Acquiring The Habit of Changing Governments Through Elections
Acquiring The Habit of Changing Governments Through Elections
net/publication/273214017
CITATIONS READS
50 1,566
1 author:
Adam Przeworski
New York University
222 PUBLICATIONS 28,532 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
All content following this page was uploaded by Adam Przeworski on 20 November 2015.
Article
Comparative Political Studies
2015, Vol. 48(1) 101–129
Acquiring the Habit of © The Author(s) 2014
Reprints and permissions:
Changing Governments sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0010414014543614
Through Elections cps.sagepub.com
Adam Przeworski1
Abstract
Changing governments through elections is a rare and a recent practice.
Yielding office the first time is foreboding because it entails the risk that
the gesture would not be reciprocated, but the habit develops rapidly once
the first step is taken. This article provides evidence for these assertions by
examining about 3,000 elections in the world since 1788.
Keywords
elections, democracy, regimes
Giving away votes to unworthy people, to the irrational passions of the parties
. . . is a suicide for a ruler and I will not commit suicide before a chimera.
—Domingo Santa María, the President of Chile between 1881 and 1886,
quoted in Collier and Sater (1996, p. 58).
We are not going to give up our country for a mere X on a ballot. How can a
ballpoint fight with a gun?
—Robert Mugabe, President of Zimbabwe.
Introduction
In a democracy, incumbent governments risk office in elections and yield it
when they lose. Why? The answer cannot be “because it is a democracy,” as
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
102 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
the vast literature on elections in various regimes tautologically has it. True,
in the few lucky countries in which most political scientists happen to live,
partisan alternation in office through elections has become so routinized that
it appears as only natural. Parties offer platforms and personalities, people
vote, votes are counted, someone is declared the winner, the winner enters
unimpeded the White, Pink, or Blue House, and this sequence of events is
repeated at regular intervals. We can take it for granted, so we do. Yet exam-
ining history, one is struck how difficult it is for rulers to place their power at
risk in elections, to trust that if they do so their actions would be reciprocated,
to feel safe that they can lose office without losing much else, that political
conflicts can be processed with limited stakes. The historical facts are elo-
quent: While the first partisan alternation in history occurred, albeit painfully,
in the United States as early as in 1801, the phenomenon has been rare until
very recently. Still, as of 2008, 68 countries, including the 2 elephants, China
and Russia, never experienced a peaceful transfer of power between parties
as a result of an election.
In a democracy, incumbents expose themselves to the possibility of defeat
and yield office with full confidence that their opponents would do the same
if they become the rulers. This equilibrium may be sustained by the possibil-
ity that deviations—not holding competitive elections or not obeying their
outcomes—would provoke costly conflicts (as in Fearon, 2011, or Przeworski,
2005) but to relinquish the reigns of power all successive incumbents must
believe that the current opposition would reciprocate if it wins an election
and becomes the incumbent in turn. This belief is easy to sustain when the
past incumbent had already yielded office having lost an election. But how is
one to know what would happen if he loses an election when nothing of the
sort ever happened before? It may not have happened because no elections
were held, because the opposition was not allowed to compete effectively, or
only because voters freely kept the incumbent in office. But whatever the
reasons, the prospect of defeat is a plunge into unknown. Will the defeated
incumbents survive intact, as political contenders with a prospect of some
day returning to office, or do they risk death, imprisonment, or exile, personal
as well as political annihilation?
When I once commented to a Polish communist reformer that if the regime
would hold a competitive election it would lose, his response was “What mat-
ters is not whether we would win or lose but what we would lose.” This
“what” is quintessential. When incumbents fear that an electoral defeat may
mean a loss of life, freedom, or even just fortune, their risk is just too high
(see Makarenko, in press, on “tolerable uncertainty”). And such fears may be
grounded. The fact that most rulers who did expose themselves to defeat and
lost were not punished1 is not informative: Only those among them who do
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 103
not expect to be punished would take this risk. Neither safeguards nor assur-
ances are enough: Before holding the plebiscite of 1989, the Chilean military
protected itself by all kinds of institutional devices and amnesty laws, yet
many still ended in jail. In Central African Republic, General Kolinga, who
took office by a coup in 1981 and got himself elected in 1986, was pressured
to hold a competitive election in 1992 and lost to Ange-Félix Patassé, who
promptly stripped Kolinga of his military rank and persecuted several of his
ministers. In Malawi, Hastings Banda, who was in power for 27 years, lost an
election in 1994, only to be arrested and charged with murder allegedly com-
mitted 10 years earlier. Several post-military countries in Latin America
relentlessly persecute violators of human rights while post-communist gov-
ernments incessantly invent new “lustration” laws to harass anyone suspected
of having collaborated with the previous regime.2
Releasing the reigns of power is like letting go of the trapeze without
knowing whether one would be caught, a matter of belief about someone
else’s good faith, of trust. Put yourself in the shoes of General Pinochet, the
Polish Communists in 1989, South African Whites in 1994, the Algerian mili-
tary in 1991, or President Putin today. If you allow elections to be competi-
tive, lose, and yield office, what will the winners do to you? After all, the
opposition does not just want to defeat you but to destroy you: It accuses you
of breaking laws, of amassing a fortune; in the case of Putin even of having
bombed a Moscow building as a pretext to intensify the Chechen war. The
risk is foreboding.
