0% found this document useful (0 votes)
10 views25 pages

The Politics of Disciplining Water Right

This article explores the complexities of local water rights in Andean countries and the challenges they pose to state and market institutions seeking uniformity. It critiques the politics of recognition and codification of local rights, arguing that official policies often serve to control and incorporate local systems into neoliberal frameworks, rather than genuinely recognizing their autonomy. The study highlights the ongoing struggles between local water user communities and formal legal systems, emphasizing the need for a nuanced understanding of local rights dynamics.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
10 views25 pages

The Politics of Disciplining Water Right

This article explores the complexities of local water rights in Andean countries and the challenges they pose to state and market institutions seeking uniformity. It critiques the politics of recognition and codification of local rights, arguing that official policies often serve to control and incorporate local systems into neoliberal frameworks, rather than genuinely recognizing their autonomy. The study highlights the ongoing struggles between local water user communities and formal legal systems, emphasizing the need for a nuanced understanding of local rights dynamics.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 25

The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights

Rutgerd Boelens

ABSTRACT

This article examines how the legal systems of Andean countries have dealt
with the region’s huge plurality of local water rights, and how official poli-
cies to ‘recognize’ local rights and identities harbour increasingly subtle
politics of codification, confinement and disciplining. The autonomy and
diversity of local water rights are a major hindrance for water companies,
elites and formal rule-enforcers, since State and market institutions require
a predictable, uniform playing field. Complex local rights orders are seen
as irrational, ill-defined and disordered. Officialdom cannot simply ignore
or oppress the ‘unruliness and disobedience’ of local rights systems: rather
it ‘incorporates’ local normative orders that have the capacity to adequately
respond to context-based needs. This article examines a number of evolving,
overlapping legal domination strategies, such as the ‘marrying’ of local and
official legal systems in ways that do not challenge the legal and power hier-
archy; and reviews the ways in which official regulation and legal strategies
deny or take into consideration local water rights repertoires, and the politics
of recognition that these entail. Post-colonial recognition policies are not
simply responses to demands by subjugated groups for greater autonomy.
Rather, they facilitate the water bureaucracy’s political control and help ne-
oliberal sectors to incorporate local water users’ rights and organizations into
the market system — even though many communities refuse to accept these
policies of recognition and politics of containment.

INTRODUCTION

‘The colonialist specialists do not recognize that the culture has changed and they hasten to
support the traditions of the indigenous society. It is the colonialists who have become the
defenders of the native lifestyle’ (Frantz Fanon, The Wretched of the Earth, 1961).

The huge diversity of existing water rights and the dynamic features of
local water control systems constitute a fundamental problem for law and
policy makers, water resource planners and commercial water industries.
In general, State and market institutions require a well established, uniform
playing field. Local water rights systems are not just incomprehensible and

I thank Margreet Zwarteveen, Hans Achterhuis, Jan Douwe van der Ploeg, Armando Guevara,
Patricia Urteaga, Irit Eguavoen, Peter Mollinga, Francis Cleaver, Jan Hendriks, Flip Wester,
Edwin Rap and the anonymous reviewers of this journal for their insightful contributions to
earlier versions of this paper.

C Institute of Social Studies 2009. Published


Development and Change 40(2): 307–331 (2009). 
by Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main St.,
Malden, MA 02148, USA
308 Rutgerd Boelens

inadequate in relation to conventional wisdom (labelled rationality) or stan-


dard concepts of justice; in the eyes of officialdom they are most of all
unmanageable — expressing ‘unruly disorder’ and going beyond official
control.
For this reason, in the Andean region, official legislation and water re-
source management policies commonly have aimed to curtail, contain and
direct the local normative diversity that is found in water user communities.
The debates and battles are ferocious since, simultaneously, the questions of
resource (re)distribution and cultural and political recognition are at stake.
At the heart of the matter, the struggle for access to water combines with the
struggle to claim or defend the legitimacy of local authority and water rights
systems. Here, the issue of recognition of local water rights is ambiguous
but central to the region’s water conflicts. Attempts to formally recognize
local rights systems have not guaranteed concrete protection in day-to-day
realities and, as this article will demonstrate, the politics of recognition can
be problematic.
The following sections concentrate on several gradually evolving, over-
lapping legal domination strategies. I will review the ways in which official
(post-colonial) regulation and legal strategies deny or take into considera-
tion local water rights repertoires, and the politics of recognition that these
entail. Notwithstanding their divergent political orientations, how have An-
dean countries’ legal systems dealt with the complexity of water rights, and
what politics (of definition, containment and disciplining of local rights, or-
ganizational forms and identities) are inherent in these legal strategies and
policies of recognition?1
As the article argues, making ‘local unruliness’ tangible is a major
preoccupation of modernist recognition policies. Peruvian economist and
World Bank advisor Hernando De Soto — one of the world’s most influ-
ential policy advocates on ‘people’s capitalism’ — clearly illustrates this
worry, and the way current policy makers explain ‘the mystery of legal
failure’:

As things stand, the creation of one integrated property system in non-Western nations is
impossible. Extralegal property arrangements are dispersed among dozens, sometimes hun-
dreds, of communities; rights and other information are known only to insiders or neighbours.
All the separate, loose extralegal property arrangements characteristic of most Third World
and former communist nations must be woven into a single system from which general
principles of law can be drawn. (De Soto, 2000: 162)

1. To delimit the contents, this article deals with the tenets of legal strategies to discipline
water rights. I refer to the academic series Agua y Sociedad – WALIR for the analysis
of other domains of Andean water rights contestation (www.iep.org.pe). Neither does the
paper deal with the contents and mechanisms of Andean water rights (see e.g., Boelens
and Hoogendam, 2002; Roth et al., 2005); or resistance strategies by Andean communities
(e.g., Bennett et al., 2005; Boelens and Gelles, 2005; Gelles, 2000).
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 309

These words, which provide the background against which I will for-
mulate my analysis and critique, are not new and are embedded in a long
history of liberal policy efforts in the region. These days, however, they
form part of a new neoliberal policy wave of participatory, inclusive power
strategies that ‘recognize the local and extralegal’. Recognition policies get
increasingly subtle. As I will show, unlike their liberal forerunners, socialist
opponents and most of their contemporary neoliberal colleagues, these new
neoliberal policy makers do not see local law as irrational. In that sense,
unlike most mainstream law and policy makers in water affairs who used to
(and continue to) simply deny local property constructs, they — with their
plea for profoundly understanding the manifestations of extralegal complex-
ity — are analytically far more ‘advanced’ and politically far more subtle
and problematic for collective rights systems in the Andes.
I say ‘problematic’, because the standpoint I take in this article is situated
(Haraway, 1991). It looks at how the continuity of Andean collective wa-
ter rights repertoires is threatened, thereby endangering the self-sustained
reproduction of the water management collectives themselves. This ‘situat-
edness’ is political in a sense that it concentrates on the position of those user
groups in the Andean water world who find social and political-economic
shelter and livelihood security within collective water rights systems. Such
collectives are complex, multi-layered entities whose members, although
differentiated by class, gender, status and often by ethnicity, try to construct
and re-affirm social, territorial and water resource bonds because of mutual
dependence: the continuation and improvement of their livelihoods requires
shared institutions for collective action to defend and control their individual
and common water resources.
The article is based on action-research with the WALIR Water Law and
Indigenous Rights programme in the Andean countries, analysing local wa-
ter rights, norms and practices and their discrimination or undermining by
official water legislation and policies. Desk studies and field work were con-
ducted in the period 2001–07, with water users’ organizations, peasant and
indigenous federations2 and civil society water platforms in Peru, Bolivia,
Ecuador and Chile (comparative country cases: Mexico and the USA).
The article concentrates on modern (that is, post-colonial) forms of rights’
disciplining, all of which, in different ways, are based on liberal inclusive,
equality ideologies. It does not focus on the ancient (but continuing) forms
of domination and disciplining based on inequality, segregation and exclu-
sion, which in everyday practice complement the modern efforts (as strategic
twins). The following section analyses the centralized, ‘equalizing’ policies
and legal systems of Andean countries, which monopolize rule-making ‘for

2. I use the concepts of ‘indigenous’, ‘peasant’ and ‘community’ as contextualized, dynamic


constructs. In the Andean region, the relation between class-based definitions (campesino)
and ethnicity-based identification (indı́gena) is complex and depends on who uses which
labels in what period or context.
310 Rutgerd Boelens

the benefit of all’. This is followed by an examination of how official leg-


islation and local rights systems are necessarily inter-related, and how this
relationship is institutionalized through ‘incorporating peasant or indigenous
laws’. I argue that such codification policies simultaneously recognize and
deny local rights, transforming the latters’ contents, force and functionality.
The study then goes on to show how multiculturalism and legal pluralism
are recognized as long as they obey the fundamental rules of play set by
the State and/or the market. There is then a reflection on the subtle capillary
politics of recognition and equalization, analysing how comprehending ex-
tralegal water rights may play a crucial role in modern, neoliberal policies to
discipline ‘unruliness’ and include all water user communities in a uniform
framework. A final section argues that local water users’ federations and
peasant and indigenous communities are not, however, defenceless.

