Cer 2015 0001
Cer 2015 0001
A Service of
zbw
Leibniz-Informationszentrum
Wirtschaft
Article
Comparison of patterns of convergence among
"emerging markets" of Central Europe, Eastern
Europe and Central Asia
Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your
Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes.
Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial
Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them
machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise
use the documents in public.
Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen
(insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open
gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you
genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated
licence.
https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/3.0
www.econstor.eu
Comparative Economic Research, Volume 18, Number 1, 2015
10.1515/cer-2015-0001
Abstract
*
Professor, Seattle Pacific University
**
Professor, University of Washington
6 Joanna Poznańska, Kazimierz Poznański
1. Introduction
There are numerous examples of less developed economies which, once they
began to converge with more developed economies, continued on the path until they
closed the distance separating them from the developed economies. For instance,
Japan, South Korea and China are in this category (with some residual uncertainty
over China). For other economies, an initial spurt of growth reaches a low
equilibrium and convergence comes to a halt. Not long ago, Brazil was considered
almost as a textbook case of this category in international economics. During the
first few post-war decades, the countries of the Soviet bloc began a convergence,
but by mid-1980’s the catching-up lost some of its momentum. At this point, the
region was still averaging one-third of the productivity rates for Western Europe.
In 1989-90, with the collapse of the Soviet bloc, its former members
embarked on dismantling their command economies established after the war by
the Soviet Union. A market-run system, intended to imitate Western Europe, was
first phased-in in Central Europe (Kornai 2006; Poznanski, Poznanska and Liu
2012) and then what is now defined as Eastern Europe (i.e., Russia, Ukraine, and
Belarus) joined in as well. The economies of Central and Eastern Europe turned
into “emerging markets”, with typical institutional features such as: an “open”
economy with low tariffs; robust domestic competition; private, and often largely,
foreign banking systems; and limited unionization and flexible wages. Relatively
stable prices and currencies are other features of the emerging markets that
countries of the region acquired at this turning point.
These changes were undertaken with the goal of resuming the catching-up
process, particularly with Western Europe as the region’s role-model.
Characteristics associated with “emerging markets” include not only their systemic
characteristics and macroeconomic choices, but their above-the-average rates of
investment and related rates of growth of their national product. The “emerging
economies” also tend to be export-driven and show trade surpluses, or at least are
not burdened with large trade deficits. In addition, their capital balance – i.e. the
difference between inflow and outflow of capital – with respect to foreign
investment is usually positive. As a rule, these factors have allowed most of the
“emerging markets” by and large to reduce the distance separating them from the
advanced economies.
This has not been the case with Central and Eastern Europe, often called
“transition” economies. When they moved forward with their market-oriented
reforms, numerous projections were made about Central Europe eliminating its
distance behind Western Europe in two, or at the most three, decades. Now
however, over two decades later, it is evident that the early projections have not
been proven correct – with the exception of Poland and Slovenia – and no
Comparison Of Patterns Of Convergence... 7
visible closing of the economic distance has taken place. In fact, in some
economies in the region the initial gap has expanded (e.g., in Ukraine and
Serbia) This puts Central and Eastern European economies into a special
category, where the systemic features of “emerging markets” are not associated
with “economic convergence” (e.g., Poznanski 2013).
The critics of Poland’s approach to transition have to recognize that at least in
terms of its overall performance, measured in growth rates, Poland is a success
story, with growth rates that put her on par with the Latin American emerging
economies that have been able to visibly close the gaps separating them from the
advanced economies. This is, however, a relative success, since among the
transition economies are also two Asian economies – China and Vietnam. In
pursuing liberalization, they also joined the category of “emerging markets”, with
China already producing two decades of the longest and fastest growth in post-war
history. This has allowed China to reach rates of growth four times higher than in
Poland, and another great success story, Vietnam, to reach rates nearly three times
as high as Poland, and accordingly both have reached similarly higher rates of
convergence levels.
The year 1989 is chosen as the starting point to measure the relative
economic performance of the “emerging economies”. As has been indicated, this
is the approximate year when a full-scale liberalization started in the formerly
state-planned economies in Central and Eastern Europe, including Russia.