One may think, however, that people learn from experience. The incum-
bent may fear that the opposition would exact a revenge if it is victorious but
the victorious opposition will have already seen that the incumbent did
release its hold on power. It may still well be that a party that yielded office
once would not do it the next time: Individuals involved may not be the same,
circumstances may change. Moreover, an entire sequence of elections may
occur peacefully, with or without alternations, and then some exogenous
event may lead to a coup, usurpation of power by the current incumbent, civil
war, or some other constitutional irregularity. Nevertheless, having gone
through alternation once should at least assuage the fears.
If this argument is correct, the first alternation should be difficult and rare
but the probability that governments would be selected through elections
should increase sharply once one had transpired. And when more alternations
occur, future conflicts should be more likely to be processed by elections,
rather than by force. This is indeed what the historical patterns indicate.
Periods in which no alternation had yet occurred are unlikely to witness one
in any subsequent election and not very likely to experience one at all, ending
in some form of a violent conflict. Incumbents are highly unlikely to lose an
election and are quite prone to disobey the verdict of the polls when they do
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
104 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
lose. Once the first alternation does occur, however, electoral defeats become
much more frequent and the rate of compliance increases, so that the electoral
mechanism becomes entrenched.
The aim of this analysis is to identify the conditions under which incum-
bents are willing to lose elections and yield office, the events adding up to a
partisan alternation in office through elections, “alternation” for short. Note
that alternations need not coincide with transitions to democracy; indeed,
they rarely do coincide. While alternations are a sine qua non of democracy,
transitions to democracy need not entail alternations: Most transitions
occurred when authoritarian rulers were overthrown by force. Conversely,
most alternations took place when previous elections were already
competitive.
The remainder of this article first provides historical background on the
outcomes of national-level elections in the world after 1788, based on the
Political Institutions and Political Events (PIPE; Przeworski, 2013) data col-
lection and delves into the conceptual relation between alternations and tran-
sitions to democracy. A simple analytical formulation elucidates the choices
confronting successive incumbents. First alternations within particular spells
of continuously held elections are then analyzed. With these initial condi-
tions, analysis moves to the dynamic of subsequent alternations and their
impact on the survival of the electoral mechanism. A summary and conclu-
sion close the article.
Background
Elections may or may not be contested. When they are contested, incumbents
may win or lose and the winners, whether the incumbent or the opposition,
may or may not assume office. The distribution of these outcomes is por-
trayed in Figure 1, which covers most national-level elections in the world
between 1788 and 2008 in which there was an incumbent which presented
itself in the election. The incumbent may be a person, or a party, or a succes-
sor designated by the government in place. Elections are contested if there is
more than one candidate for president in presidential systems or when voters
in at least some districts have a choice of candidates or lists in legislative
elections.3
Of the 2,886 elections in which there was some kind of incumbent, in
656 / 2,886 = 0.23 there was no opposition. Incumbents won (2,210 + 116) /
2,886 = 0.81 of all elections, obviously all in which there was no opposition
but also (1,497 + 73) / 2,230 = 0.70 of those that were contested. In (43 + 73
+ 57) / 2,886 = 0.06 elections, the winner, whether the incumbent or the
opposition, did not end up in office. Finally, in 603 / 2,886 = 0.21 elections,
incumbents lost and peacefully yielded office to the winners.
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 105
Election Held
Incumbent Challenger
Wins Wins
Periods in which any kind of elections are held regularly, without being
interrupted by coups, autocoups, civil wars, or other major constitutional
irregularities, constitute “electoral spells.”4 An electoral spell begins when
someone is elected for the first time, either the first time in the history of a
country or after someone grabbed power by force.5 Among the 423 electoral
spells that ever began, 156 continued until an alternation. The rest either con-
tinued until the country was last observed or were interrupted by a constitu-
tional breakdown. An “alternation” is considered to have occurred if (a) the
incumbent, however he originally entered office but was already elected,
presents itself in an election and (b) the party or the person of the chief execu-
tive changes as a result of an election.6 Also included are instances in which
there are no formally constituted parties but a manifest government candidate.7
The winner of the election must enter the office without anyone else attempting
to squeeze in before and must hold office at least for 1 year or until the next
election, whichever comes first, but not necessarily the entire constitutional
term.8 The result on an election is “obeyed” when these conditions are satisfied;
it is not obeyed when the losing incumbent attempts to hold onto office or the
defeated opposition tries to force its way into office. Note that alternation is a
conjunction of two events: The incumbent lost and the result was obeyed.