RIGHTS DISCIPLINING BY LEGAL CENTRALISM

Local water rights, organizational norms and operational rules in the Andean
region are not only dynamic, extremely diverse, puzzlingly intertwined and
even mutually contradictory; often they also stand in clear contradiction to
national legislation (Cremers et al., 2005). From a legal point of view this
adds to a lack of clarity and order. However, from local points of view,
the rules of the game are commonly not perceived at all as unclear, unruly
or intangible.3 Context-based socio-legal repertoires link water benefits and
burdens in particular ways. Instead of reflecting general principles of ‘Right-
ness’ or positivist Justice, they correspond to diverse spheres and layers of
social justice as negotiated and constructed over time in place-specific set-
tings and power contexts: the local conceptions of fairness or equity. Unlike
engineering principles that see equitable rights in terms of water allotment
proportional to landholding and crop water requirements, and unlike the de-
politicized notion of equity that is moulded by the mainstream development
triangle of Equity–Democracy–Sustainability, I use the notion of equity to
refer to location-, time-, and group-specific political constructs of fairness.4
According to the locality, (sub)culture, historical development and position
in prevailing power structures, equity perceptions differ enormously. As
such they cannot be reified or romanticized and constitute a power relation
in themselves.

3. Despite their higher degree of adaptation to agro-physical, historical knowledge and social
community contexts (if compared to policy-driven rights frameworks), I do not argue that
local water rights are intrinsically ‘better’ in terms of equity and democracy.
4. See also von Benda-Beckmann and von Benda-Beckmann (2001); Ingram (2008); Roth
et al. (2005).
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 311

A Labyrinth of Systems and Rights

In most Andean communities, the conceptualization of a water use system


is entirely different from those in conventional irrigation or water manage-
ment manuals. Instead of referring fundamentally to a physical hydraulic
system and a functional organization, local perceptions commonly refer to,
as Hendriks observes, ‘a system of rights, of obligations, and of (cultural)
management regarding one or more water sources, shared among a given
pool of users’ (2006: 84). Besides the intertwining of the social and technical
disciplines of water control, the systems themselves also mix together and
become muddled, physically, organizationally and legally — deepening the
notion of legal pluralism (von Benda-Beckmann et al., 1998; Roth et al.,
2005). Commonly, systems have become inter-related, making the territory
ever denser with multiple overlapping systems that vie with but also com-
plement each other. Together they provide water in a given territory, and a
family may belong to several systems at once. In this complex arrangement,
irrigation systems are often distinguished by the kinds of water they con-
duct with regard to their source, the owners’ group, or the way the system
was made. Hendriks (2006) illustrates the complex of co-existing systems
with the case of Tiquipaya, Cochabamba, Bolivia. Of the eight overlapping
irrigation systems (not counting other water use systems), each is managed
through a different normative and organizational framework.
The Machu Mit’a System dates back to before the Incas, with some 830
users, distributing fifty-five collective rights allocations in thirteen communi-
ties. This comprises the natural flow of the Khora River (Hendriks, 2006: 85).
The Lagum Mayu System provides rights to some 450 users through forty-
eight allocations in nine communities. It uses the water dammed in a lake
and was established by haciendas in the late nineteenth and early twentieth
centuries. The Sayt’u Kocha System was built in the late nineteenth century
and serves groups in southern Tiquipaya. The Chankas System consists of
eleven lakes adapted in the 1960s by two sub-communities of Tiquipaya.
The El Tajamar system takes water from the Khora River, and is managed
by some eighty peasant families from one sector of Tiquipaya. The National
Irrigation System No 1 was commissioned in 1946. Its water comes from
a large dam and benefits some 530 users from eight communities around
Cochabamba. The seventh group is a system of springs: some 850 families
have rights to forty springs, fed by an aquifer that comes to the surface in
central Tiquipaya. Each spring is tapped by an independent group with its
own roster. Finally, as the eighth group, there are many private wells, drilled
individually and managed autonomously (ibid.: 86).
In that same Tiquipaya area, even on a single farm, different water rights
orders may be distinguished. As Hendriks explains, there are water rights
originally based on the configuration of Inca villages and colonial reset-
tlements, rights originating in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries from
labour or capital invested by hacienda owners, localized rights to one or
312 Rutgerd Boelens

more springs, rights originating in recent irrigation projects, rights based on


the drilling of private wells, and so forth. Alongside these irrigation water
rights frameworks, there are many other rights systems in the zone involving
other water uses. These same households also deal with government legis-
lation norms, which, rather than being above the tangle of local normative
repertoires (as positive law theories would maintain) are actually in ongoing
interaction, immersed in local systems.
As Hendriks argues, this overlapping of several irrigation systems, with
different rights and distribution frames, has generated a very complex water
territory. Also, a single user belongs to different irrigators’ organizations
at once, visible or less visible, structured or less structured. ‘The different
systems use (part of ) a single network of canals, so it would be easy to
jump to the mistaken conclusion of seeing the local reality as “a single
system”, if one thought exclusively in terms of infrastructure, in order to
define an irrigation system’ (ibid.: 87). Just as these multiple rights systems
are different from each other, they also differ greatly from the norms of
water legislation. For any outside agency, this is an almost impenetrable,
almost ungovernable puzzle.
When, in 2003, the Bolivian ambassador to The Netherlands visited Wa-
geningen to inquire about possibilities for supporting water policies in her
country, she clearly expressed the government’s governance worry: how to
standardize and rule unruly diversity? ‘Our problem is that every munici-
pality wants to create its own rules for managing the water’.5 The reason for
wanting more control was also clear. Her explanation of the recent Water
Wars that had shaken Bolivia, and many parts of the world, was simple and
stripped of all complexities: ‘The locals don’t want to pay for the water’.
Commonly such complex local rights agreements and institutional ar-
rangements have been and still are obstructed, if not declared illegal, by
Andean water laws. We can distinguish various legal responses to water
rights complexity, which I will review below.
During the epoch of colonialism — which falls outside the scope of this
article — local water rights were either replaced to facilitate control and
extraction by elites, or were ‘respected’ under pluralist (dualist) regimes
that aimed to divide and rule. Spanish colonial law was both exclusive and
paternalistic but, unlike its early liberal successors, it was not based on a
mono-juridical model.6
The latter was introduced by post-colonial, Republic period governments.
They tended to utterly abolish local rights repertoires and import Western law
in order to promote ‘progress, modernity and development’. Since then, mod-
ern water legislation and policies have been an expression of liberal equality