It should be noted that in China market-oriented reforms greatly accelerated from
1985 onward. Historical real (i.e. corrected for inflation) GDP statistics are
utilized for the calculation of growth patterns. Straight-forward indices, with the
1989 GDP level taken as 100, are calculated for selected countries in specific
regions. Averages for regions are calculated by dividing the total 2014 GDP for
the countries of the region by their 1989 GDP level. Using this methodology,
country indices are “weighted” by the size of their economies.
Table 1 below summarizes the results for 55 “emerging economies” from
five different regions, namely Asia, Latin America, Central and Eastern Europe as
well as Central Asia (encompassing the remaining former Soviet republics, however
with the Baltic States considered part of Central Europe). As a further point of
reference for Central and Eastern Europe, growth indices for thirteen countries of
Western Europe (from the “old” European Union) are included as well. This latter
8 Joanna Poznańska, Kazimierz Poznański
2014 2014
Region
Index (1989=100) Index (2008 =100)
Asia 609 146
China 990 164
Vietnam 519 141
without China 411 144
Latin America 209 118
Argentina 256 126
Chile 336 125
Central Europe 221 106
Hungary 125 78
Poland 238 118
without Poland 165 100
South Central Europe 126 98
Serbia 79 105
Eastern Europe 112 138
Belarus 204 124
Russia 117 145
Ukraine 65 90
Central Asia 198 139
Kazakhstan 194 135
Western Europe 153 99
Austria 165 102
Germany 149 105
Turkey 242 111
Egypt 267 114
Morocco 220 113
Algeria 176 108
Source: Calculated from “Development Indicators. GDP and Growth Rates of GDP, 1989-2011”,
World Bank, 2012.
10 Joanna Poznańska, Kazimierz Poznański
Turning to Western Europe, the 2014 GDP index for the 15 European
Union “old” members was 153. This is below the Central European 221 index
as well as the region’s index of 165 when counted without Poland. Of the 27
countries comprising Central and Eastern Europe, South Central Europe, and the
former Soviet republics of Central Asia, only eight reported 1989-2014 growth
rates higher than Western Europe as a group. Of these eight countries, three are
from Central Europe, namely Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia. The remaining
countries in this group include Albania from South Central Europe, Belarus
from Eastern Europe plus five Central Asian countries, namely Armenia,
Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan, the latter with the
fastest growing economy within the whole group of 27 economies.
When the 2008 crisis shook the world, it marked the worst financial crisis
that hit the advanced economies in the post-war period. By 2014, the total
product of Western Europe (European Union – 15) still remained below the
2008 level. Specifically, the GDP 2014 index (2008=100) was 99 for the
advanced region of Europe. This was the first test for Central and Eastern Europe
to see how resistant the region is to cross-border financial shocks originating in
Western Europe. To the surprise of many, as a group the Central and Eastern
European countries showed better economic performance in terms of growth. The
respective 2014 index for Central Europe was 106, meaning it was 7 points higher
than Western Europe in the six-year time span of 2008-2014.
The most resistant economies of Western Europe showed a modest
increase in production and ended up with a GDP 2014 index around 102. This
group would include five economies, i.e., Belgium, Austria, France, Germany
and Sweden (the latter being the most successful among them, with a 108 GDP
index). Among the ten economies in this group which reported declines for
2008-2014, the most severely damaged turned out to be the economies of
Greece, with a 2014 growth index of 78, and Ireland with a respective index of
96. Portugal also experienced difficulties with a 94 growth index for 2014,
while the respective index for Spain was also 94 and for Italy the index was 93.
Proportionally speaking, the number of Central European economies that
suffered a decline from the financial shock has been lower than in Western
Europe. Of the ten sampled countries of Central and Eastern Europe, two
reported a visible increase in national product, namely Poland and Slovenia,
with Poland having the distinct status of the best-performing European
(including both West and East) economy in terms of growth. Poland’s GDP
12 Joanna Poznańska, Kazimierz Poznański
2014 growth index (with 2008=100) was 118 and that of Sweden, indicated as
the fastest growing Western European member, by a large margin. Of the
remaining eight Central and Eastern European economies that sharpest decline
was reported by Slovenia with 91 index, Hungary with 97 and Latvia with 98
index. This is less than decline reported by the worst affected Western European
economies (including Finland with 95 index in 2014).
The lesson of the 2008 crisis is that joining the European Union did not
render Central Europe immune to the financial shocks. The shocks were actually
imported from Western European economies, with many of them reporting the
most damaging downturns ever encountered in post-war Western Europe.