While Przeworski (1991) defines democracy as a “system in which parties
lose elections” (p. 11), and while everyone agrees that the occurrence of alter-
nations is the litmus test of democracy, the conceptual relation between tran-
sitions to democracy and alternations is complex. Transitions to democracy
occur when the first competitive election is held after a period in which elec-
tions were not held or were uncontested or were so rigged that the opposition
had no chance to win. Most transitions occurred not when the authoritarian
rulers held competitive elections but when they were overthrown by the use or
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
106 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Incumbent Incumbent
runs loses Transition Alternation Example
Previously elections were
No — No No Georgia, 2004
Contested Yes No No No Botswana, 1964-to date
Yes Yes No Yes Luxembourg, 1974
threat of force. Hence, many transitions do not entail alternation, while most
alternations occur when the regime is already democratic.
As shown in Table 1, transitions and alternations coincide only in the cases
in which previous elections were uncontested, the former incumbent pre-
sented itself in first contested elections, lost, and obeyed, as is in Brazil in
1985 as well as Hungary and Poland in 1989. Because an alternation can
occur only if the current ruler was elected, no alternation can occur if elec-
tions were not previously held, as in Argentina before 1983 or Ghana before
1992. Alternation also cannot occur unless the formerly elected incumbent
presents itself (which excludes Niger in 1993) and it does not occur when the
forces that have supported the dictatorship present themselves and win, as in
Spain in 1977 or Mongolia in 1990. In turn, transition does not occur if previ-
ous election(s) were contested, whether an alternation takes place, as in
Luxembourg in 1974, or the same party continues to win, as in Botswana
from the independence in 1964 until the present.
The Argument
I hesitate to call the argument that follows a “model” because it is just a math-
ematically adorned restatement of the verbal reasoning. Nevertheless, formu-
lating the argument in the mathematical language does elucidate the choices
available to incumbent rulers.
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 107
Each incumbent faces at each time a choice between two lotteries. In one,
he can hold elections which he cannot lose or not hold them at all, facing the
possibility of being removed by force. In the second, he lets the voters decide.
Let q be the probability that an incumbent who assures himself of not being
defeated in an election survives in power for one period (measured in electoral
terms). Let the one-period utility of surviving in office be U(w) and the utility of
being deposed by force be U(d). The expected value of the first lottery is then
EV ( q ) = qV ( w ) + (1 − q )V ( d ) , (1)
where V (.) are the expected present values, discounted flows of future util-
ity, associated with each outcome.
In the second lottery, the incumbent holds an election which he may lose.
What the incumbent does not know is what would happen if he does lose:
With probability θ , he may be treated just as a future electoral opponent,
obtaining V (l ) , and with probability 1− θ , he may experience the same fate
as if he were deposed by force: death, imprisonment, or exile. Let p be the
probability that the incumbent wins an election. The expected value of the
electoral lottery is9
EV ( p ) = pV ( w ) + (1 − p ) θV ( l ) + (1 − θ )V ( d ) , (2)
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
108 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
loses he would be treated just as a future electoral opponent, he opts for the
electoral lottery even if p < q , specifically if
p−q V (l ) − V ( d )
> −θ ≡ −θα < 0, (3)
1− p V ( w) − V ( d )
or as long as
q − θα
p> ≡ p* ( q, θ, α ) , (4)
1 − θα
V (l ) − V ( d )
where α = is the value of being in opposition relative to being
in office. V ( w ) − V ( d )
This condition is portrayed in Figure 2. When θ = 0 , the ruler holds com-
petitive elections only if p > q . As θ increases, he is willing to hold them
even if he has little of a chance to win; indeed, when α is sufficiently high,
even if he is certain to lose. This is because losing an election is not that much
of a disaster, obviously worse than winning it but far better than physical and
political annihilation. It is not whether the incumbent would lose but what he
would lose that matters.
This condition does not guarantee, however, that the incumbent would
obey the verdict of the polls if he loses. I leave open the possibility than he
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 109
might not obey because, as shown below (Table 5), among the 168 instances
in which an incumbent lost an election for the first time within a particular
spell in 29 of them, the winner was not able to assume office. It is reasonable,
however, to assume that an electoral defeat results in a loss of the incum-
bent’s power to impose himself by force, so that when the incumbent loses an
election q falls to some level q’ . One might think, with Geddes (2005) or
Simpser (2013), that an electoral defeat signals that the incumbent is not pop-
ular or at least that it does not control the state apparatus necessary to manip-
ulate the outcomes of elections, so that he is less likely to impose himself by
force. Alternatively, one might follow Przeworski, Rivero, and Xi (2014) in
thinking that at least some of those who bear arms are constitutionalists,
ready to obey a duly elected government.