5. Pers. comm. 1 September 2003.


6. A parallel legal system of ‘guardianship of the miserable’ was established: the Republic of
Indians, complementary to the Republic of Spaniards. The indigenous had to operate under
both systems (see Boelens et al., 2005; Guevara, 2006).
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 313

discourses. It is the State’s exclusive prerogative to make and enforce law,


and define and allocate water rights. In some aspects this effectively opposed
abusive water rights systems such as those enacted by feudal landlords, and
in theory this could bring a more equal sharing of (water) rights and bur-
dens in society, and provide common claim-making mechanisms for the less
powerful. In Andean countries’ reality, however, monolegality and forced
normative equality were fiercely imposed by a liberal upper class, white-
mestizo minority. They did not just oppose feudalism but also dominated
nation-building and State institutions and portrayed modern society as a ho-
mogeneous reality into which no diversity of rights conceptions could fit.
State monopoly on violence and law production with so-called ‘universal
rationality’ — but in the Andes, developed and enacted by this ruling eth-
nic group and class — was to suppress and replace the Hobbesian ‘natural
State’ of uncontrolled war and contestation among humans with its diverse
‘disobedient forms of justice’. This ideology of equality was also formu-
lated in terms of a major political undertaking of racial mixing (mestizaje).
Fundamentally it was an ideology of whiteness, standardizing all nations’
inhabitants under the model of white-mestizo hegemonic groups, with regard
to cultural codes, norms and even physical aspects.
Gradually, the racist assimilation project was combined with an integra-
tion model that attempted to grant indigenous communities more rights and
integrate them into a market system, to share in the benefits of modern
society. The building of a national identity and unitary consciousness was
quintessential for the dominant groups’ effort to enhance and control na-
tion/State building.7 Although certain indigenous cultural norms were taken
more seriously, this did not affect the ideology and sovereignty of the State
political administration, which was and still is particularly strong in water
resources management. Thus, the approach of normalizing the ‘inferiors’ to
fit them into the white-mestizo model was combined with a paternalistic,
civilizing approach geared to ‘supporting the backward’ to help them be-
come equal. Indeed, throughout the post-colonial period, from liberal and
‘revolutionary’ reforms to the wave of neoliberal water privatization, poli-
cies of recognition neatly combined recognition with denial of the ‘other’ in
an attempt to ‘normalize the abnormals’.
One of the enduring assumptions of post-colonial law making for water
management was that Western property institutions, and standardization of
agreements among all, would be for the benefit of all and produce efficient
rights and rational organization. Cultural differences would vanish as soon
as local communities experienced its effectiveness. This universal ethical
system remains key to the current legal-modernization thrust. Rather than
looking at the reasons why Andean water users’ organizations and federa-
tions actively challenge this uniform system of (commoditized) water values

7. Cf. Anderson (1983); Assies (2006); Baud (2003); Gelles (2000); Stavenhagen (2002).
314 Rutgerd Boelens

and property relations that, in their experience, facilitates transfer of water


rights to the few, it is portrayed as ‘civilized interaction and exchange’. And
rather than acknowledging the capacity of collective water rights systems
to enable — in the adverse political and agro-ecological Andean environ-
ment — livelihood security of the economically less powerful, the liberal
discourse argues that only through State law and market institutions can
local people be released from the mystery and uncertainty of local ‘arbitrary
arrangements’.
In Andean countries, the liberal equality myth, the assumption that a
modern water society could be legally engineered, and the unitary legalis-
tic notion, have always been very strong. For instance, national legislation
in Peru ignores the existence of the tremendous diversity of rural and in-
digenous water rights repertoires. Although the 1969 General Water Law
contained certain major improvements over previous laws to further dis-
tributive justice, it rigidly enforced ‘equalization of all’ but was completely
based on the reality of Peru’s coastal region, with contexts and cultures
that are totally different from those of the Andean and Amazon regions.
Moreover, the blueprint Water Law regime incorporated institutions, wa-
ter rights values and norms that neatly resemble those found in large-scale
State-managed irrigation systems anywhere in the world. The ideology of
nation building, together with the effort to counteract colonial racialization
of ethnic differences, introduced a new type of cultural politics, whereby
cultural differences were denied and the right to culturally define and orga-
nize were oppressed (see Guevara, 2006). In Ecuador, the very similar 1972
Water Law and its regulations are not compatible with any existing local
management processes in the Andean highlands (see Boelens and Doornbos,
2001).
Aside from legal structures and contents, it is useful to distinguish among
liberal legal ideology and legal practice. On the one hand, in practice, under
extremely unequal power relations, the liberal argument of equality under
the law results in a myth. This is manifested, for instance, in the capacity
of hegemonic sectors to legally manipulate conflicts over water and acquire
water rights.8 On the other hand, it does not mean that the equality ideology
is without effect. In Andean water policies, the equality argument is not
applied to achieve more equal access, but to deny difference and contain
diversity. It de-legitimizes the demands of various ethnic and societal groups
to manage water affairs according to their own rights repertoires. Problems
are commonly diagnosed as not being caused by racism or class oppression,
but by the indigenous and peasant communities’ backwardness and lack of
access to official legislation, since these population groups are attached to
their traditional water management systems. Official discourse suggests that

8. See, for example, Guevara (2006); Hendriks (1998), Mayer (2002); van der Ploeg (2006);
WALIR (2007) Bakker (2007).
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 315

they will be included though training and enhancing legal and institutional
access. There is an assumed need to educate the ‘uneducated’, and raise
consciousness for the ‘unconscious’, in order to include the ‘excluded’.

RIGHTS DISCIPLINING BY SHOTGUN MARRIAGE

‘Humanity does not gradually progress from combat to combat until it arrives at universal
reciprocity, where the rule of law finally replaces warfare; humanity installs each of its
violences in a system of rules and thus proceeds from domination to domination’ (Michel
Foucault, 1977: 1351).

Hobbesian hope or liberal faith in State law is clearly problematic, certainly


when analysing most Andean countries’ agrarian and water laws. The pol-
itics of recognition often materialize in policies of recognition, in which
domination is institutionalized either in legal scripts and/or in actual legal
procedures. During the last decade, the laws of most Andean countries un-
derwent major multicultural changes. The constitutions of Colombia, Peru,
Bolivia and Ecuador now formally recognize cultural diversity and legal
pluralism. Yet, such general changes regarding recognition of diversity are
not reflected in most of the powerful water laws or agrarian laws, even less
in water legal practice.
Nevertheless, in their own interest, the State institutions and national elites
could not always remain silent and often have had to respond to demands
and uprisings by indigenous and peasant groups, in terms of legal changes.
Therefore, next to the uniform equal-for-all State law, dealt with above,
another (or rather, complementary) strategy does appear to create local rule-
making space. In the Andean countries’ legal systems, commonly, Agrarian
and Community Laws create particular rights especially applicable to the
peasant and indigenous populations, thereby expanding their concept of
unique, omnipresent and overall national law. Such special laws may also be
‘added’ to an existing legal structure, for example, by adding an Indigenous
Law or Peasant Community Law to the existing Water Law and Mining
Code.
Most often, ‘legalized customary law’ is a product of a forced engagement
between official and local law systems — a ‘shotgun marriage’. Official law
is too general to be able to resolve particular local problems and often cannot
do ‘perceived justice’ in local cases and water cultures. Therefore the State
and its legal system face the need to incorporate local fairness constructs
and solve normative conflicts in order not to lose legitimacy and discursive
power in the eyes of its citizens. Local law systems, in turn, are intrinsically
hybrids, and cannot operate without relating to formal law systems. But the
marriage is unhappy and extremely complicated. This is partly because most
of the time it is the aim of the State and dominant groups in the Andean
countries to resolve only ad hoc, secondary conflicts, without changing the
316 Rutgerd Boelens

primary, fundamental conflicts based on class contradictions and power


structures that reproduce gender and ethnic positions. Various ‘marriage
conflicts’ cast doubts on the effectiveness of such official recognition policies
in safeguarding local water rights. Even the latest Bolivian legislative efforts
to marry the two are full of complexities and contradictions.
Commonly, the official recognition policies make use of simplified, stereo-
typed constructs that misrepresent peasant and indigenous organizational
forms, identities and natural resource management dynamics. Thereby, they
institutionalize local Andean water users’ rights and management norms
in ways that may reinforce their subordination to other bodies of law, and
strengthen (intentionally or not) the interests of influential players. Thus, the
outcome of this recognition may be the oppression or obliteration of local
law, codifying it in isolation from its cultural context and slotting it into
larger-scale power structures and strategies.
Tellingly, in order to match Ecuadorian Water Law, the large variety of
peasant and indigenous irrigation collectives are labelled and recognized
as private systems, as any other enterprise or hacienda system. Although
the new 2008 Constitution aims to somehow correct various errors of the
past, legal recognition of rural communities so far has largely misunderstood
people’s own organization forms, by imposing a single form of organization,
with characteristics reflecting the structures and values of liberal democracy
rather than the existing ones.
Similarly, in Peru, the General Law on Peasant Communities codifies a
simplified notion of ‘the community’. Peruvian law subtly links this essen-
tialist legal framework for community recognition to the above-mentioned
top-down water administrative framework: the Irrigators’ Commission is
established as a specialized committee within the codified community. To
obtain title to their territory communities need to present ‘official evidence’
that sustains their claim. ‘In day-to-day legal practice communities can
operate with any chance of success only when they have accredited their
official registration and recognition’ (Guevara, 2006: 141). Thus, many ru-
ral groups, self-defined for decades as peasant or indigenous communities,
are involved in lengthy procedures, but have not yet received their offi-
cial classification notice — often with serious consequences for the defence
of their rights to water and other natural resources, and access to loans
and public resources. Recent legal changes were not made to adapt to the
complex rural reality, but mainly to thrust peasant communities into the
market, to make it easier to break them up and sell their land (Guevara,
2006).
In this respect, Chilean law is even more ‘advanced’. In 1993, Chile en-
acted the Indigenous Law to counteract the negative consequences of the
neoliberal 1981 Water Code (see also below). It was meant to support in-
digenous populations in protecting what was left of their territorial rights.
But although the law has managed to fill some gaps in the Water Code, it
continues to be difficult to substantively defend indigenous rights against
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 317

