at
one extreme are the modernizers, liberals, or progressives, who strive to
change the agrarian reality at any cost, including cultural costs. At the other,
radical indianists, indigenists, and proponents of recovering Andean culture
and technology postulate a romantic environmentalism that places Andean
peoples beyond history and near an autarkic utopia’. These essentialist and
naturalized constructs have often served in official identity politics — to
validate segregationist policies, to justify ethno-nationalism or to legitimize
bio-political mestizaje.9 This is quite similar to the way colonial law, in many
countries, constructed customary rights, invented and officialized traditions
and created a usable past. Simplified institutional models, abstracted from
complexity, have not just denied existing diversity but also transformed the
way to interpret reality.
Essentialization is not just an error but often has a political purpose: the
re-presentation and re-cognition of local water rights and identities refers
to re-interpreting and thus transforming them. ‘Recognize’ literally means
9. They were also (re)appropriated as political tools by the marginalized groups themselves
(see, for example, Baud, 2003; Boelens and Gelles, 2005; Gelles, 2000; van der Ploeg,
2006).
318 Rutgerd Boelens
‘to know and understand reality again’ — here, to reshape the image and
contents according to the needs of the formal ‘recognizers’. In this process of
recognizing, essentialization and objectification fundamentally occur when
complex realities and indefinite categories need to be contained in order
to control them. State or externally endorsed ethnicity, identity and nature
of people’s water rights provide the illusion of the continuity of existing
rights, institutions and practices, which are, however, subject to new contexts
in which power relations are being reinforced or strategically rearranged.
Commonly, Andean countries’ cultural politics thus define water culture
and rights as fixed, reified and aligned to prevailing institutional and power
relations: a crystallization of the presumed physical, political-economic and
psychological boundaries and repertoires of a group, which predetermines
and makes tangible their behaviour. Abandoning uncontrolled dynamics,
diversity, human agency, contingency and local resistance to the domains of
illusion is the implicit political effort.
Thus, clearly, not all uses and customs are denied: some essentialized
local rules and rights are allowed and institutionalized, at the expense of
most others and at the cost of intensifying the repression of more fractious,
defiant and disloyal norms. Legal recognition and the subsequent freezing of
a naturalized socio-legal repertoire impacts both peoples and management
systems that are ‘recognized’ and those that do not have this new legal
backing. The legalization of some is accompanied by the illegalization of
others. This relates to both cultural rights (including water management
rules and norms) and distributive justice (such as water access and use
rights). The example below illustrates how incorporation of some local
water rights (naturalized as traditional rights) has direct implications for the
non-protection of others.
10. The water law in Bolivia is old, dating from 1906, and since then a large number of
proposals have been formulated but without approval. Decrees have changed legal water
matters on an ad hoc or sectoral basis. Five years ago a new Irrigation Law was enacted
(see Perreault, 2006). Since 2006 the Evo Morales government has been working on a new
framework for water law and policies. In Peru and Ecuador, the current water laws were
installed in 1969 and 1972 respectively, during reformist military governments. Since then
they have incorporated a number of (mostly neoliberal and ad hoc decentralization) decrees
(de Vos et al., 2006). The Chilean Water Code was enacted under the military dictatorship
of Pinochet and installed a private property regime with dreadful consequences, especially
for many indı́gena and campesino communities. Since the return to democracy only slight
changes have been made to the legal framework to reverse its problematic impact for poor
user groups and the environment (see, e.g., Boelens et al., 2006; Boelens and Zwarteveen,
2005; Bustamante, 2005; Gentes, 2006; Hendriks, 2006; WALIR, 2007).
11. In the USA, after two centuries of limiting Indian rights geographically and politically in
ever-smaller reservations, white settlers and investors often are the prime advocates of clear
Indian water rights in order to know how far their encroachment practices can go without
overstepping their legal backing: ‘Because investments and property values are undermined
by uncertainty, non-Indians and the western states that tend to support non-Indian interests
have also urged that Indian water rights should be legally determined’ (Getches, 2005: 48).
