Making Social Spending Work
Making Social Spending Work
Enduring Issues
Human societies have always needed safety nets to catch those who end
up in need, whether by unlucky endowments, by past mistakes, or by the
arrival of hard times. The risks are not new. They have always been there.
Yet for most of human history, we have lacked the means, or the political
will, to prevent or cushion them.
With each wave of expansion in the economic base, humans did what
little they could to cut risk at the local level, yet serious risks remained.
Prehistoric fortunes were never stabilized by hunting and gathering. The
arrival of agriculture tens of thousands of years ago initially helped to
diversify humanity’s economic portfolio, yet brought new vulnerabilities
to weather and pests once it had expanded. More recently, as the spread
of commerce diversified our sources of supply and allowed a further
expansion of population, our risks were reduced a bit further, though
3
OVERVIEW
they remained. Still more recently – in a mere blink of an eye lasting less
than three hundred years – industrialization and the ever-growing reli-
ance on skilled services once again cut our risks somewhat yet have not
eliminated them. Our world is risky, but not increasingly so.
A common error in the way we view history, and the way it is taught in
school, is to believe that an unprecedented economic insecurity was ush-
ered in by the Industrial Revolution and by the rise of a new greedy market
mentality around 1750. Marx and Engels said so. The gentler reformists of
the Fabian Society agreed that the age of dark satanic mills brought new
urgency to finding ways of providing social insurance and social assistance
to the needy. Karl Polanyi’s The Great Transformation (1944) agreed. While
their landmark writings contained great insights, they were mistaken in
believing that the industrial era and the rise of a market mentality brought
a transformational rise of risk and a brand-new need for social security. The
risks were at least as great before the Industrial Revolution. As for the rise
of a market mentality, it did not happen. There was no modern dawn of
market exchange, nor of self-interest, nor of “greed,” because all of these
are at least as old as the human species itself.
The risk of mortality, even more than economic risk, has also been
dropping over the centuries. There has been a great convergence in
human life spans, thanks mainly to the elimination of death from child-
birth and infant mortality. In the 2020s, people will naturally share the
fear that our vulnerability to mortality shocks is greater than ever, as
witnessed by the coronavirus pandemic. Not so. Horrible as it is, the latest
pandemic will not match the introduction of smallpox and malaria into
the Western Hemisphere, which killed a majority of its population. The
Black Death of the fourteenth century killed perhaps a quarter or half of
the European population, which the coronavirus will not do. And
Chinese history recorded frequent epidemics stretching back at least
three thousand years. Life has always been filled with risks as least as
great as those we face today, underlining the point that our need for
safety nets was at least as great in the past.
Given that humanity’s exposure to risks seems eternal, it is puzzling
that societies have only very recently built effective safety nets for contain-
ing such risks.
4
ENDURING ISSUES
5
OVERVIEW
(cont.)
run and long-run. Basically, safety nets are what social spend-
ing is for.
• Selfish generations: The book will use the convenient shorthand
Selfish Generations borrowed from David Thomson’s (1996) fine
book on how New Zealand governments had redistributed
resources between age groups.
The selfish is a shorthand for “advantaged by inter-generational
redistribution.” The advantaged “selfish” ones are not the whole
generation, but just those of its members who have political voice.
In many cases, the selfish generation’s poor were not helped. To
further clarify, a generation in this phrase and in Thomson’s book
refers to an age group, as in the common parlance about “the older
generation” or “the younger generation.” It does not strictly refer
to a birth cohort, as a demographer might prefer.
BASIC QUESTIONS
6
ENDURING ISSUES
• The answer to the third question is yes. Yes, safety nets had to be
administered mainly by government. Private charity and family sup-
ports have never been up to the tasks of eliminating poverty or educat-
ing the whole population. The forces behind government social
programs came together only in the last two hundred years, with
almost all their advance coming in the last sixty years. Government
social spending has now become worldwide, absorbing around 10 per-
cent of world product.
• A partial answer to the fifth question: The tendency to get the mix
wrong is as great among the world’s low-spending governments as it is
among those who spend more. Thus, the fourth and fifth questions
can be studied separately.
AS CONTROVERSIAL AS EVER
7
OVERVIEW
eight centuries. The words have changed, but the opposing positions
have not.