third parties. The fact that it is a special law only applicable to (and within)
a special group of the national population (in Chile strongly essentialized)
has left most indigenous claims unanswered (Gentes, 2006). Moreover, the
Indigenous Law has proven to be extremely weak, whenever indigenous
communities had to face the powerful Water and Mining Codes, which are
called upon by the water-owning elites. The Law stresses special protec-
tion of water for indigenous groups but at the same time it establishes that,
in any event, this must not interfere with water rights that have already
been registered pursuant to the Water Code. As Gentes observes, a funda-
mental problem involves the difficulty of protecting collective community
laws in an overall neoliberal framework that destroys collective organiza-
tion and favours individual and private rights. Government agencies and
international trade law assume that indigenous groups must either fit into
the market or count themselves out of the process of globalization (Gentes,
2006).
The flip-side of the recognition question is the well-known danger of
curtailing local autonomy, chaining local rights groups to new strict rules
and boxing them into a generalizing State law system. The dynamics and
multiple manifestations of local water rights systems cannot be codified into
blanket legal terms without jeopardizing their foundations. They refer to a
broad range of diverse ‘living’ rights systems and cultures that constantly
reorganize their rules precisely to maintain their identity, and their capacity
to negotiate and solve problems.
In the Andean region, law makers, policy makers and scholars have long
used different approaches to analyse the issue of peasant communities and
regulate ‘the indigenous question’. As Guevara (2006: 131) observes, ‘at
one extreme are the modernizers, liberals, or progressives, who strive to
change the agrarian reality at any cost, including cultural costs. At the other,
radical indianists, indigenists, and proponents of recovering Andean culture
and technology postulate a romantic environmentalism that places Andean
peoples beyond history and near an autarkic utopia’. These essentialist and
naturalized constructs have often served in official identity politics — to
validate segregationist policies, to justify ethno-nationalism or to legitimize
bio-political mestizaje.9 This is quite similar to the way colonial law, in many
countries, constructed customary rights, invented and officialized traditions
and created a usable past. Simplified institutional models, abstracted from
complexity, have not just denied existing diversity but also transformed the
way to interpret reality.
Essentialization is not just an error but often has a political purpose: the
re-presentation and re-cognition of local water rights and identities refers
to re-interpreting and thus transforming them. ‘Recognize’ literally means

9. They were also (re)appropriated as political tools by the marginalized groups themselves
(see, for example, Baud, 2003; Boelens and Gelles, 2005; Gelles, 2000; van der Ploeg,
2006).
318 Rutgerd Boelens

‘to know and understand reality again’ — here, to reshape the image and
contents according to the needs of the formal ‘recognizers’. In this process of
recognizing, essentialization and objectification fundamentally occur when
complex realities and indefinite categories need to be contained in order
to control them. State or externally endorsed ethnicity, identity and nature
of people’s water rights provide the illusion of the continuity of existing
rights, institutions and practices, which are, however, subject to new contexts
in which power relations are being reinforced or strategically rearranged.
Commonly, Andean countries’ cultural politics thus define water culture
and rights as fixed, reified and aligned to prevailing institutional and power
relations: a crystallization of the presumed physical, political-economic and
psychological boundaries and repertoires of a group, which predetermines
and makes tangible their behaviour. Abandoning uncontrolled dynamics,
diversity, human agency, contingency and local resistance to the domains of
illusion is the implicit political effort.
Thus, clearly, not all uses and customs are denied: some essentialized
local rules and rights are allowed and institutionalized, at the expense of
most others and at the cost of intensifying the repression of more fractious,
defiant and disloyal norms. Legal recognition and the subsequent freezing of
a naturalized socio-legal repertoire impacts both peoples and management
systems that are ‘recognized’ and those that do not have this new legal
backing. The legalization of some is accompanied by the illegalization of
others. This relates to both cultural rights (including water management
rules and norms) and distributive justice (such as water access and use
rights). The example below illustrates how incorporation of some local
water rights (naturalized as traditional rights) has direct implications for the
non-protection of others.

The Quest for Redefining Water Rights and Essentializing Identity

Andean community irrigation rights, in all their complexity and diversity,


have some common features. These include: they typically constitute collec-
tive property; they are territory-bound; their authority is vested in rotating
community leadership posts; they can hardly ever be transferred to users
outside the system; they express diverse use values (also non-economic); in
times of scarcity they obey prioritization reflecting social needs (to enable
livelihood reproduction); their acquisition and consolidation is based on wa-
ter use system construction and consolidation; decision-making procedures
are based on one vote per right-holder. Each community provides its own
individual context and history version of such a rights repertoire. Therefore,
it is not surprising that communities’ resistance to changing their funda-
mental rights framework is enormous; significantly, all Andean countries’
water laws (which fundamentally neglect these local rights) were established
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 319

during military dictatorships, commonly oppressing dissenting voices (as in


Bolivia, Peru, Ecuador and Chile).10
Reviewing the above properties, it is immediately clear not only that
the diversity of rights limits the control of outside bureaucratic or market
players, but also that the very contents and mechanisms of Andean water
rights make free market operation very difficult. In Chile, the fundamen-
tal attack on Andean community rights by the neoliberal model, claiming
freedom for all, was made possible only after the Pinochet regime violently
oppressed resistance. The neoliberal Water Code promoted precisely the
opposite of what Andean community rights entail — private water rights.
Separated from the land and community; their authority is vested in the
State that protects the functioning of the free market; their transfer is pro-
moted and new rights are awarded to the economically most powerful bidder.
These private water rights fundamentally express market exchange value;
they do not obey any legally protected social prioritization; their acquisi-
tion and consolidation is cut loose from system sustainability and repro-
duction; and, suffocating democratic decision making, the voting weight
of the individual is proportional to his or her water shares and buying
power.
Similar to the historical analysis of Getches (2005) regarding the white
settlers’ interest in defining Indian water rights and identity in US reserva-
tions,11 the paradox in Chile’s neoliberal model of local rights recognition
is that it is, as one of the interested parties, precisely the business sectors
(such as mining, hydropower and forest companies) that are pushing for