A secondary effect was the government’s attempt to civilize and contain unruly Indians
by turning them into individual farmers. After dividing up the reservation and individually
allocating the land, the rest of land and water rights could be given to white settlers (cf.
Getches, 2006).
320 Rutgerd Boelens
The experiences in Chile, Peru and Ecuador show that the issue of how
to codify, contain and dominate the diversity of local water rights through
recognition policies is a fundamental question. The answers become increas-
ingly subtle and participatory. Interestingly, the decade in which the greatest
wave of official recognition of indigenous and customary rights emerged in
Latin America was the same one in which the neoliberal model was imple-
mented. Strong support was and still is provided by multilateral institutions
and financial lending agencies to the cause of multiculturalism and recog-
nition of diversity. In fact, there is a convergence of interests between the
neoliberal model and certain multicultural currents.
As Assies argues, recognition policies during the past decade in Latin
America have been greatly influenced by a new strategy of ‘managed mul-
ticulturalism’, which celebrates cultural pluralism but fails to materialize
resource redistribution (Assies, 2006). By contrast with transformative ap-
proaches to multiculturalism — which do aim to redistribute power and
resources — this multiculturalism endorsed by State and multilateral agen-
cies reinforces essentialist expressions of group entities. Also in the field
of water control, this policy seeks to standardize cultures and their rights
and procedures. Self-regulation, as Hale observes, comes with clearly ar-
ticulated limits: it ‘attempts to distinguish those rights that are acceptable
from those that are not . . . defining the language of contention; stating which
rights are legitimate; and what forms of political action are appropriate for
achieving them’ (Hale, 2002: 490). For example, as a typical feature of mod-
ern Andean water policies, decentralization of water administration forms
part of the recipe, and ‘participatory’ rights and organizational forms are
rigidly detailed. At the same time, paradoxically, in the neoliberal age of
State downsizing, decentralization is seized upon by central governments to
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 321
12. ‘Gestión Social del Riego’ – Social Management of Irrigation, in Angaraes Sur.
322 Rutgerd Boelens
Paniagua cites the project plan, which states: ‘There is no pre-defined model
and each irrigators’ organization will design their own operation’ (2005: 49).
That said, the Overall Operating Plan argues that, for improving irrigation,
Irrigators Committees must be created and formalized by the Technical Ad-
ministration of the Irrigation District (ATDR) — the government authority
responsible for setting irrigation management norms.
The NGO views it as part of its mission to rationalize irrigation organiza-
tion by including user communities in the formal hierarchy and governmen-
tal structure. Interestingly, the project’s Operating Plan creates the Irrigators
Committee (parallel to the community) before beginning the ‘participatory
assessment’. Moreover, states Paniagua (2005: 49):
This mixes government law and ‘project law’, subtly imposing the latter upon
local norms. In the words of one of the social promoters who was given the
Kafkaesque job of implementing these irrational plans to ‘rationalize local
regulations’: ‘Committees are important, but it is like preparing a medicine
for a disease that you don’t have’ (ibid.: 54).
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 323
‘Once governments know where to look for extralegal representations and get their hands on
them, they have found the Ariadne’s thread leading to the social contract’ (De Soto, 2000:
186)
In the water rights’ normalization process, the State and its hierarchical–legal
apparatus is not the sole, or even most important source of power. Capillary,
bottom-up power mechanisms, particularly, have a much broader range of
action, and many day-to-day normalizing mechanisms not involving the
State or its official institutions may be even more important for sustaining
and reinforcing the State system and class relations than the State institutions
themselves. Nevertheless, it would be a serious miscalculation to omit the
force and functionality of formal structures from any analysis of the water
rights game. The ‘game of the rules’ relates to official rules and rights as
much as to informal ones, and the two are intrinsically connected.
In this sense, structure versus agency debates are often highly misleading.