8
ENDURING ISSUES
9
OVERVIEW
new facts can raise the level of the debate. They can arm all sides with an
awareness of how tax-based social spending would affect collective goods
that all profess to care about – social peace and the size of the economy.
The competitiveness of the intellectual marketplace, and of the political
marketplace in electoral democracies, allows new facts to exert pressure
toward these collective goods. At the very least, new facts can speed up
society’s rejection of bad arguments.4
Eventually, despite the noise, true signals do come through, and far-
sighted societies heed them.
10
CHAPTER 2
The main reasons why social spending has spread all over the world is
the mirror image of what prevented social spending outside of Europe
before the last century: Having the government spend on the poor, the
sick, the elderly, and school children requires fiscal capacity plus political
pressure from below (Chapters 3 and 4).
Within the last sixty years, government social spending has grown to
absorb more than a quarter of GDP in over a dozen countries, mainly in
Europe. The demand for such tax-based programs was raised by
11
OVERVIEW
Finding #2. A major barrier to growth and equality has been the
refusal of those with power to devote taxes to universal education.
Government funding for mass education has always been the
main driver of adults’ years of schooling, building human skills
and productivity. The leading countries passed up chances to
capture these gains in the eighteenth century and part of the
nineteenth. Once tax-based schooling took off, it became more
equal. The Americans were leaders in the quantity of primary and
secondary schooling, but never leaders in its quality.
12
FINDINGS AND LESSONS
evidence, the United States never led the world in the quality of primary
and secondary schooling (Chapter 5).
Finding #3. Since around 1910, there has been a long mission shift
in social spending, toward support for the powerful and elderly, at
the expense of assisting the young and the poor. This mission shift
in social targeting has offset part of the pro-growth and pro-equality
effects of the overall expansion of safety-net spending.
Over the last hundred years, many countries’ social spending shifted
missions, toward public pensions for the non-poor and away from pro-
gressive policies like mass schooling and aid to the poor. This mission
shift has not been reversed since. It probably compromised both income
equality and income growth. The global mission shift toward public
pensions may have been due in large part to improvements in life
expectancy, which allowed longer life past work and contributed to
political “gray power.” The inference about gray power springs from
the fact that public pension spending rose even per elderly person, and
not just at the rate of population aging. Its per person generosity rose
faster than the rise in educational spending per child of school age.
The rising demand for government pensions was probably also linked,
in addition, to a quiet global change in the role of intra-family transfers.
Career and family developments may have raised public pressure for
more tax-based support of the elderly (Chapter 6).
13
OVERVIEW
14
FINDINGS AND LESSONS
“regressive” redistribution have been rare and limited. For all that has been
written about a shift of political sentiments and government policy away
from progressivity since the late 1970s, no such trend is clear yet in how
overall taxes or social spending are distributed. Among democratic welfare
states, the closest thing to a demonstrable reversal against Robin Hood is the
slight retreat in Sweden since the 1990s. Globally, the most dramatic swing
since the late 1970s has been Chile’s record-setting return toward progres-
sivity after the regressivity of Pinochet.
Finding that redistribution has continued to march slowly toward
progressivity carries a strong implication for our interpretation of the
rise in income inequality since the 1970s, so firmly established by the
World Top Incomes Project and by Thomas Piketty (2014). That rise may
owe nothing to a net shift in government redistribution toward the rich,
despite the lowering of top tax rates. If so, it is all the more important to
explore what non-fiscal forces have widened gaps in market incomes
around the world (Chapter 10).
15
OVERVIEW
3”), admitting all sorts of immigrants but denying them access to social
assistance and social insurance is unsustainable. The cherry-picking
Option 4 seems to win by default (Chapter 11).
Finding #7. The most durable threat to the future of social spend-
ing and the welfare state is posed by the upward march of senior life
spans. Something has to give, for financial sustainability. Five coun-
tries are clearly keeping their total public pension costs under
control, while protecting their basic anti-poverty pensions, but at
least seven others are not.