10. The water law in Bolivia is old, dating from 1906, and since then a large number of
proposals have been formulated but without approval. Decrees have changed legal water
matters on an ad hoc or sectoral basis. Five years ago a new Irrigation Law was enacted
(see Perreault, 2006). Since 2006 the Evo Morales government has been working on a new
framework for water law and policies. In Peru and Ecuador, the current water laws were
installed in 1969 and 1972 respectively, during reformist military governments. Since then
they have incorporated a number of (mostly neoliberal and ad hoc decentralization) decrees
(de Vos et al., 2006). The Chilean Water Code was enacted under the military dictatorship
of Pinochet and installed a private property regime with dreadful consequences, especially
for many indı́gena and campesino communities. Since the return to democracy only slight
changes have been made to the legal framework to reverse its problematic impact for poor
user groups and the environment (see, e.g., Boelens et al., 2006; Boelens and Zwarteveen,
2005; Bustamante, 2005; Gentes, 2006; Hendriks, 2006; WALIR, 2007).
11. In the USA, after two centuries of limiting Indian rights geographically and politically in
ever-smaller reservations, white settlers and investors often are the prime advocates of clear
Indian water rights in order to know how far their encroachment practices can go without
overstepping their legal backing: ‘Because investments and property values are undermined
by uncertainty, non-Indians and the western states that tend to support non-Indian interests
have also urged that Indian water rights should be legally determined’ (Getches, 2005: 48).
A secondary effect was the government’s attempt to civilize and contain unruly Indians
by turning them into individual farmers. After dividing up the reservation and individually
allocating the land, the rest of land and water rights could be given to white settlers (cf.
Getches, 2006).
320 Rutgerd Boelens

clear rights for indigenous communities. Their objective is not to defend


indigenous autonomy but to provide a broad catalogue of legal certainties
for outside investors in these territories (Gentes, 2006). The water rights
market and investment plans, according to them, cannot operate if there are
customary rights that are not registered but do entail a certain legal pro-
tection. Thus, they seek ways to motivate all water users to register their
rights and they drive public policy geared to making users participate in
water rights trading (Boelens et al., 2005; Gentes, 2006). They therefore
plead for strict codification of indigenous rights, grounded in an essentialist
concept of indigenousness, disregarding its dynamic nature. This enlarges
the security of outside investors as to ‘how far they can go’, reduces the
universe of users who can claim ‘indigenous rights’, and establishes lo-
cal rules for behaving as ‘Noble Indians’ accredited by the free market
game.

RIGHTS DISCIPLINING BY ‘MANAGED MULTICULTURALISM’

The experiences in Chile, Peru and Ecuador show that the issue of how
to codify, contain and dominate the diversity of local water rights through
recognition policies is a fundamental question. The answers become increas-
ingly subtle and participatory. Interestingly, the decade in which the greatest
wave of official recognition of indigenous and customary rights emerged in
Latin America was the same one in which the neoliberal model was imple-
mented. Strong support was and still is provided by multilateral institutions
and financial lending agencies to the cause of multiculturalism and recog-
nition of diversity. In fact, there is a convergence of interests between the
neoliberal model and certain multicultural currents.
As Assies argues, recognition policies during the past decade in Latin
America have been greatly influenced by a new strategy of ‘managed mul-
ticulturalism’, which celebrates cultural pluralism but fails to materialize
resource redistribution (Assies, 2006). By contrast with transformative ap-
proaches to multiculturalism — which do aim to redistribute power and
resources — this multiculturalism endorsed by State and multilateral agen-
cies reinforces essentialist expressions of group entities. Also in the field
of water control, this policy seeks to standardize cultures and their rights
and procedures. Self-regulation, as Hale observes, comes with clearly ar-
ticulated limits: it ‘attempts to distinguish those rights that are acceptable
from those that are not . . . defining the language of contention; stating which
rights are legitimate; and what forms of political action are appropriate for
achieving them’ (Hale, 2002: 490). For example, as a typical feature of mod-
ern Andean water policies, decentralization of water administration forms
part of the recipe, and ‘participatory’ rights and organizational forms are
rigidly detailed. At the same time, paradoxically, in the neoliberal age of
State downsizing, decentralization is seized upon by central governments to
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 321

lighten their responsibilities and strengthen their legitimacy and control at


the local level. For example, the previous (neoliberal) Bolivian government
explicitly stated that the core purpose of decentralization was to re-establish
State authority over society. Legislation regarding watershed management
in Peru is another illustrative example of how the State uses the new ‘par-
ticipatory, decentralizing’ discourse to strengthen its control (Boelens et al.,
2005).
That is why these local water rights recognition policies are not in oppo-
sition to, but rather combine quite well with, current modernizing policies.
As once foreseen by Marx and Engels, capitalism ‘equalizes’ and creates
a world after its own image. Similarly, in modern times, as Assies (2006)
observes, the neoliberal State does not simply recognize the community,
civil society or the indigenous culture, but rather reconstructs them, as a re-
production of its own relationships. This policy differentiates between good
Indians and bad Indians. The former present cultural demands that are com-
patible with the neoliberal project, whereas the latter are the ‘radical Indians’
who call for redistribution of power and resources. Indeed, as Hale argues,
powerful political and economic actors use this kind of multiculturalism ‘to
affirm cultural difference, while retaining the prerogative to discern between
cultural rights consistent with the ideal of liberal, democratic pluralism, and
cultural rights inimical to that ideal. In doing so they advance a univer-
salistic ethic which constitutes a defence of the neoliberal capitalist order
itself ’ (Hale, 2002: 491). Therefore, although this neoliberal, neo-indigenous
project speaks of decentralization, tolerance and respect for multicultural-
ism, these values must not impinge on the model’s foundations and market
rationality. Communities’ own natural resource management institutions are
attacked, because they are seen to jeopardize free market operation (Assies,
2006). As Hale accurately observes, this neoliberal multiculturalism and its
recognition project opens up political space for acknowledgement of pack-
ages of rights and the same time ‘disciplines those who occupy them’ (Hale,
2002: 490).

Participatory Non-Governmental Intervention to Install


Government Rule and Order

Manyaccla (Huancavelica) is a community located in one of Peru’s most


remote Andean areas, where governmental agencies and State law are no-
toriously absent. The participatory GESORI12 NGO project aims to support
these communities in improving their irrigation systems. In the zone, there
are already age-old organizations for natural resource management: although
often not legally recognized, the communities and their general assemblies
direct water management and community life. In his analysis of the project,

12. ‘Gestión Social del Riego’ – Social Management of Irrigation, in Angaraes Sur.
322 Rutgerd Boelens

Paniagua cites the project plan, which states: ‘There is no pre-defined model
and each irrigators’ organization will design their own operation’ (2005: 49).
That said, the Overall Operating Plan argues that, for improving irrigation,
Irrigators Committees must be created and formalized by the Technical Ad-
ministration of the Irrigation District (ATDR) — the government authority
responsible for setting irrigation management norms.
The NGO views it as part of its mission to rationalize irrigation organiza-
tion by including user communities in the formal hierarchy and governmen-
tal structure. Interestingly, the project’s Operating Plan creates the Irrigators
Committee (parallel to the community) before beginning the ‘participatory
assessment’. Moreover, states Paniagua (2005: 49):

The irrigation management model is pre-defined by the project, standardized by sources


and means of verifying the activities’ achievements. The Operating Plan calls for a report
indicating the number of community members trained in preparing the water fee, legal
documents proving institutional recognition and formalization of the irrigators’ organizations.
Social promoters are hired, and their pay and the evaluation of their performance depend on
making these project goals a reality.

Although the participatory assessment guide mentions that irrigators’ or-


ganizations will prepare their own regulations, to be recognized they must
follow the rigid model imposed by the ATDR.
It is a generalized pattern: NGOs often penetrate the zones most inacces-
sible for governmental legislators, taking responsibility for enforcing laws
modelled on the context of the coast and entirely unsuited to the Andean
situation — creating a world that corresponds with officialdom’s rationality.
Also in Manyaccla, the Committee model is an almost verbatim copy of the
User Organizations Regulations. The pyramid structure views the Irrigators
Committee simply as a body to support the governmental administration.
The latter does not have the institutional capacity to formalize the official
hierarchy of Users’ Junta, Commissions and Committees (all subordinated
to the ATDR), so non-governmental projects have often used their partici-
patory tools to bridge between local water control reality and governmental
norms. Paniagua (2005: 53) concludes that:

The regulations that must be ‘signed participatorily’ by community members to obtain


their ‘legal recognition’ oblige them to set up a specialized organization: this Irrigators
Committee is to support a non-existent Irrigators’ Commission and non-functional Users’
Junta, and to ignore the traditional irrigation authority — in the case of Manyaccla their
community authority, wielded by the president, who does exist, lives in the community and is
respected.