While legal structures cannot operate by themselves but need the forces in
society that make law work, both legal pluralism and human agency (or
‘actor-oriented’) schools sometimes underestimate the strategic force of of-
ficial structures and formal laws. Others (even Foucault in some texts) have
argued that the ancient, sovereign power of Law has been replaced by the
modern, disciplinary power of the Norm. But, at least in the Andean region
(and probably everywhere), normalizing mechanisms have not replaced for-
mal modalities; rather, they have infiltrated them from below, sometimes
undermining them but also serving as an intermediary between them, and
above all, making it possible to bring the effects to the most distant parts of
the Andean region.13 To a large extent the legal system and other official
power structures have become part of the inclusive power game, particularly
since it adopted an equalizing, liberal ideology. In a Foulcauldian sense,
wherever ‘the law’ is invaded and colonized by ‘the norm’ (normalizing
techniques and discourses), its effectiveness multiplies. Law, rather than
depending just on authoritarian power or the power of one group over an-
other, depends on the way people interact with and constitute each other as
agents and subjects of law. The more the rules are (seemingly or actually)
co-constructed by non-rulers, the greater their normalizing and subjugating
power. In cases such as that of Manyaccla, NGOs and Juntas de Usuarios
actively participate in advancing the uniform rule of state law even more
intensively in those remote places of the Andean highlands where the State
agencies lack access.
13. In his later works Foucault admitted this: ‘the power of the Norm appears through the
disciplines. Is this the new law of modern society? Let us say rather that. . . it has joined
other powers — the Law, the Word and the Text, Tradition — imposing new delimitations
upon them’ (1995: 184).
324 Rutgerd Boelens
In short, State law has continued to exert its dominating power, but unlike
colonial times, no longer as a top-down power modality: its ideology exer-
cises capillary power and invites all Andeans — white, red, black, yellow
or green — to participate ‘under equal terms’. As such it disguises the new
ways of normalizing water control, claiming to improve its effectiveness by
applying presumably objective and non-discriminatory legal codes. Indeed,
similar to Foucault’s argument, the system of law is superimposed upon the
mechanisms of discipline in such a way as to conceal its all-inclusive but
hierarchical procedures.
Despite their strategic interaction, ‘top-down/coercive power’ and ‘cap-
illary/inclusive power’ (or State law and norms-as-a-societal-force) are not
the same, and cannot be reduced to each other. It makes law into a complex
instrument of power, especially since marginalized water user groups and
indı́gena and campesino federations in Andean countries actively strive to
join in this power, and to have their customary rights ‘included’. Hybrid
and even shotgun marriages are the result in the Andean region, commonly
resulting in poor fertility and doubtful offspring in terms of effectiveness for
the subjugated population.
In 2005, even before the country could provide any example of its ac-
tual functionality, Peruvian law enacted the new international fashion of
‘Payment for Environmental Services’, the latest strategy for water rights
commoditization, which entirely neglects existing water rights relationships
in Andean communities (see Isch and Gentes, 2006). It is a characteristic
phenomenon: legislators, universities and NGOs working in the field with
farmer organizations all supported this because they felt ‘they should not
remain behind and needed to be included’. Once the discursive power of
such modernist models has become effective, the ideological function of
law is to naturalize (and make obvious and morally ‘right’) these new water
rights and relations, and to bridge the gap between official norms and local
practices. More than through coercive law making, or rule imposition by the
(many) transnational institutes which actively push for this new policy, the
mechanism is to invade the consciousness of water users and redefine their
normative frames of reference and day-to-day water rules.
As I have argued, the fact that this process requires misunderstanding and
essentialization of local water arrangements should not be disregarded as
simple slip-ups or ‘off-notes’ due to misinformation. It is part of the water
power game in which Andean families, communities and their water rights
are ‘identified’ and reduced to labels. Through institutional and political
alignment, their complexes of unruliness become comprehensible. Water
rights are to be ‘equalized’, and become included and embraced through
capillary power — not necessarily as political effects that are purposely
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 325
14. As indicated at the start, this article concentrates on the (overlapping) mechanisms of water
rights’ disciplining, and will only give slight attention (see below) to the multiple resistance
strategies.