The logic governing how public pension budgets must behave in the
long run produces this necessary rule for sustainability. Some countries
have already built something like it into official policy rules. The notional
16
FINDINGS AND LESSONS
defined contribution (NDC) system fixes the share of GDP (or earnings)
to be paid out in yearly pension benefits. The simple rule stated in
Finding #8 indexes pensions not to the latest GDP or earnings, but to
the real value of peak GDP or earnings. Pension institutions need to retain
this safeguard, to avoid having yearly pensions sink as fast as GDP in
a short-run recession or depression like the one triggered by the corona-
virus pandemic of 2020 (Chapters 12–14).1
17
OVERVIEW
Finding #10. The younger the person, the greater the long-run
social return on society’s investments in them, both on the average
and at the still-unexploited margin. For any given total public social
spending, investing in child development, not least pre-school
children, is more pro-growth and pro-equality than spending the
same amount on public pensions for the well-off (or on transfers
favoring the rich). Generations of powerful groups in many coun-
tries have selfishly failed to heed this lesson from history.
18
FINDINGS AND LESSONS
19
OVERVIEW
20
FINDINGS AND LESSONS
suffered through their working life before 1990, while heaping health
and education benefits on the generations born since 1970 in the east-
coast provinces.
• In Greece between 1982 and 2014, pensioners in the public and formal
private sectors received unsustainable gains paid for largely by others,
contributing to the country’s debt crisis.
• In Japan, despite a tradition of saying that the elderly should be able to
count on their adult children for support, the elderly population has
instead been supported by the taxpayers of their children’s genera-
tion, ever since a jump in taxpayer support from 1974 to 1983. The
support is only moderate per year of an elderly person’s retirement,
but becomes a huge aggregate burden on younger workers in such an
aged population (Chapters 12 and 14).
• In Singapore, the main beneficiaries will be the first future generation
to benefit from a shift in government policy away from capital accu-
mulation toward public social spending (Chapter 13).
• Turkey’s pensioners have captured increasingly unsustainable benefits
at the expense of the rest of society, at least for the period 1980–2017.
The beneficiaries are again those near the top of society, as in Greece
and several Latin American countries (Chapters 7 and 12).
• In the United States, the generation becoming 65 years old between
1967 and 2002 (born 1902–1937) benefited at the expense of other
generations from the arrival of age-restricted Medicare and the shift
toward more generous non-contributory Social Security benefits. Also
since 1967, the United States has lost its lead in public education, and
has been particularly remiss about having the nation’s taxpayers pro-
vide paid work-leave for the parents of newborns (Chapters 9, 12, and
14).
In the long run, while all public safety nets have helped to stabilize
people’s purchasing powers, the strongest safety net has been the one
woven by investing more in the young.
21
CHAPTER 11
235
CONFRONTING THREATS
This chapter addresses the other very real demographic threat – the
shorter-run threat posed by the combination of rising immigration and
the political backlash against it.
Figure 11.1. The percentage of US residents born outside the United States, 1850–2017
Source: United States Census Bureau.
236
DO IMMIGRATION TENSIONS FRAY THE SAFETY NETS?
237
CONFRONTING THREATS
The recent rise of immigration has in fact been shared by all the
richest democracies of Western Europe and North America. Over these
years, the inflow of migrants has grown most clearly for Germany, which
accepted a particularly large number of refugees in the 2015–2016 wave
from Syria, Iraq, and Afghanistan. While this latest wave has been
impeded by the migration barriers in response to the 2020 virus pan-
demic, Europe should expect further rises in the supply of migrants, both
ordinary economic migrants and desperate refugees. The rich receiving
countries all have poorer neighbors with dysfunctional governments.
Economic breakdowns and humanitarian crises are likely. A horrific
descent into civil war like that in Syria after 2012 could easily happen
again in any of several large countries – say, in one of the large countries
of Mediterranean North Africa and the Middle East. Such a civil war
would send another wave of refugees to Europe. While some of the
African and Middle Eastern refugees will also head to Australasia and
North America, there will be an offsetting decline in migration from
Latin America. That region has entered an era of low population growth,
so there will be less demographic pressure to cross the Rio Grande, with
or without a border wall (Hanson and McIntosh 2016).
The wave of refugees that crested in 2015–2016, like earlier high
waves, raised nativist backlash against the arriving foreigners. Almost all
European countries and the United States have seen anti-immigrant
political parties capture a rising share of votes. Much of the accompany-
ing rhetoric has been raw. Viktor Orbán, prime minister of Hungary, has
repeated the phrase “the best migrant is the migrant who does not
come.”2 In Denmark in 2005, Pia Kjaersgaard, then head of the nativist
Danish People’s Party, demonized Sweden’s liberal welcoming of refu-
gees thus: “If they [Swedes] want to turn Stockholm, Gothenburg or
Malmoe into a Scandinavian Beirut, with clan wars, honour killings and
gang rapes, let them do it. We can always put a barrier on the Oeresund
Bridge [between Sweden and Denmark].”3 In the American presidential
election campaign of 2015–2016, candidate Donald Trump similarly
demonized migrants, in this case from Mexico: “When Mexico sends its
people, they’re not sending their best . . . They’re sending people that
have lots of problems, and they’re bringing those problems with us.