This mixes government law and ‘project law’, subtly imposing the latter upon
local norms. In the words of one of the social promoters who was given the
Kafkaesque job of implementing these irrational plans to ‘rationalize local
regulations’: ‘Committees are important, but it is like preparing a medicine
for a disease that you don’t have’ (ibid.: 54).
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 323

RIGHTS DISCIPLINING BY CAPILLARY INVASION

‘Once governments know where to look for extralegal representations and get their hands on
them, they have found the Ariadne’s thread leading to the social contract’ (De Soto, 2000:
186)

In the water rights’ normalization process, the State and its hierarchical–legal
apparatus is not the sole, or even most important source of power. Capillary,
bottom-up power mechanisms, particularly, have a much broader range of
action, and many day-to-day normalizing mechanisms not involving the
State or its official institutions may be even more important for sustaining
and reinforcing the State system and class relations than the State institutions
themselves. Nevertheless, it would be a serious miscalculation to omit the
force and functionality of formal structures from any analysis of the water
rights game. The ‘game of the rules’ relates to official rules and rights as
much as to informal ones, and the two are intrinsically connected.
In this sense, structure versus agency debates are often highly misleading.
While legal structures cannot operate by themselves but need the forces in
society that make law work, both legal pluralism and human agency (or
‘actor-oriented’) schools sometimes underestimate the strategic force of of-
ficial structures and formal laws. Others (even Foucault in some texts) have
argued that the ancient, sovereign power of Law has been replaced by the
modern, disciplinary power of the Norm. But, at least in the Andean region
(and probably everywhere), normalizing mechanisms have not replaced for-
mal modalities; rather, they have infiltrated them from below, sometimes
undermining them but also serving as an intermediary between them, and
above all, making it possible to bring the effects to the most distant parts of
the Andean region.13 To a large extent the legal system and other official
power structures have become part of the inclusive power game, particularly
since it adopted an equalizing, liberal ideology. In a Foulcauldian sense,
wherever ‘the law’ is invaded and colonized by ‘the norm’ (normalizing
techniques and discourses), its effectiveness multiplies. Law, rather than
depending just on authoritarian power or the power of one group over an-
other, depends on the way people interact with and constitute each other as
agents and subjects of law. The more the rules are (seemingly or actually)
co-constructed by non-rulers, the greater their normalizing and subjugating
power. In cases such as that of Manyaccla, NGOs and Juntas de Usuarios
actively participate in advancing the uniform rule of state law even more
intensively in those remote places of the Andean highlands where the State
agencies lack access.

13. In his later works Foucault admitted this: ‘the power of the Norm appears through the
disciplines. Is this the new law of modern society? Let us say rather that. . . it has joined
other powers — the Law, the Word and the Text, Tradition — imposing new delimitations
upon them’ (1995: 184).
324 Rutgerd Boelens

In short, State law has continued to exert its dominating power, but unlike
colonial times, no longer as a top-down power modality: its ideology exer-
cises capillary power and invites all Andeans — white, red, black, yellow
or green — to participate ‘under equal terms’. As such it disguises the new
ways of normalizing water control, claiming to improve its effectiveness by
applying presumably objective and non-discriminatory legal codes. Indeed,
similar to Foucault’s argument, the system of law is superimposed upon the
mechanisms of discipline in such a way as to conceal its all-inclusive but
hierarchical procedures.
Despite their strategic interaction, ‘top-down/coercive power’ and ‘cap-
illary/inclusive power’ (or State law and norms-as-a-societal-force) are not
the same, and cannot be reduced to each other. It makes law into a complex
instrument of power, especially since marginalized water user groups and
indı́gena and campesino federations in Andean countries actively strive to
join in this power, and to have their customary rights ‘included’. Hybrid
and even shotgun marriages are the result in the Andean region, commonly
resulting in poor fertility and doubtful offspring in terms of effectiveness for
the subjugated population.

Back to De Soto’s Utopia: Comprehending and Including Extralegal Rights

In 2005, even before the country could provide any example of its ac-
tual functionality, Peruvian law enacted the new international fashion of
‘Payment for Environmental Services’, the latest strategy for water rights
commoditization, which entirely neglects existing water rights relationships
in Andean communities (see Isch and Gentes, 2006). It is a characteristic
phenomenon: legislators, universities and NGOs working in the field with
farmer organizations all supported this because they felt ‘they should not
remain behind and needed to be included’. Once the discursive power of
such modernist models has become effective, the ideological function of
law is to naturalize (and make obvious and morally ‘right’) these new water
rights and relations, and to bridge the gap between official norms and local
practices. More than through coercive law making, or rule imposition by the
(many) transnational institutes which actively push for this new policy, the
mechanism is to invade the consciousness of water users and redefine their
normative frames of reference and day-to-day water rules.
As I have argued, the fact that this process requires misunderstanding and
essentialization of local water arrangements should not be disregarded as
simple slip-ups or ‘off-notes’ due to misinformation. It is part of the water
power game in which Andean families, communities and their water rights
are ‘identified’ and reduced to labels. Through institutional and political
alignment, their complexes of unruliness become comprehensible. Water
rights are to be ‘equalized’, and become included and embraced through
capillary power — not necessarily as political effects that are purposely
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 325

constructed. The re-constitution of local rights and organizations in the


State’s image forms the crux of the policy effort. In this effort of subject-
formation the role of the water users themselves is quintessential. NGOs,
just like water user leaders and communities, also often play a crucial role
in this process of self-examination and self-disciplining; of denying and
reconstructing the Self by comparing and equalizing it with the Other (which
by no means implies that there is ‘no escape’ or ‘no resistance’ — quite the
contrary).14
In this sense, these legal models in the Andean countries not only preach
equality among subjects but also strive, as ‘civilized nations’, to become
equal: equal to the Western standards of modernity and progress. If we
return to De Soto’s influential policy mission, it becomes directly clear that
following the Western model has profound consequences for local rights
recognition and formalization: ‘that was basically how Western law was
built: by gradually discarding what was not useful and enforceable and
absorbing what worked’ (De Soto, 2000: 187). For De Soto, it is not the
formalization of law as such, but its importance as a means to ‘create an
orderly market’ and ‘encourage law and order’ (ibid.: 98) and therefore,
most of all, its ability to define and defend private rights. State law must
defend private rights as the way to equalization, integration and rational
order. De Soto sees private property as ‘the principle vehicle for inculcating
in the mass of the population respect for law and order and interest in the
preservation of the status quo’ (ibid.: 196). In order to produce this stability,
local hearts and minds need to be seduced to abandon their own water rights
repertoires and common laws, and instead see the need for formal law and
its defence of private, transferable rights.
According to De Soto, this process of inclusion of local rights and institu-
tions, whenever possible, is to be arranged through participatory strategies,
not by coercive State power or private agents’ violence. He closes his eyes
to the broad day-to-day resistance: ‘The most striking feature of these insti-
tutions, throughout the world, is their desire to be integrated into the formal
sector. . . The extralegals want to come in from the cold’ (2000: 178, empha-
sis added). No obligation, no force, everybody joins — the long hoped for
utopian synthesis of governors’ laws and citizens’ moral wishes, plights and
responsibilities. Or, in dystopian terms, the nightmare in which the ultimate
supremacy of obedience and disciplinary power is established: ‘the laws of
the State and the laws of the heart, at last identical’ (Foucault, 2001: 57).
The results of this neoliberal utopian dream of forging Law and Norm
in the neoliberal melting pot, according to De Soto, will be just fine: ‘Ev-
eryone will benefit from globalizing capitalism within a country, but the
most obvious and largest beneficiary will be the poor’ (2000: 190). That is,

14. As indicated at the start, this article concentrates on the (overlapping) mechanisms of water
rights’ disciplining, and will only give slight attention (see below) to the multiple resistance
strategies.
326 Rutgerd Boelens

if the incapable poor and uneducated masses can be convinced: they need
to provide the information on their extralegal arrangements, and on how to
transform and integrate their properties into the formal system. This way,
the State will have ‘the information required to integrate the poor and their
possessions into a legal framework, so that they can finally begin to have a
stake in the capitalist system’ (ibid.: 188). Indeed, it is not just ‘the poor’
who need to be included, but most of all their possessions, their minds and
their hearts.
But how to overcome potential resistance to formalization?15 This is cer-
tainly important, since ‘in Peru, for instance, the government has tried to
formalize property at least twenty-two times in the four hundred years since
Spanish conquest. Their success rate: zero’ (ibid.: 170). Therefore, the afore-
mentioned inclusive power mechanisms are put to work, that seem to ac-
knowledge local institutions but fundamentally recreate them by reifying
some presumed essences, rearranging the political–administrative frame-
work, and transforming the lines of accountability. As a result, the very
heart of local rights is invaded from below, to be absorbed by and codified
in an all-embracing framework. The quest is for an all-encompassing so-
cial contract grounded in a formal property system and built into a political
structure that appears to be anchored in people’s own legal arrangements
but which fundamentally represents the interests of international or Andean
nation-state elites.
Therefore, unlike their mono-legalist liberal or socialist predecessors who
ignored local property systems outright, a modern De Soto policy and law
maker, by contrast, recognizes legal pluralism in line with the above philos-
ophy of managed multiculturalism.16 He or she studies and embraces local
water rights and people’s living law in order, with this information, to incor-
porate these particular rules and rights and subtly squeeze them to death. Or
put euphemistically: ‘Once government obtains this information, it will be
able to explain its intent in a way the poor can understand and relate to. As a
result, they will support the agenda of reform enthusiastically. The poor will
become the most effective public relation machine for reform’ (ibid.: 199).
Indeed, not by force but by ‘educating the uneducated masses’.
What is more, if the ‘unquestionable benefits’ of formal law and the lead-
ers of property reform manage to seduce these common peoples, the latter