Further, for some Western European economies this severe decline followed
years of remarkable expansion, which had been taken as proof that liberalization
pays off handsomely. For example, Ireland was praised as an example that
globalization worked “miracles”. Its GDP index for the year 2000 (1989=100)
was 217, compared to 128 index for Western Europe as a whole. But, as already
mentioned, following four years of consecutive decline Ireland’s GDP index for
2014 was 96, among the worst in the whole of Western Europe.
Turning now to Latin America, growth statistics show that as a region
these countries proved more resistant to the 2008 financial shock, at least in the
sense that none in the sample witnessed a decline of national product through
2014. The group as a whole reported an increase that averaged to a 2014 index
equal to 118. This meant, however, that these economies considerably slowed
down compared to the long-term average index of 209 achieved during the
1989-2014 period. Some countries showed very impressive growth rates, raising
their national product during this six-year span by one-third as in Peru) or one
fourth, e.g., Argentina (whose economic performance defied those critics who
predicted a painful and protracted recovery from its own severe financial crisis
incurred by its default on foreign debt and steep devaluation).
Central Europe fell not only behind Latin America, but also behind the
“emerging economies” of Asia, which collectively enjoyed a 2014 growth index
of 146 against the 2008 GDP base level, i.e. the equivalent of nearly one-half.
This index is higher than that for Latin America and not matched even by the
best performing member of Central Europe – Poland. If China is removed from
the sample, the growth index for Asia is at 144, still higher than for any other
group of “emerging economies”; still higher than for Poland alone; and also
higher than that of the former Central Asian republics, which reported a very
strong 2014 growth index of 138.
For further comparison, Russia reported an index of 145 and Ukraine an
index of 90 for the world crisis period 2008-2014. With this data the records for
the former Soviet republics can be contrasted with that of individual “emerging
Comparison Of Patterns Of Convergence... 13
The question which arises is: How is it that the “emerging markets “of
Central and Eastern Europe, together with Russia and the former Soviet
republics, which by and large have liberalized their systems so much, have
recorded growth rates insufficient to enable convergence in a reasonably short
period of time? The existing pattern is so prevalent among these “transition
economies” that one would expect more or less the same factors to be
responsible for the pattern discerned here. At this stage of the discussion among
14 Joanna Poznańska, Kazimierz Poznański
One hypothesis concerning the possible reasons for the slow convergence is
that domestic demand doesn’t provide a sufficient stimulus for production growth;
in other words, the low rates of growth are demand-driven. This argument was
raised already at the time when the region entered the post-1989 “transition
recession” that shaved off over ¼ of the regional national product. According to
the prevailing view, this downturn was caused by structural – supply-side –
impediments, namely the presence of huge amounts of “unwanted production”
which the state planners had developed in earlier years. A dissenting argument
was raised, however, pointing to the demand side, namely a sharp decline in real
wages combined with a drastic credit squeeze and a sharp increase in the interest
charged (justified on the grounds of eradicating inflation and “strengthening” the
currencies).
The demand argument has been recently revived by Podkaminer (2013) in
the context of the ongoing debate on how to cope best with the post-2008
financial crisis and its aftermath. The prevailing view has been that austerity
(higher unemployment and wage cuts etc.) is the remedy. But a small group of
vocal Keynesian economists (e.g., Krugman in the United States, Laski in
Europe) have called for “monetary easing” by allowing increased budgetary
deficits and moderate price inflation. A retrospective examination of the real
wage trends since 1989 seems to argue for the validity of the demand argument
in explaining growth performance, both at the outset of the transition as well as
in the years that followed.