The condition to obey an electoral defeat is then that the expected value of
being in electoral opposition, θV (l ) + (1 − θ)V (d ) , is larger than the expected
value of imposing oneself by force with q’ < q , which is q’V ( w) + (1 − q’ )V (d ).
This condition is satisfied as long as q’ < θα and it still does allow the pos-
sibility that the incumbent would not obey an electoral defeat.
Suppose now that the first alternation had occurred: The incumbent ran an
election with p < 1 , lost, obeyed, and the opposition is in office. The winner
faces the same choice between the two lotteries as the previous incumbent.
The difference, however, is that the winner knows that the defeated incum-
bent revealed himself to be of the type who allows himself to lose. Thus, he
can now believe that θ = 1 . Assume that the distribution of partisan support
does not change in the first period after the alternation had occurred,12 with
p still characterizing the defeated incumbent. The expected value of the
electoral lottery for the winner is then
EV (1 − p ) = (1 − p )V ( w ) + pV ( l ) , (5)
( ) ( )
EV 1 − q’ = 1 − q’ V ( w ) + q’V ( d ) , (6)
V ( w) − V ( d )
p < q’ = q’ / (1 − α ) ,
V ( w) − V (l ) (7)
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
110 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
that is, as long as the former incumbent is not highly likely to return to office
in the next election.
Now, the incumbent must anticipate that if q’ / (1 − α) ≤ p < 1 and by
some fluke he happens to lose, the winner will not reciprocate by holding a
competitive election. Yet, as long as q < 1 , the incumbent still holds elections
with p < 1 . This case can occur only when α < 1− q’ , so that being in oppo-
sition is costly, but the incumbent expects to win (1 − p ) −1 consecutive elec-
tions, and because p is high, the prospect of the defeat materializing is
distant.
∗
Proposition 1a: If p > p , the incumbent in a spell that never experi-
enced an alternation holds elections with p < 1 ; otherwise, he does not
hold elections or assures himself of electoral victory.
Proposition 1b: When elections are held with p < 1 and the incumbent
loses, he obeys if q’ < θα and does not yield office otherwise.
Proposition 1c: If the incumbent loses and obeys, the winner reciprocates
by holding competitive elections if p < q’ / (1 − α) and does not hold elec-
tions or assures himself of victory otherwise.
Proof: It follows from the above, except for the claim that the incumbent
holds elections with p∗ < p < 1 even if the winner would not hold elec-
tions or assured himself of victory, the proof of which is in the appendix.
The comparative statics are obvious. For any q , a lower p is required for
the first incumbent to hold a competitive election as either α or θ increases.
In turn, the second incumbent is more inclined to reciprocate as α increases.
First Alternations
The first alternation in history took place in the United States following a
deeply divisive election of 1800 (about which Dunn, 2004; Weisberger,
2000). In Great Britain, the first alternation occurred in 1835 when the king
accepted the electoral victory of the Liberals. The first alternation in Latin
America was in New Granada (now Colombia) in 1837: General Santander,
who believed that the country was not ready for a civilian chief executive,
supported General Obando to be his successor, yet a civilian, Dr. José Ignacio
de Márquez won the plurality of electoral votes and the Congress confirmed
his victory (Posada Carbó, 2000). According to Bushnell (1993), “Santander
then delivered his office to someone he had opposed—taking pains to point
out, in a proclamation, that he had thus respected the will of the people and
the law of the land” (p. 90).13
As shown in Table 2, 19 countries experienced at least one alternation
before 1900, but only in 8 or 9 of them (depending how one thinks of Vichy
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 111
Italic fonts indicate that coups, civil wars, or other constitutional breakdowns occurred
between the previous alternation and the date appearing in italics.
France) control over the office of the chief executive alternated peacefully
without interruption by coups or civil wars from then on.
Elections preceding the first alternations were contested everywhere
except for Argentina before 1868 and Costa Rica before 1889. In turn, in
Dominican Republic in 1849 and Spain in 1857, elections in which first alter-
nations occurred were preceded by coups. Hence, these are the cases in which
alternations constituted transitions to democracy. In all other cases, contested
elections were held regularly before the first alternation happened to
transpire.