326 Rutgerd Boelens
if the incapable poor and uneducated masses can be convinced: they need
to provide the information on their extralegal arrangements, and on how to
transform and integrate their properties into the formal system. This way,
the State will have ‘the information required to integrate the poor and their
possessions into a legal framework, so that they can finally begin to have a
stake in the capitalist system’ (ibid.: 188). Indeed, it is not just ‘the poor’
who need to be included, but most of all their possessions, their minds and
their hearts.
But how to overcome potential resistance to formalization?15 This is cer-
tainly important, since ‘in Peru, for instance, the government has tried to
formalize property at least twenty-two times in the four hundred years since
Spanish conquest. Their success rate: zero’ (ibid.: 170). Therefore, the afore-
mentioned inclusive power mechanisms are put to work, that seem to ac-
knowledge local institutions but fundamentally recreate them by reifying
some presumed essences, rearranging the political–administrative frame-
work, and transforming the lines of accountability. As a result, the very
heart of local rights is invaded from below, to be absorbed by and codified
in an all-embracing framework. The quest is for an all-encompassing so-
cial contract grounded in a formal property system and built into a political
structure that appears to be anchored in people’s own legal arrangements
but which fundamentally represents the interests of international or Andean
nation-state elites.
Therefore, unlike their mono-legalist liberal or socialist predecessors who
ignored local property systems outright, a modern De Soto policy and law
maker, by contrast, recognizes legal pluralism in line with the above philos-
ophy of managed multiculturalism.16 He or she studies and embraces local
water rights and people’s living law in order, with this information, to incor-
porate these particular rules and rights and subtly squeeze them to death. Or
put euphemistically: ‘Once government obtains this information, it will be
able to explain its intent in a way the poor can understand and relate to. As a
result, they will support the agenda of reform enthusiastically. The poor will
become the most effective public relation machine for reform’ (ibid.: 199).
Indeed, not by force but by ‘educating the uneducated masses’.
What is more, if the ‘unquestionable benefits’ of formal law and the lead-
ers of property reform manage to seduce these common peoples, the latter
15. In De Soto’s analysis resistance is not seen as a broad societal protest against elite-based
control, but as a communication problem caused by: a) the ‘extralegals’ failing to understand
the benefits of uniform rights and popular capitalism; and b) local elites’ stubbornness, since
they benefit from current extralegal arrangements. The first is to be solved by education; the
second by the market itself that ‘encourages law and order, and puts money in the pockets
of the elite’ (2000: 198).
16. De Soto goes further and criticizes lawyers, particularly in the South, for not studying legal
pluralism: ‘The truth is that lawyers in these countries are generally too busy studying
Western law and adapting it. They have been taught that local practices are not genuine law
but a romantic area of study best left to folklorists’ (2000: 187).
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 327
FINAL REFLECTIONS
Andean water control history has made it very clear that this claim of ‘win–
win for all’ does not materialize. Since, according to (neo)liberal ideology,
everybody is fundamentally equal, policies not only tend to disregard eco-
nomic differences (while some cultural differences may be recognized as
encapsulated, harmless and folkloric otherness) but the neoliberal State si-
multaneously refuses to actively balance societal injustice.17 Laws of supply
and demand, sanctioned by State law, become the driving force for water
management. As equals, peasant and indigenous families are supposed to
compete with large-scale farms and transnational companies in this ‘win–
win exercise’.
But Andean water user collectives and peasant-indigenous federations
have learned from the historical power game of intermittent exclusive and
inclusive discourses and, although beyond the scope of this paper, they have
formulated their multiple reactions — from local to international struggles.
At first, they demanded together with socialist-inspired labour unions the
right to equality. However, having unmasked the assimilation thinking based
on whitening and normalizing the anomalous, at a later stage they demanded
the right to be different: to rebuild their identity, not as folklore, but as
a proactive, dynamic construct. In fact, the past two decades have been
characterized by self-reorganization of Andean and indigenous identity. As
a result, they claim both the right to more equal access to resources and the
right to maintain self-sustained differences regarding the contents of their
water normative frameworks.