238
DO IMMIGRATION TENSIONS FRAY THE SAFETY NETS?
What percentage of people in Actual 10.0 13.4 12.2 10.0 14.8 17.6
your country are foreign-born? Perceived 36.1 31.3 28.8 26.4 30.3 27.0
What percentage of your
foreign-born are from North Actual 4.4 6.0 38.9 13.1 18.8 25.0
Africa and the Middle East? Perceived 20.6 20.9 28.2 33.9 32.9 37.2
What percentage of your Actual 10.0 23.0 48.0 33.0 30.0 27.0
foreign-born are Muslim? Perceived 22.7 33.9 50.2 47.0 43.9 44.8
What percentage of your foreign- Actual 22.0 16.6 39.1 49.1 35.1 33.7
Born have not finished high school? Perceived 29.0 25.6 51.6 43.6 37.2 40.9
What percentage of your Actual 5.5 5.7 16.6 14.7 6.9 16.1
foreign-born are unemployed? Perceived 26.4 27.0 38.8 41.8 39.2 37.2
Ratio of government transfers
received by the average foreign- Actual 1.23 1.42 1.39 1.29 0.72 1.44
born, vs. the average native-born Perceived 1.17 1.02 1.77 1.34 1.13 1.28
Source and notes: Alesina, Miano, and Stantcheva (2018). The sample sizes are 4,500 native-
born adult interviewees for the United States, 4,001 for the UK, 4,000 for France, 4,000 for
Italy, 4,001 for Germany, and 2,004 for Sweden, for a total of 22,506 respondents.
239
CONFRONTING THREATS
First, as shown in the top row, people in all six countries greatly over-
estimate the share of immigrants in their midst, imagining that about
30 percent of residents are foreign-born, when the true shares are only
10–18 percent. In five of the six countries, people also over-imagine the
shares of immigrants that are Muslim or that come from North Africa and
the Middle East. Strikingly, the only country that did not overestimate the
Muslim share, or the share from North Africa and the Middle East, was
France, the country where Muslims and trans-Mediterranean migrants was
the greatest. People in all six countries made the further mistake of under-
estimating the education of the immigrants; as shown in Table 11.1, they
consistently overestimated the low-education share, the share of immigrants
that had not yet finished high school.5
Regarding what happens to the immigrants after arrival, we often hear
conflicting perceptions. Some nationals think that the immigrants are
a fiscal burden because they work very little and get handouts, while others
think they work too much, taking jobs away from the native-born. The team
of Alesina, Miano, and Stantcheva came up with a clear result regarding
work by immigrants of working age. In all six countries of Table 11.1,
immigrants’ unemployment rate has in fact been much lower than people
tend to think, even in that winter of 2017–2018, when so many refugees still
had not mastered the new native language or found jobs. Finally, people
were asked whether the average adult immigrant received more transfer
payments from government than the average native-born. The truth is that
immigrants do receive more on average, because of their initial economic
hardships. On this matter, the interview responses of the native-born were
close to the truth, even though they had overestimated immigrants’ unem-
ployment and had underestimated their education.
240
DO IMMIGRATION TENSIONS FRAY THE SAFETY NETS?
241
CONFRONTING THREATS
table 11.2. The fiscal effects of extra immigrants depend on the question you ask
about them
Burden through public
The question you ask Burden through public pensions? schooling, aid to young?
Notes: If one could pay for pensions and other social transfers out of government debt, and
out of the reserves of the pension system, then the left-hand side of the equation should be
modified to include taxes paid in earlier and later years, not just in the current year. Yet they
have to be paid sooner or later, and the problem remains essentially as stated in this pure
same-year version of pay-as-you-go.
Note another simplification here: Taxation here refers only to those taxes that are spent
on education, pensions, and other social benefits, and not the total of all tax revenues. This
analysis ignores taxes channeled into non-transfer spending, such as national defense,
highway construction, and basic government payrolls.