In almost all instances, victory of the opposition met with considerable
resistance. Jefferson may have prevailed only as a consequence of Madison’s
threat to mobilize the Virginia militia (Dunn, 2004). In Colombia, the defeated
candidate, General Obando, rose against President Márquez 2 years later, but
was defeated. In Great Britain, the king appointed a Tory prime minister in
spite of the Tory electoral defeat in 1834 and only the second victory of the
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
112 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 113
a. The legislature was temporarily closed in 1841, otherwise the continuity would be dated
back to 1831, with the duration of 60 years.
b. Control over government alternated regularly between two parties but alternations always
occurred before elections and governments newly chosen by the King never lost.
and Japan smell democratic and are invariably considered as such but Mexico,
Taiwan, and Botswana are generally seen as authoritarian. To call the cases in
which elections are pluralistic but the opposition never wins “hybrid” is just
an admission of the inability to decide. Przeworski, Alvarez, Cheibub, and
Limongi (2000) coped with this issue by using a retrospective rule to classify
as democratic periods of continued rule of the same party whenever an alter-
nation subsequently occurred under the same rules of competition. But they
also threw their hands up in the air when history was not kind enough to
generate this event and the electoral spell was right-hand censored, as in
Botswana. Geddes, Wright, and Frantz (2013, Section 1.3) claim that their
coding rules resolve this conundrum by classifying as autocracies regimes in
which rulers came into power by “any means besides direct, reasonably fair,
competitive elections.” But in the end, one still wonders on what grounds
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
114 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 115
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
116 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 117
Kenya, the democratic opposition talked to the military, who then organized
a national day of honoring the retirement of President Moi, against his will.
Such random events inflate the errors of regressions but they are crucial in
overcoming the incumbents’ fear of the consequences of leaving power.
When a person, a party, or a clique had been in power for decades, their priors
are so uninformative that anything, even a minor event, can alter beliefs. And
beliefs are all that the incumbents can rely on to decide whether to put their
future at stake in elections.
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
118 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Past Number of
alternations electionsa Pr(lost) Pr(obey) Pr(obey|lost) Pr(alternation)
0 1,221 0.14 0.95 0.83 0.12
1 353 0.33 0.94 0.88 0.30
2 162 0.47 0.96 0.95 0.45
3 102 0.44 0.94 0.93 0.42
>3 413 0.41 1.00 1.00 0.41
Total 2,251 0.24 0.96 0.91 0.22
Spells which experience an alternation during the first election are considered here as having
one past alternation.
a. This is the number of elections that took place but the base of each probability is slightly
lower given that the information about the final outcome is not always available.
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 119
Table 6. The Probability That at Least One More Alternation Will Occur Within
a Spell Given the Number of Past Alternations Within a Spell.
Past Pr(continue|
alternations Spells with Censored Broke Pr(broke)a uncensored)b
0 423 53 214 0.51 0.42
1 156 27 26 0.18 0.79
2 102 17 13 0.13 0.85
3 72 25 5 0.07 0.89
4 42 10 4 0.10 0.88
5 28 4 1 0.04 0.96
6 23 4 1 0.04 0.95
>6 18 18 0 0.00 1.00
All spells, including those in which alternation occurs in the first election within the spell,
are considered to have begun with zero past alternations. Hence, 423 is the total number of
spells.
a. Pr(broke) = Number of spells that ended unconstitutionally/Number of spells with a given
number of past alternations.
b. Pr(continue|uncensored) = Number of spells with one more alternation/Uncensored
number of spells with a given number of past alternations. This is the probability that at least
one more alternation would occur within a particular spell.
In Chile in 1924, Costa Rica in 1948, Ecuador in 2000, Germany in 1933, and
Thailand in 2000, electoral spells ended after three alternations; in Portugal
in 1870, Sri Lanka in 1982, Norway in 1940, and Philippines in 1972 after
four; in Chile in 1973 after five; and in Italy in 1922 after six. One might want
to eliminate Italy from this list because alternations were an outcome of an
agreement between parties,27 and one might want to drop Norway because
the constitutional breakdown was accompanied by the German invasion. But
if we were to include France in 1940 (the Vichy regime), the threshold would
have been nine.28 Hence, the number of past alternations that makes the elec-
toral mechanism immune to constitutional breakdowns is somewhere
between five and nine. Nevertheless, the effect of past alternations on the
survival of the electoral mechanism is powerful.
Probit regressions of breakdowns on the number of past alternations
within the particular spell (sum past alt), the electoral history of the country
(electoral spell), and per capita income (gdpcap) or year, presented in Table 7,
confirm that past alternations within the current spell increase the likelihood
that it would continue. In concordance with Przeworski et al. (2000), past
constitutional breakdowns increase the probability that the current electoral
spell would break as well, which suggests that analyses that ignore past his-
tory suffer form an omitted variable bias.29 Finally, as in analyses of regime
transitions, higher income makes constitutional breakdowns less likely.
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
120 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Country spell clustered errors. With cubic polynomial of electoral age, not shown. lroc =
area under the receiver operating curve.
a. “Effect” is the partial derivative or difference.
**significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 121
occurred, breakdowns occurred in 0.0343 of the 3,814 years but after a sin-
gle alternation only in 0.0115 of the 4,094 years, t = 6.75, p(t) = .0000. To
summarize these numbers, observe that a breakdown occurs on the average
once in every 19.8 years when there are no elections, once in 24.7 when elec-
tions are held without opposition, once in 46.1 years when opposition is
allowed, and once in 87.0 years after a single alternation occurred. Hence,
while elections of any kind do prevent violent conflicts and contested elec-
tions increase this protection, a single experience of having witnessed a gov-
ernment changing as a result of people’s choice provides almost perfect
immunity from political violence.
Conclusion
The main conclusion of this analysis is that competitive elections are a self-
institutionalizing mechanism. Elections are a method of processing conflicts,
one among several possible. Contending political forces channel their efforts
into electoral competition rather than engage in violence when elections offer
them real prospects of prevailing at some time in the future, when govern-
ments can change as a consequence of elections. The first experience of elec-
tions in which the incumbent rulers subject themselves to the verdict of the
people, lose, and peacefully leave office has a powerful effect on shaping the
beliefs about these prospects: It almost doubles the probability that peaceful
electoral competition will continue indefinitely. Moreover, this effect holds
independently of political, economic, or social conditions, at least of those
that could be considered. Thus, a single experience of partisan alternation in
office as a result of elections goes a long way to consolidate democracy.
While once acquired the habit of changing governments through elections
is durable, it is not easy to acquire. Letting go of power for the first time is
extremely difficult. Wading through untreaded waters, rulers do not know
what else they would lose if they lose office, how deeply they would sink.
This uncertainty is reduced with each successive alternation, so that incum-
bents become willing to expose themselves to losing elections and to yield
office when they lose. Random events still intervene to generate constitu-
tional breakdowns even when political leaders had already learned to risk
their power in elections but after some number of alternations the habit
becomes safely entrenched.
This dynamic is reflected in the fact that, as shown in Figure 3, 81 out of
204 countries that existed at any time after 1918 and 68 out of 188 observed
as of 2008 never experienced an alternation, while countries that experienced
at least one went on to repeat the experience.
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
122 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
The countries where the habit became entrenched are familiar: The United
States experienced 23 alternations, the United Kingdom and the Netherlands
22, followed by Denmark, Sweden, New Zealand, Finland, Iceland, Belgium,
Costa Rica, Australia, Ireland, and France. The newcomers are the 57
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 123
Appendix
Proof
When q / (1 − α) < 1 , the winner does not hold competitive elections if
’
( )
pV ( w ) + (1 − p ) E q’ > E ( q ) , (8)
q q
where E ( ) = V (d ) + ( )(V ( w) − V (d )) , where q applies to the ex ante
q’ q’
and q to the ex post lottery that occurs when the current ruler does not hold
’
competitive elections.
Substitutions show that the incumbent holds competitive elections when-
ever the winner would not if
q − q’
p> ≡ p’ . (9)
1 − q’
Comparing the two thresholds yields p’ > p∗ ⇔ θα > q’ . But if
∗
p > 0, θα > q and because q > q’ , it is always true that p’ > p∗ . In turn, it
q q − q’
is apparent that 1 − α > 1 − q’ (given that this inequality is true for α = 0 ).
∗
Hence, the incumbent holds competitive elections when p < p < q / (1 − α)
and the winner reciprocates when p’ < q / (1 − α) < p and the winner does
not hold elections or assures himself of victory.
Acknowledgments
I appreciate comments by Abel Escribà, Joanne Fox-Przeworski, Bert Hoffmann,
Fernando Limongi, Frédéric Louault, Pasquale Pasquino, Gonzalo Rivero, Rubén
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
124 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Ruiz-Rufino, Ian Shapiro, Tianyang Xi, the editors of this journal, as well as anony-
mous reviewers.
Author’s Note
The original data and the Stata replication files are available at https://sites.google.
com/a/nyu.edu/adam-przeworski/
Funding
The author received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publica-
tion of this article.
Notes
1. Wright and Escribà Folch (2012) count that between 1946 and 2004 of the 199
rulers of autocratic leaders who lost office when regimes became democratic,
93 met with violent death, imprisonment, or exile. Geddes, Wright, and Frantz
(2014) report that of the 100 transitions to democracy between 1946 and 2010, in
40 cases the outgoing rulers suffered death, jail, or exile. These counts include,
however, the cases in which the incumbents were overthrown by force. Goemans
(2008), in turn, distinguishes leaders who lost office according to the rules of any
regime, among whom 8% were killed, jailed, or exiled within 1 year, and those
who left under the threat or the use of force, among whom 80% suffered this fate.
Counting only the 28 cases in which autocratic incumbents lost elections, only 3
were punished within 1 year (Abel Escribà, personal communication, April 24,
2014.), but some were jailed later.