In their contemporary struggles, claims for recognition and redistribution
necessarily combine (Assies and Gundermann, 2007; Boelens and Gelles,
2005; Dávila and Olazával, 2006; Zwarteveen et al., 2005). Local water
17. Recent attempts by the Bolivian and Ecuadorian government to abolish neoliberal water
policies constitute important test cases. They already face tremendous resistance from
economic power groups.
328 Rutgerd Boelens
REFERENCES
Anderson, B. (1983) Imagined Communities: Reflections on the Origin and Spread of National-
ism. London: Verso.
Assies, W. (2006) ‘Reforma estatal y multiculturalismo latinoamericano al inicio del siglo XXI’,
in R. Boelens, D. Getches and A. Guevara (eds) Agua y Derecho. Polı́ticas hı́dricas, derechos
consuetudinarios e identidades locales, pp. 59–82. Lima: IEP.
Assies, W. and A. Gundermann (eds) (2007) Movimientos indı́genas y gobiernos locales en
América Latina. IWGIA, El Colegio de Michoacán, Universidad Católica del Norte. Santiago
de Chile: IIAM.
Bakker, K. (2007) ‘The “Common” versus the “Commodity”: Alter-globalization, Anti-
privatization and the Human Right to Water in the Global South,’ Antipode 39(3): 430–55.
Baud, M. (2003) Intelectuales y sus utopı́as. Indigenismo y la imaginación de América Latina.
Amsterdam: CEDLA.
von Benda-Beckmann, F. and K. von Benda-Beckmann (2001) ‘Recognizing Water Rights’, in R.
Meinzen-Dick and R. Rosegrant (eds) Overcoming Water Scarcity and Quality Constraints:
2020 Vision, Focus Brief 1. www.ifpri.org/2020/focus (accessed June 2008).
von Benda-Beckmann, F., K. von Benda-Beckmann and J. Spiertz (1998) ‘Equity and Legal
Pluralism: Taking Customary Law into Account in Natural Resource Policies’, in R. Boelens
and G. Dávila (eds) Searching for Equity. Conceptions of Justice and Equity in Peasant
Irrigation, pp. 57–69. Assen: Van Gorcum.
Bennet, V., S. Dávila-Poblete and M.N. Rico (eds) (2005) Opposing Currents. The Politics of
Water and Gender in Latin America. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press.
Boelens, R. and B. Doornbos (2001) ‘The Battlefield of Water Rights. Rule Making amidst
Conflicting Normative Frameworks in the Ecuadorian Highlands’, Human Organization
60(4): 343–55.
Boelens, R. and P. Hoogendam (eds) (2002) Water Rights and Empowerment. Assen: Van
Gorcum.
Boelens, R. and P.H. Gelles (2005) ‘Cultural Politics, Communal Resistance and Identity
in Andean Irrigation Development’, Bulletin of Latin American Research 24(3): 311–
27.
Boelens, R., I. Gentes, A. Guevara and P. Urteaga (2005) ‘Special Law: Recognition and
Denial of Diversity in Andean Water Control’, in D. Roth, R. Boelens and M. Zwarteveen
(eds) Liquid Relations, pp. 144–71. New Brunswick, NJ and London: Rutgers University
Press.
Boelens, R., D. Getches and A. Guevara (eds) (2006) Agua y Derecho: Polı́ticas hı́dricas,
derechos consuetudinarios e identidades locales. Lima: IEP.
330 Rutgerd Boelens
Boelens, R. and M. Zwarteveen (2005) ‘Prices and Politics in Andean Water Reforms’, Devel-
opment and Change 36(4): 735–58.
Bustamante, R. (2005) Normas indı́genas y consuetudinarias sobre la gestión del agua en
Bolivia. WALIR Studies Volume 10. Cochabamba: Centro Agua; Santiago: UN/CEPAL;
Wageningen: Wageningen University.