242
DO IMMIGRATION TENSIONS FRAY THE SAFETY NETS?
Suppose we take the usual short-run view, in the top row of Table 11.2,
asking the pay-as-you-go question “Do today’s extra immigrants cause a net
drain on government budgets right now, in this same year?”11 They often do
so, since extra immigrants’ families typically are a net drain through the host
country’s child-related social programs such as education. If this drain is
greater than the tax revenues collected from adult immigrants, helping to
pay for pensions and other public programs, then immigrants do cause a net
fiscal drain this year. Fiscal-demographic simulations suggest that the net
short-run fiscal effect is indeed negative. A typical mix of immigrant age
groups is so tilted toward the young that the costs of child-centered social
programs yield a negative net result for the first twelve to fifteen years after an
immigrant arrival. This short-run negative effect would also show up in
immigrants’ use of non-contributory aid to those of working age. As OECD
economists have rightly emphasized, the short-run fiscal impact depends
above all on the host country’s success or failure in helping the foreign-born
find jobs.12
Next, suppose one takes a somewhat longer view, asking
Table 11.2’s second question about the net fiscal effects over the whole
lifetimes of the first generation of new immigrants. Now the net effect is
probably positive. True, the immigrants in old age probably get a net
transfer from others, because public pension systems are typically
designed to be progressive, giving a high rate of return to lower-income
earners, such as first-generation immigrants. Yet while that first genera-
tion is aging, its children have already become productive adults, paying
positive taxes instead of needing school money. These tax contributions
should outweigh any intra-cohort redistributions toward foreign-born
pensioners.
Finally, when we consider the whole lifetimes of not only the extra
immigrants but also their children and grandchildren, the net fiscal
effects become clearly positive, as again suggested in Table 11.2. We
know that the eventual fiscal results are clearly positive, because in the
long run the immigrants and their descendants pay more in taxes than
they get in targeted transfers, just like the rest of society. So the answer to
the net-burden question is clearly “no,” not a net burden for any year
beyond about the sixteenth year after arrival. The long-run fiscal effect of
extra immigration is clearly positive.13 That makes perfect sense: In the
243
CONFRONTING THREATS
long run, we are all descendants of immigrants, and over our lifetimes we
pay more in taxes than anybody receives in social spending – our remain-
ing taxes cover such shared public goods as national defense and public
transit.
244
DO IMMIGRATION TENSIONS FRAY THE SAFETY NETS?
245
CONFRONTING THREATS
The political climate can change, of course. For example, people can
update their opinions about welfare programs, and change their votes, in
response to new exposures to immigrants. We can gather two kinds of
clues to upcoming trends: public opinions about the welfare state, and
actual policy changes.
Public opinion surveys sometimes ask people whether they think that
“social benefits” should be higher, and in a subset of those surveys one
can exploit exogenous-looking variation in exposure to immigration to
see if that exposure seems to reduce support for social spending. An early
opportunity to conduct such a test occurred in Sweden in 1985–1994. At
that time, the government’s Refugee Placement Program assigned refu-
gees to cities, with preference for secondary cities. That is, the refugees
were not allowed to decide where they first lived. That suggests that which
native-born Swedes came in contact with foreigners was initially exogen-
ous, even though the refugees were soon able to change cities. Exploiting
this geographic variation within Sweden, the research team of Matz
Dahlberg, Karin Edmark, and Heléne Lundqvist (2012, 2013) estimated
the effect of locals’ exposure to immigrants on the locals’ answer to the
question “Are you in favor of decreasing the social benefits?” The authors
found that there was indeed a tendency for Swedes more exposed to
immigrants to favor cutting social benefits. And since the question about
social benefits seemed to refer to universal benefits, the implication was
that support for the welfare state was undercut by contact with newly
arrived immigrants. If true, this would suggest something like the nega-
tive effect of ethnic fractionalization on the growth of social spending, as
we described back in Chapter 6.
A more recent survey is that 2017–2018 survey conducted by Alberto
Alesina, Armando Miano, and Stefanie Stantcheva, cited earlier in con-
nection with Table 11.1. The authors found that people’s support for
generous redistribution is undermined by the perception that immi-
grants are more represented among the beneficiaries of redistribution.