Comparison Of Patterns Of Convergence... 15
1989 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2005 2007 2009 2012
Czech
100.0 76.7 85.5 101.4 101.3 110.1 121.3 136.7 148.2 153.8 154.0
Republic
Hungary 100.0 88.2 90.9 75.8 82.4 75.7 103.6 118.9 117.5 115.7 116.4
Poland 100.0 73.3 74.4 80.7 88.2 93.3 96.3 102.1 112.0 121.0 124.5
Slovakia 100.0 73.6 73.0 81.3 89.1 82.1 87.7 93.7 100.9 105.7 104.8
Slovenia 100.0 60.6 73.5 80.3 83.9 87.6 92.9 99.2 106.0 110.8 111.0
Estonia 100.0 40.0 45.1 48.8 56.1 63.7 72.8 88.0 111.0 108.9 110.0
Lithuania 100.0 47.6 33.1 35.4 45.4 45.1 46.6 57.1 76.7 78.4 74.8
Bulgaria 100.0 68.0 48.6 38.1 38.3 41.5 41.9 46.2 52.8 64.7 72.5
Romania 100.0 74.7 62.4 76.7 61.7 62.8 67.5 94.5 118.2 135.6 130.3
for gross national product, and 104 for real wages, meaning that in the over
twenty years that have passed real wages in this country have basically not
increased. In the extreme case of Bulgaria, wages declined to an index value of 72,
while product increased by 122 points. In Lithuania the index for product was 119
and for wages 75, indicating another case of an enormous gap. Finally, in Hungary
the respective indices were 129 and 116.
The above described phenomena constitute a rather unprecedented case of
the distribution of gains from economic growth, certainly in light of the Chinese
transition path, where phenomenal increase in the total national product has been
accompanied by almost as rapid an increase in real wages, often 10% or more on an
annual basis. This is actually in line with the patterns detected in other Asian
economies that experienced “economic miracles”, e.g. Japan and South Korea. They
all ensured a model of so-called “shared growth”, guaranteeing that all major groups
would equally benefit from the growing national income and productivity as its
principal source.
by 12%, mainly due to migration. The losses might be permanent, since migrant
workers usually intend to settle and have families in Western Europe, whose
leadership is very accommodating to this source of economic growth. This happens
also to be a source of repressed growth in Central Europe, since the wealth created
by these migrants tends to stay in the countries they move into.
The case of Poland is instructive here, with the country reporting 10.5
million persons employed in 1990, the first full year of transition. Due to initial
reductions and the weak demand for labour, the number of persons employed
declined permanently, settling at around 8.5 million people. This meant a reduction
in the use of labour factor by 2 million people. In 2013, official statistics revealed
that the unemployment rate is oscillating at around 13.5 – 14.5%, or around 2.2
million persons in absolute numbers. This was close to the level reached two
decades earlier during the 1989–1992 “transition recession” that shaved off almost
20% of the gross national product. These 2.2 million represent nearly one quarter
of the number of employed persons, meaning that after the transition and
recession the economy has been moving forward at about one-quarter below its
“potential” production growth.
Asia Africa
Bangladesh 0 Algeria 9
Cambodia 27 Angola 53
China 0 Cameron 63
India 5 Egypt 12
Indonesia 28 Kenya 41
Malaysia 16 Madagascar 100
Mongolia 22 Morocco 18
Pakistan 25 Mozambique 100
Philippines 1 Nigeria 5
Vietnam 0 Senegal 48
Sri Lanka 0 South Africa 0
Thailand 5 Sudan 20
Swaziland 100
Middle East
Tanzania 66
Iran 0 Tunisia 22
Jordan 14 Uganda 80
Lebanon 34 Zambia 77
Turkey 4 Zimbabwe 51
Yemen 0
Few economists have tried to estimate the correlation between the level of
foreign “penetration” and the efficiency of financial sectors (se however the
review article of Estrin 2009). There is no compelling research to make the
argument that the impact is either positive or negative for economic growth.
However, it seems reasonable to argue that the higher the foreign ownership
controls, the more influence they can exert over the accessibility of means – like
credit – for the formation of capital, i.e., investment. It could well be that at least
until this point foreign banks in operation have – rationally – chosen a strategy
to restrict investment credit as opposed to other allocations. The higher foreign
ownership of banking and insurance in Central Europe might be a factor in
keeping Central and Eastern European rates of income growth below their
“potential” level.
20 Joanna Poznańska, Kazimierz Poznański
increase from $8 billion to $70 billion). In a sharp reversal, foreign direct investment
into the region collapsed to $70 billion (with as much as one-quarter of the overall
decline taking place in the real estate sector) (Podkaminer 2013).
Tapping foreign direct investment has yielded many remarkable benefits
to the region’s development, but it has also exposed the region to an outflow of
value to the host countries of foreign companies. The inflow of foreign
investment must be measured against the outflow of income earned by the
foreign companies from their operations in the Central and Eastern European
region. The macroeconomic indicator of the resultant effects is the difference
between the gross national income and gross domestic product, which tells us
the annual value generated and the value “utilized” internally.