2. Nalepa (2010) observes that actual punishments were rare after the fall of com-
munism. Nevertheless, many people were and still are prosecuted, temporarily
deprived of political rights, or found unfit to occupy public positions.
3. With minor exception of instances where political parties agreed to a unique can-
didate (as in Chile in 1891). Elections in which there was one organized party and
independent candidates (as in Portugal in 1954) are not considered contested.
4. Electoral spells must experience at least two consecutive elections in which the
winner of the first one assumed and completed the term in office, regardless
of what happened after the second election. Included in the analysis that fol-
lows are all spells that began after a country became independent and those ini-
tiated before independence if at least two consecutive elections occurred after
independence.
5. For example, in Malawi, Dr. Hastings Banda was elected in 1966 and upon being
reelected in 1970 proclaimed himself president for life, not holding elections
until 1994, when he presented himself and lost.
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 125
6. Note that this definition biases upward the count of events considered as alterna-
tions because it includes instances in which the governing coalition remained
the same but the person and the party of the prime minister changed. In parlia-
mentary systems, partisan control often changes hands between elections. Such
events are not considered alternations here.
7. Changes between non-partisan, “caretaker” or “technical” governments, and par-
tisan ones are not considered alternations.
8. There were 18 instances in which victorious opposition assumed office but only
after either the defeated incumbents attempted to hold onto power or some third
party attempted to squeeze into office: they are not counted as alternations. Note
that alternations are dated in the year in which the relevant election occurred, not
the year new government assumed office.
9. For simplicity, I ignore the possibility that a ruler elected in competitive elections
may also be deposed by force. While such events do occur, holding an election
sharply reduces the probability of coups. See below.
10. The most recent anecdote is provided by the October 6, 2013, election in
Azerbaijan, where election results were inadvertently released before voting
took place ( www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/worldviews/wp/2013/10/09/). For
different “menus of manipulation,” see Posada-Carbó (2000), Lehoucq (2002),
Mozaffar and Schedler (2002), and Hyde (2011).
11. This assumption is buttressed by the fact that predicted probabilities of incum-
bents winning are bimodal, with one peak around p = .65 and the second around
p = .95, regardless of the specification of the regression equation.
12. One could assume that the incumbent and the potential opposition update their
beliefs about p and θ depending on the outcomes of elections, with θ adjust-
ing gradually rather than jumping to 1. I do not develop this model because the
results would be qualitatively the same.
13. Posada-Carbó (2008) points out the contrast with the events in Venezuela 2 years
earlier: “Although in Venezuela President Páez’s favourite, General Soublette,
also lost at the polls and Páez handed in power to the victor, Dr José M. Vargas
-a civilian-, the latter was ousted seven months later, when Páez returned to
the presidency and then practically ruled Venezuela for the next two decades”
(p. 31).
14. Geddes et al. (2014) as well as Escribà Folch (2014) show that the proportion
of autocratic rulers who were punished in various ways differs depending on
whether the autocracy was monarchic, personalist, military, or single-party.
15. Of the 32 constitutional monarchies, only 9 survived by allowing alternations:
Belgium, Denmark, Japan (where the Emperor lost even nominal executive
power in 1947), Lesotho (where the monarch lost executive power in 1993),
the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden (where the monarch lost executive power in
1974), Thailand, and the United Kingdom.
16. Interestingly, in 1935, Stalin wanted elections to be direct, based on universal
suffrage, secret, and open to competition, arguing that because class enemies had
been eradicated, the Communists have nothing to fear from contested elections.
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
126 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
The intra-party elections in 1936 took place under these rules but the communist
cadres persuaded Stalin that popular elections were too dangerous and the 1937
elections were uncontested (see Getty, 1991; Schlögel, 2014).
17. A direct passage from uncontested elections to competition in which they incum-
bent had presented itself, lost, and yielded office has been rare. Elections had
been previously contested in all the 36 monarchies that experienced the first
alternation, in 57 out of 62 parliamentary republics, and in 50 out of 61 presi-
dential systems, in total in 143 cases, 92% of 156 first transitions.Note again that
if the party that ruled unopposed does not present itself in the first competitive
election, there can be no alternation: by definition, an alternation can occur only
if the incumbent competes in an election.
18. The reasoning here, based on the ideas of Przeworski (2005) and Benhabib and
Przeworski (2006), is that if utility is concave in income, losing income matters
less to the losers when the country income is high. Specifically, if the utility of
1− σ
income is Constant Relative Risk Aversion (CRRA), U ( yi ) = yi , σ > 1,
1− σ
and winners obtain a larger multiple of average income than losers, the utility
difference between winning and losing declines in average income. The best
illustrations of the role of income are the elections in Costa Rica in 1948 and in
the United States in 2000: In both, the outcome was a technical draw, after which
the Congress in Costa Rica and the Supreme Court in the United States awarded
the victory to one of the candidates. The result in Costa Rica was a bloody civil
war, while in the United States supporters of the loser just drove their SUVs
back home to cultivate their gardens. The difference was that they had SUVs
and gardens.