Cremers, L., M. Ooijevaar and R. Boelens (2005) ‘Institutional Reform in the Andean Irrigation
Sector: Enabling Policies for Strengthening Local Rights and Water Management’, Natural
Resources Forum 29: 37–50.
Dávila, G. and H. Olazával (2006) De la Mediación a la Movilización Social. Conflictos por el
agua en Chimborazo, Ecuador. WALIR – Interjuntas. Quito: AbyaYala.
De Soto, H. (2000) The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails
Everywhere Else. New York: Basic Books.
Fanon, F. (1963[1961]) The Wretched of the Earth. New York: Grove Press.
Foucault, M. (1977) ‘Nietzsche, Genealogy, History’, in D.F. Bouchard (ed.) Language, Counter-
Memory, Practice: Selected Essays and Interviews, pp. 1339–64. Ithaca, NY: Cornell Uni-
versity Press.
Foucault, M. (1995[1975]) Discipline and Punish: The Birth of the Prison. New York: Vintage
Books.
Foucault, M. (2001[1961]) Madness and Civilization: A History of Insanity in the Age of Reason.
London and New York: Routledge.
Gelles, P.H. (2000) Water and Power in Highland Peru: The Cultural Politics of Irrigation and
Development. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press.
Gentes, I. (2006) ‘La interacción de los derechos locales e indı́genas de agua con la legislación
chilena’, in R. Boelens, D. Getches and A. Guevara (eds) Agua y Derecho, pp. 255–84. Lima:
IEP.
Getches, D.H. (2005) ‘Defending Indigenous Water Rights with the Laws of a Dominant Culture:
The Case of the United States’, in D. Roth, R. Boelens and M. Zwarteveen (eds) Liquid
Relations, pp. 44–65. New Brunswick, NJ and London: Rutgers University Press.
Getches, D.H. (2006) Indigenous Water Rights in the United States and under International
Norms. WALIR Studies Volume 6. Boulder, CO: University of Colorado; Cusco, Peru:
UN/CEPAL; Wageningen: Wageningen University.
Guevara, A. (2006) ‘Official Water Law Versus Indigenous and Peasant Rights in Peru’, in
R. Boelens, M. Chiba and D. Nakashima (eds) Water and Indigenous Peoples, pp. 126–43.
Paris: UNESCO.
Hale, C.R. (2002) ‘Does Multiculturalism Menace? Governance, Cultural Rights and the Politics
of Identity in Guatemala’, Journal of Latin America Studies 34 (3): 485–524.
Haraway, D.J. (1991) Simians, Cyborgs and Women: The Reinvention of Nature. London: Free
Association Books.
Hendriks, J. (1998) ‘Water as Private Property. Notes on the Case of Chile’, in R. Boelens and G.
Dávila (eds) Searching for Equity: Conceptions of Justice and Equity in Peasant Irrigation,
pp. 297–310. Assen, The Netherlands: Van Gorcum.
Hendriks, J. (2006) ‘Legislación de aguas y gestión de sistemas hı́dricos en paı́ses de la región
andina’, in P. Urteaga and R. Boelens (eds) Derechos Colectivos y Polı́ticas Hı́dricas en la
Región Andina, pp. 47–112. Lima: IEP.
Ingram, H. (2008) ‘Beyond Universal Remedies for Good Water Governance: A Political and
Contextual Approach’. Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona, and Irvine, CA: University of
California at Irvine. http://rosenberg.ucanr.org/documents/V%20Ingram.pdf
Isch, E. and I. Gentes (eds) (2006) Agua y servicios ambientales. Visiones crı́ticas desde los
Andes. Quito: AbyaYala.
Mayer, E. (2002) The Articulated Peasant: Household Economies in the Andes. Boulder, CO
and Oxford: Westview Press.
Paniagua, H. (2005) ‘La ley de proyectos y percepciones campesinas de derechos de agua en un
sistema de riego andino’. Research document. Wageningen: Wageningen University.
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 331