15. In De Soto’s analysis resistance is not seen as a broad societal protest against elite-based
control, but as a communication problem caused by: a) the ‘extralegals’ failing to understand
the benefits of uniform rights and popular capitalism; and b) local elites’ stubbornness, since
they benefit from current extralegal arrangements. The first is to be solved by education; the
second by the market itself that ‘encourages law and order, and puts money in the pockets
of the elite’ (2000: 198).
16. De Soto goes further and criticizes lawyers, particularly in the South, for not studying legal
pluralism: ‘The truth is that lawyers in these countries are generally too busy studying
Western law and adapting it. They have been taught that local practices are not genuine law
but a romantic area of study best left to folklorists’ (2000: 187).
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 327

themselves would become the intelligence-gatherers needed for State con-


trol and market expansion, critically screening their own properties: they
will organize in line with bureaucratic boundaries and criteria to enable
consultation and water development, and provide water control records ac-
cording to the standardized needs of State administration. They will relieve
and extend State functions in water governance. At least, that is the hope of
current legal modernization missionaries such as De Soto: ‘The leaders of
property reform need to describe how popular capitalism will affect many
different interest groups, show them the benefits they will derive from it,
and persuade them that it is a win-win exercise for all segments of society’
(ibid.: 204–6).

FINAL REFLECTIONS

Andean water control history has made it very clear that this claim of ‘win–
win for all’ does not materialize. Since, according to (neo)liberal ideology,
everybody is fundamentally equal, policies not only tend to disregard eco-
nomic differences (while some cultural differences may be recognized as
encapsulated, harmless and folkloric otherness) but the neoliberal State si-
multaneously refuses to actively balance societal injustice.17 Laws of supply
and demand, sanctioned by State law, become the driving force for water
management. As equals, peasant and indigenous families are supposed to
compete with large-scale farms and transnational companies in this ‘win–
win exercise’.
But Andean water user collectives and peasant-indigenous federations
have learned from the historical power game of intermittent exclusive and
inclusive discourses and, although beyond the scope of this paper, they have
formulated their multiple reactions — from local to international struggles.
At first, they demanded together with socialist-inspired labour unions the
right to equality. However, having unmasked the assimilation thinking based
on whitening and normalizing the anomalous, at a later stage they demanded
the right to be different: to rebuild their identity, not as folklore, but as
a proactive, dynamic construct. In fact, the past two decades have been
characterized by self-reorganization of Andean and indigenous identity. As
a result, they claim both the right to more equal access to resources and the
right to maintain self-sustained differences regarding the contents of their
water normative frameworks.
In their contemporary struggles, claims for recognition and redistribution
necessarily combine (Assies and Gundermann, 2007; Boelens and Gelles,
2005; Dávila and Olazával, 2006; Zwarteveen et al., 2005). Local water

17. Recent attempts by the Bolivian and Ecuadorian government to abolish neoliberal water
policies constitute important test cases. They already face tremendous resistance from
economic power groups.
328 Rutgerd Boelens

users’ organizations simultaneously contest the regimes that aim to re-


represent their cultural norms, values and organizational practices and the
unequal distribution of water and other resources. The struggle combines
diverse levels. First, in order to concretize water claims, there is a strug-
gle over the access to water and related material resources. Second, they
contest the formal definition of the rules: the contents of water rights and
management rules and the mechanisms to acquire rights. A third level of
contestation relates to the authority to make decisions and enforce rights.
Since each higher level of abstraction tends to provide legitimacy to claims
at the lower levels, the fourth and most abstract level refers to the discourses
that establish, impose or defend particular water rights policies and regimes.
The power to formulate and enforce water rights necessarily blends the four
levels (Boelens and Zwarteveen, 2005).
This multilevel battle — the struggle to defend, define and enforce local
rights systems — may be positioned within the law, outside the law or head-
to-head with the law. Within the law are the struggles: to achieve greater
justice in water access and to change current water property structures; to
obtain greater autonomy and control for internal water management; and to
recognize water rights as collective rights. Outside (or on the margins of )
the law are most rules, norms and practices that water user collectives apply
when building their own organizations and practising their own water rights.
These norms and normative structures are neither accepted nor denied by
the law. The less detailed and codified they are in legal terms, the better
they elude bureaucratic control. At the same time, this is a struggle against
those recognition policies that seek to tame this variety of rules and rights.
Struggles against the law are also often grounded in protests against assim-
ilation or integration processes, or when illegal rules are applied as outside
parties ignore or try to usurp local water rights. Often viewed and labelled
‘illegal’ by official law are the manifold mobilizations and expressions of
resistance to the imposition of outside technological, political and cultural
models.
Whereas official recognition policies and ideologies commonly serve to
simplify local complexity, align ‘unreliable’ and ‘unruly’ rights frameworks,
and subtly include and domesticate the water use communities according to
bureaucratic or market needs and images, the responses may be equally
subtle and complex. Adopting formal, uniform institutions of water con-
trol does not necessarily mean obeying (just) these rules and conforming
to them. There is a large range between ‘mimesis’ (the force and result of
imitating and aligning to the dominant models, based on either top-down
imposition or self-correcting, capillary modes of normalization) and what I
refer to as ‘mimicry’, a conscious strategy of counter-identification. Under
the surface of homogeneous rules and organizational structures that count
with official legitimacy, adopted by most communities mainly for external
representation and formal protection, user collectives harbour a tremendous
organizational and normative diversity. Often, the most powerful, durable
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 329

and effective elements — like networks of contacts, informal norms, social


positions and water-rights-in-action — can hardly be reached by official
legislation and policies. They form part of a strategic, political struggle for
counter-identification and legitimization of own authorities, which also in-
cludes the construction, by local user collectives and campesino and indı́gena
federations, of their own discourses about the meaning of ‘community’, ‘An-
dean’ and ‘indigenous’, and the construction of policies to regulate water
accordingly. In other words, openly or under the guise of sheltering and
apparent adoption of outside rules and organizational constructs, a great
diversity of local rights and hybrid norms are developed, exerted and recon-
structed, which act precisely against essentialistic containment, universalis-
tic takeover and normative colonization.