19. In Latin America, during most of the 19th century, the “military” were landown-
ers calling themselves “generals,” who rode into presidential palaces accom-
panied by their peones, whom they called “soldiers,” but who never followed
institutionalized military careers. I do not know if that makes them “personalistic
militaries,” so I prefer to stay away from this term.
20. For example, Lt. Col. Mathieu Kérékou grabbed office by a coup in Benin in
1972 and had himself elected and reelected without opposition several times
until 1991, when he held a competitive election, lost, and yielded office, only to
be elected again in 1996 and reelected in 2001. He is classified as having entered
office by force in 1972 and constitutionally in 1996.
21. These analyses have been replicated with a random effects logit estimator. The
results are not reported because they are almost identical.
22. The average within-country correlation of year and gdpcap is .57.
23. I also examined the role of the extent of suffrage, measured alternatively on
an ordinal scale or by the proportion of the population eligible to vote, to find
that it has no statistically significant effect. Finally, expecting that the incum-
bent would have more to lose in unequal societies, I performed heroic efforts
to introduce inequality (measured in the earlier period by proportion of family
farms—from Vanhanen, 1997) and in the later period by interpolated values of
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 127
References
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J. A., & Yared, P. (2008). Income and democ-
racy. American Economic Review, 98, 808-842.
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J. A., & Yared, P. (2009). Reevaluating the
modernization hypothesis. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56, 1043-1058.
Banks, A. (2005). Cross-National Time Series Data Archive. Retrieved from www.
databanksinternational.com
Benhabib, J., & Przeworski, A. (2006). The political economy of redistribution under
democracy. Economic Theory, 29, 271-290.
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
128 Comparative Political Studies 48(1)
Boix, C., & Stokes, S. C. (2003). Endogenous democratization. World Politics, 55,
517-549.
Bushnell, D. (1993). The making of modern Colombia. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Carter, D. B., & Signorino, C. S. (2010). Back to the future: Modeling time depen-
dence in binary data. Political Analysis, 18, 271-292.
Cercas, J. (2011). The anatomy of a moment. New York, NY: Bloomsbury.
Collier, S., & Sater, W. F. (1996). A history of Chile, 1808-1994. Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Cox, G. W. (2008). Authoritarian elections and leadership succession, 1975–2000.
Unpublished paper, Department of Political Science, University of California,
San Diego.
Dunn, S. (2004). Jefferson’s second revolution: The election crisis of 1800 and the
triumph of republicanism. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.
Escribà Folch, A. (2014). Accountable for what? Regime types, performance, and the
fate of outgoing dictators, 1946–2004. Democratization, 20, 160-185.
Fearon, J. (2011). Self-enforcing democracy. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126,
1661-1708.
Geddes, B. (2005, September). Why parties and elections in authoritarian regimes?
Presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association,
Washington, DC.
Geddes, B. (2009, September). How autocrats defend themselves against armed
rivals. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science
Association, Toronto, Ontario, Canada.
Geddes, B., Wright, J., & Frantz, E. (2013). Autocratic regimes code book. Available
from dictators.la.psu.edu
Geddes, B., Wright, J., & Frantz, E. (2014). New data set: Autocratic breakdown and
regime transitions. Perspectives on Politics, 12, 305-309.
Getty, J. A. (1991). State and society under Stalin: Constitutions and elections in the
1930s. Slavic Review, 50, 18-35.
Goemans, H. E. (2008). Which way out? The manner and consequences of losing
office. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 52, 771-794.
Hyde, S. D. (2011). The pseudo-democrat’s dilemma: Why election monitoring
became an international norm? Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Lehoucq, F. (2002). Can parties police themselves? Electoral governance and democ-
ratization. International Political Science Review, 23, 29-46.
Maddison, A. (2010). Statistics on world population, GDP and per capita GDP,
1-2008 AD. Retrieved from www.ggdc.net/maddison/maddison-project/home.
htm
Makarenko, B. (in press). The role of elections in democracy. In A. Przeworski (Ed.),
Democracy in a Russian mirror. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Mozaffar, S., & Schedler, A. (2002). The comparative study of electoral gover-
nance—Introduction. International Political Science Review, 23, 5-27.
Nalepa, M. (2010). Skeletons in the closet: Transitional justice in post-communist
Europe. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
Przeworski 129
Author Biography
Adam Przeworski is the Carroll and Milton Petrie Professor of Politics at New York
University. His most recent book is Democracy and the Limits of Self-Government
(Cambridge University Press, 2011).
Downloaded from cps.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on November 13, 2015
View publication stats