As documented, except for the initial phase when foreign companies took
advantage of the privatization programs that made available a huge supply of
previously state-owned assets, the region has witnessed a substantial and growing
outflow of profits, rents and dividends abroad. In 2011, Czech Republic incomes
collected by the foreign companies from their subsidiaries represented 7% of the
gross domestic product, 5% in Estonia and 5% in Hungary. In Poland this share was
also high at 4.5 %. One needs to keep in mind that these are estimates and the actual
numbers could be higher. Besides, looking at the trends of the last decade these
shares are on the rise in most of the economies.
The faster growth rate in the “converging economies” has been driven by
acceleration of exports that allowed them to produce trade surpluses. China is
again a model example, while in Central Europe trade deficits are registered
almost uniformly, including in Poland, which is the fastest growing economy in
the region. Also, the stiffer import competition from Western Europe limits
employment opportunities. Another factor is that Eastern Europe’s foreign trade
is centred on Germany, which notoriously runs large surpluses with its partners.
This has a repressive impact on the region’s deficit-running economies across
Europe. Central and Eastern Europe (with Russia and Ukraine) are all still in
search of a “growth strategy” that would put them on sustainable path toward
a convergence trajectory.
4. Conclusions
Overall, during the last two decades Central and Eastern European growth
rates have not produced any visible convergence with Western Europe. Their rates
sharply contrast with the growth performance of other “emerging markets”.
During the two last decades the “emerging markets” collectively grew at a rate at
22 Joanna Poznańska, Kazimierz Poznański
least twice as high as the world average (Poznański 2011). A statistical comparison
reveals that Central Europe as a region grew at 1/3 of the rates reported by the most
robust “emerging markets” from other parts of the world, like China and Vietnam.
Poland, and to lesser extent Slovenia, are notable exceptions with growth rates
within the benchmark for convergence. However, even Poland is no match for the
fastest growing “emerging markets”, with China of course being the greatest
success story and rapidly closing the productivity and income gap. Importantly,
except for Poland, Slovenia and Slovakia, during 1989–2014 the growth rates of
the other economies of Central Europe were less than in Western Europe
combined. Those in South Central Europe (excluding Albania) were lower as
well, with some even negative, all cases indicating a lack of convergence. Such
a demand factor as wage repression might be one reason behind Central Europe’s
slower growth, as well as the continuous trade deficits. Restricted access to credit
from largely foreign-owned banking could be another culprit. Also, the large scale
emigration to seek work in Western Europe, combined with high – often double
digit – rates of unemployment might contribute as well. Understanding the Polish
exception is a challenge to economists studying the region, as is the case of
Slovenia, which is converging on Western Europe.
References
Estrin S. (2009), The effects of privatization and ownership in transition economies, ʻJournal of
Economic Literatureʼ, 47 (3).
Haiyue L. and Poznanska J., (2015), Korean FDI in China: Impact on Bilateral Trade, International
Trade and Finance Association Conference, Saratoga, FL, (conference paper).
Gabor H. (2012), Diverging patterns of FDI recovery, Vienna: WIIW.
Kornai J. (2006), The great transformation of Central Eastern Europe. Success and disappointment,
ʻEconomics of Transitionʼ.
Podkaminer L. (2013), Development patterns of Central and East European Countries, Vienna: WIIW.
Poznanska J. (2006), The Impact of Globalization on Economic Transition in China, [in:] K. Fatemi
(ed.), Globalization Opportunities and Challenges in East Asia, Binghampton: Haworth Press.
Poznanski K. (2011), Patterns of Transition, Vienna: WIIW Monthly Report, No. 3.
Poznanski K. (2012), State condition, foreign influence and alternative models of market reforms
in China, Russia and Eastern Europe, ʻInternational Critical Thoughtʼ, vol.1, No. 3.
Price & Waterhouse, 2010, “Foreign direct investment in Central and Eastern Europe” (March).
World Bank 2008, Foreign banks in the developing world, [in:] Global Development Finance:
Review, analysis and outlook, Washington D.C.: World Bank.
Comparison Of Patterns Of Convergence... 23
Streszczenie