REFERENCES

Anderson, B. (1983) Imagined Communities: Reflections on the Origin and Spread of National-
ism. London: Verso.
Assies, W. (2006) ‘Reforma estatal y multiculturalismo latinoamericano al inicio del siglo XXI’,
in R. Boelens, D. Getches and A. Guevara (eds) Agua y Derecho. Polı́ticas hı́dricas, derechos
consuetudinarios e identidades locales, pp. 59–82. Lima: IEP.
Assies, W. and A. Gundermann (eds) (2007) Movimientos indı́genas y gobiernos locales en
América Latina. IWGIA, El Colegio de Michoacán, Universidad Católica del Norte. Santiago
de Chile: IIAM.
Bakker, K. (2007) ‘The “Common” versus the “Commodity”: Alter-globalization, Anti-
privatization and the Human Right to Water in the Global South,’ Antipode 39(3): 430–55.
Baud, M. (2003) Intelectuales y sus utopı́as. Indigenismo y la imaginación de América Latina.
Amsterdam: CEDLA.
von Benda-Beckmann, F. and K. von Benda-Beckmann (2001) ‘Recognizing Water Rights’, in R.
Meinzen-Dick and R. Rosegrant (eds) Overcoming Water Scarcity and Quality Constraints:
2020 Vision, Focus Brief 1. www.ifpri.org/2020/focus (accessed June 2008).
von Benda-Beckmann, F., K. von Benda-Beckmann and J. Spiertz (1998) ‘Equity and Legal
Pluralism: Taking Customary Law into Account in Natural Resource Policies’, in R. Boelens
and G. Dávila (eds) Searching for Equity. Conceptions of Justice and Equity in Peasant
Irrigation, pp. 57–69. Assen: Van Gorcum.
Bennet, V., S. Dávila-Poblete and M.N. Rico (eds) (2005) Opposing Currents. The Politics of
Water and Gender in Latin America. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press.
Boelens, R. and B. Doornbos (2001) ‘The Battlefield of Water Rights. Rule Making amidst
Conflicting Normative Frameworks in the Ecuadorian Highlands’, Human Organization
60(4): 343–55.
Boelens, R. and P. Hoogendam (eds) (2002) Water Rights and Empowerment. Assen: Van
Gorcum.
Boelens, R. and P.H. Gelles (2005) ‘Cultural Politics, Communal Resistance and Identity
in Andean Irrigation Development’, Bulletin of Latin American Research 24(3): 311–
27.
Boelens, R., I. Gentes, A. Guevara and P. Urteaga (2005) ‘Special Law: Recognition and
Denial of Diversity in Andean Water Control’, in D. Roth, R. Boelens and M. Zwarteveen
(eds) Liquid Relations, pp. 144–71. New Brunswick, NJ and London: Rutgers University
Press.
Boelens, R., D. Getches and A. Guevara (eds) (2006) Agua y Derecho: Polı́ticas hı́dricas,
derechos consuetudinarios e identidades locales. Lima: IEP.
330 Rutgerd Boelens

Boelens, R. and M. Zwarteveen (2005) ‘Prices and Politics in Andean Water Reforms’, Devel-
opment and Change 36(4): 735–58.
Bustamante, R. (2005) Normas indı́genas y consuetudinarias sobre la gestión del agua en
Bolivia. WALIR Studies Volume 10. Cochabamba: Centro Agua; Santiago: UN/CEPAL;
Wageningen: Wageningen University.
Cremers, L., M. Ooijevaar and R. Boelens (2005) ‘Institutional Reform in the Andean Irrigation
Sector: Enabling Policies for Strengthening Local Rights and Water Management’, Natural
Resources Forum 29: 37–50.
Dávila, G. and H. Olazával (2006) De la Mediación a la Movilización Social. Conflictos por el
agua en Chimborazo, Ecuador. WALIR – Interjuntas. Quito: AbyaYala.
De Soto, H. (2000) The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails
Everywhere Else. New York: Basic Books.
Fanon, F. (1963[1961]) The Wretched of the Earth. New York: Grove Press.
Foucault, M. (1977) ‘Nietzsche, Genealogy, History’, in D.F. Bouchard (ed.) Language, Counter-
Memory, Practice: Selected Essays and Interviews, pp. 1339–64. Ithaca, NY: Cornell Uni-
versity Press.
Foucault, M. (1995[1975]) Discipline and Punish: The Birth of the Prison. New York: Vintage
Books.
Foucault, M. (2001[1961]) Madness and Civilization: A History of Insanity in the Age of Reason.
London and New York: Routledge.
Gelles, P.H. (2000) Water and Power in Highland Peru: The Cultural Politics of Irrigation and
Development. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press.
Gentes, I. (2006) ‘La interacción de los derechos locales e indı́genas de agua con la legislación
chilena’, in R. Boelens, D. Getches and A. Guevara (eds) Agua y Derecho, pp. 255–84. Lima:
IEP.
Getches, D.H. (2005) ‘Defending Indigenous Water Rights with the Laws of a Dominant Culture:
The Case of the United States’, in D. Roth, R. Boelens and M. Zwarteveen (eds) Liquid
Relations, pp. 44–65. New Brunswick, NJ and London: Rutgers University Press.
Getches, D.H. (2006) Indigenous Water Rights in the United States and under International
Norms. WALIR Studies Volume 6. Boulder, CO: University of Colorado; Cusco, Peru:
UN/CEPAL; Wageningen: Wageningen University.
Guevara, A. (2006) ‘Official Water Law Versus Indigenous and Peasant Rights in Peru’, in
R. Boelens, M. Chiba and D. Nakashima (eds) Water and Indigenous Peoples, pp. 126–43.
Paris: UNESCO.
Hale, C.R. (2002) ‘Does Multiculturalism Menace? Governance, Cultural Rights and the Politics
of Identity in Guatemala’, Journal of Latin America Studies 34 (3): 485–524.
Haraway, D.J. (1991) Simians, Cyborgs and Women: The Reinvention of Nature. London: Free
Association Books.
Hendriks, J. (1998) ‘Water as Private Property. Notes on the Case of Chile’, in R. Boelens and G.
Dávila (eds) Searching for Equity: Conceptions of Justice and Equity in Peasant Irrigation,
pp. 297–310. Assen, The Netherlands: Van Gorcum.
Hendriks, J. (2006) ‘Legislación de aguas y gestión de sistemas hı́dricos en paı́ses de la región
andina’, in P. Urteaga and R. Boelens (eds) Derechos Colectivos y Polı́ticas Hı́dricas en la
Región Andina, pp. 47–112. Lima: IEP.
Ingram, H. (2008) ‘Beyond Universal Remedies for Good Water Governance: A Political and
Contextual Approach’. Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona, and Irvine, CA: University of
California at Irvine. http://rosenberg.ucanr.org/documents/V%20Ingram.pdf
Isch, E. and I. Gentes (eds) (2006) Agua y servicios ambientales. Visiones crı́ticas desde los
Andes. Quito: AbyaYala.
Mayer, E. (2002) The Articulated Peasant: Household Economies in the Andes. Boulder, CO
and Oxford: Westview Press.
Paniagua, H. (2005) ‘La ley de proyectos y percepciones campesinas de derechos de agua en un
sistema de riego andino’. Research document. Wageningen: Wageningen University.
The Politics of Disciplining Water Rights 331

Perreault, T. (2006) ‘Escalas socio-espaciales, reestructuración del Estado y la gobernanza


neoliberal del agua en Bolivia’, in R. Boelens, D. Getches and A. Guevara (eds) Agua y
Derecho, pp. 285–320. Lima: IEP.
Ploeg, Jan Douwe van der (2006) El Futuro Robado: Tierra, agua y lucha campesina. Lima:
IEP.
Roth, D., R. Boelens and M. Zwarteveen (eds) (2005) Liquid Relations: Contested Water Rights
and Legal Complexity. New Brunswick, NJ and London: Rutgers University Press.
Stavenhagen, R. (2002) ‘Indigenous Peoples and the State in Latin America: An Ongoing
Debate’, in R. Sieder (ed.) Multiculturalism in Latin America: Indigenous Rights, Diversity
and Democracy, pp. 24–44. Basingstoke and NewYork: Palgrave Macmillan.
de Vos, H., R. Boelens and R. Bustamante (2006) ‘Formal Law and Local Water Control in
the Andean Region: A Fiercely Contested Field,’ International Journal of Water Resources
Development 22(1): 37–48.
WALIR (2007) Pluralismo Legal, Reforma Hı́drica y Polı́ticas de Reconocimiento. WALIR
Studies Vol 13. Cusco, Peru: UN/CEPAL; Wageningen: Wageningen University.
Zwarteveen, M., D. Roth and R. Boelens (2005) ‘Water Rights and Legal Pluralism: Beyond
Analysis and Recognition’, in D. Roth, R. Boelens and M. Zwarteveen (eds) Liquid Relations:
Contested Water Rights and Legal Complexity, pp. 254–68. New Brunswick, NJ and London:
Rutgers University Press.

Rutgerd Boelens is Senior Researcher at Wageningen University, The


Netherlands and Co-ordinator of the international research networks Water
Law and Indigenous Rights (WALIR), Concertación and La Justicia Hı́drica.
In books, articles and films, he has widely published on the linkages between
water rights and justice, legal pluralism, water policy reforms, cultural poli-
tics and power relations. He can be contacted at [email protected]

You might also like