At first glance, this seems to reveal direct links between their fears of
immigrants and their willingness to retreat from offering universal social
benefits. However, the link is actually not so direct here. The fears about
immigrants only take the indirect form of their being asked first about
immigrants before being asked the payoff questions about social benefits.
246
DO IMMIGRATION TENSIONS FRAY THE SAFETY NETS?
Given this ordering of the questions, there is a strong chance that they
interpreted the questions about social benefits as referring to immigrants
as such, not to the more universal benefits of the welfare state.
A deeper test of the link between exogenous exposure to immigrants
and support for income redistribution has now been carried out by the
research team of Alberto Alesina, Elie Murard, and Hillel Rapoport
(2019). Like the Dahlberg–Edmark–Lundqvist team, they exploited var-
iation in actual exposure to immigrants among regions, in this case
among 140 regions within sixteen Western European countries between
2002 and 2016. Controlling for many other things, they explored how
regional exposure to immigrants made the interviewed individuals agree
or disagree with the statement “The government should take measures to
reduce differences in income levels.” The effects were strongly negative,
that is against progressive redistribution. Going beyond asking just about
progressive redistribution, the authors also asked questions about social
spending itself, such as whether one agrees that “social benefits place too
great strain on economy,” “social benefits cost businesses too much in
taxes and charges,” and “social benefits make people lazy.” While social
spending is indeed correlated with progressive redistribution, as shown
in Chapter 10, the authors concentrated on the demand for redistribu-
tion, not on social spending itself. Still, their overall conclusion also
strongly suggests a negative effect of exposure to immigrants on support
for social spending. Importantly, and not surprisingly, they also found
that cultural distance and low skills on the part of immigrants made the
negative effect stronger. Implication: Welcoming low-skilled immigrants
from very different cultures will weaken the universalist welfare state.
So far, all the studies are based on opinion surveys, and all suggest that
an erosion of expressed support for social spending will result either
from anti-immigrant prejudice or from actual contact with immigrants
from distant cultures.
The second kind of relevant clue comes not from expressed opinions
but from directly observed policy changes themselves. Have immigration
shocks negatively affected actual safety-net policies? One econometric
study has looked at the pool of twenty-five developed OECD countries for
the period 1980–2008, testing for effects of changes in immigration on
changes in aggregate social expenditures, controlling for time and
247
CONFRONTING THREATS
248
DO IMMIGRATION TENSIONS FRAY THE SAFETY NETS?
249
CONFRONTING THREATS
250
DO IMMIGRATION TENSIONS FRAY THE SAFETY NETS?
251
CONFRONTING THREATS
252
DO IMMIGRATION TENSIONS FRAY THE SAFETY NETS?
free lunch – with low-wage farm labor blocked from entering the country,
who will pick the real cherries off the trees? Still, Option 4’s cherry-
picking would have three favorable economic effects, relative to a more
balanced admission of immigrants. It would raise GDP per capita, gen-
erate more net revenue for government to spend, and avoid exacerbating
visible domestic inequalities. It would also help to secure social insurance
and social assistance within the country. Think of Option 4 as the
national-level version of walling off gated communities, or to restrictive
zoning laws designed to block the building of housing that the poor can
afford.
Would it really placate the divisive anti-immigrant politics? Yes, it
would help in this respect, according to a recent study by Simone
Moriconi, Giovanni Peri, and Riccardo Turati (2018). Studying elections
in twelve European countries, over the period 2007–2016, they find that
preferences change more strongly in response to the low-skilled immi-
grant share among less-educated voters than for highly educated voters.
Especially among less-educated and older native-born individuals, an
increase in low-skilled immigrants makes their votes and attitudes more
nativist, more anti-immigrant. Thus voting for nationalistic parties is
more sensitive among lower-education native-born voters, and more
sensitive in response to low-skilled immigration.
So the choice should boil down to Option 4 versus Option 1: Choose
between promoting domestic goals and promoting world goals.
For now, the political pendulum on the migration issue is swinging
toward Option 4’s preserving productivity, equality, harmony – and social
spending – within a country, at the expense of world productivity, equal-
ity, and humanitarian relief. The pendulum could swing back again in
the future. Whichever way it swings, we face the same sad dilemma we saw
in connection with Japan, Korea, and Taiwan in Chapter 10: There is an
undeniable conflict between serving these objectives inside a country and
serving them worldwide.
253