0% found this document useful (0 votes)
51 views8 pages

The Opportunity Cost of Using Excess Capacity

The document discusses the concept of opportunity cost associated with using excess capacity in firms, emphasizing the value lost when idle resources are deployed for new projects instead of being reserved for potentially more profitable future uses. It critiques traditional capital budgeting methods for failing to account for the strategic value of real options and suggests that finance professionals should adopt real options analysis for better decision-making. The findings are particularly relevant for Indian firms in capital-heavy sectors, highlighting the need to model uncertainty and flexibility in investment decisions.

Uploaded by

aarpa100z
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as DOCX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
51 views8 pages

The Opportunity Cost of Using Excess Capacity

The document discusses the concept of opportunity cost associated with using excess capacity in firms, emphasizing the value lost when idle resources are deployed for new projects instead of being reserved for potentially more profitable future uses. It critiques traditional capital budgeting methods for failing to account for the strategic value of real options and suggests that finance professionals should adopt real options analysis for better decision-making. The findings are particularly relevant for Indian firms in capital-heavy sectors, highlighting the need to model uncertainty and flexibility in investment decisions.

Uploaded by

aarpa100z
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as DOCX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 8

1

Case Study Summary:


The Opportunity Cost of
Using Excess Capacity

Authors: Robyn McLaughlin & Robert A. Taggart, Jr.


Published in: Financial Management, Vol. 21, No. 2 (Summer, 1992), pp.
12–23
Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/3665660
2

Initial Study (Information)


Understanding Case Concept

📘 Meaning of "The Opportunity Cost of Using Excess Capacity"

Opportunity Cost refers to the value of the next best alternative


foregone when a choice is made.

So, when we talk about:

"The Opportunity Cost of Using Excess Capacity" —

It means:

💡 The value the firm gives up by using currently unused or idle


assets (like machinery, plant space, or manpower) for a new
project, instead of keeping them available for future or
alternative (possibly better) uses.

🔍 Breaking it Down:

 Excess Capacity: These are resources a company owns but is not


currently using—e.g., an idle factory, equipment, or floor space.

 Using It: If the firm decides to deploy this idle capacity for a new
product or service, it might seem like a good idea since there’s no
new cost.

 But the Trade-Off?

o Once used, that capacity is no longer available for other


potentially more profitable uses.

o It may also lead to earlier wear-and-tear or require


replacement sooner.

🧠 Real Example (Simplified):


3

A factory has idle space (excess capacity). The management considers


using it to manufacture a low-margin product.

 On paper, the project shows a positive Net Present Value (NPV).

 But: If in the future, a higher-margin product needs that space


and can't use it anymore, the firm loses that opportunity.

Thus, the opportunity cost = the value of the best future use forgone
by using the excess capacity now.

📊 Financial Relevance

In capital budgeting, this becomes important:

 You must account for the opportunity cost of using idle capacity.

 Not doing so overstates project returns and leads to suboptimal


investment decisions.

🇮🇳 Application in Indian Context

In India:

 Public Sector Units (PSUs) often have underutilized assets.

 Private companies in infrastructure, textiles, or heavy industries


may have idle capacity due to demand cycles.

Ignoring the opportunity cost of using these idle resources can result in:

 Wrong product mix

 Missed high-margin opportunities

 Unnecessary capital expenditures (capex) later

✅ In Summary:

The opportunity cost of using excess capacity is the value of what


you lose by not saving or reallocating that capacity to a
potentially better future use.
4

This concept urges finance professionals to look beyond current


profitability and evaluate the strategic value of keeping flexibility
for future, possibly superior, opportunities.

Decrypting Case
🔑 Summary and Financial Relevance in
Indian Markets

🎯 Objective

This paper redefines how opportunity cost should be viewed in capital


budgeting decisions, especially when a firm uses idle or excess
capacity (e.g., an unused plant) for new projects. The authors argue that
traditional approaches—like using Equivalent Annual Cost (EAC)—
ignore the value of real options embedded in existing capacity.

1. Reframing Opportunity Cost via Real Options

 Traditional View: Opportunity cost = Replacement cost or EAC of


capacity lost.

 Proposed View: Opportunity cost = Value of forgone production


and investment options (McLaughlin & Taggart, 1992).

📌 Indian Market Relevance: Firms in capital-heavy sectors like


power, steel, PSUs, or railways often have excess capacity.
5

Recognizing its option value helps improve decisions about asset


redeployment or privatization under policies like National Monetisation
Pipeline (NMP) or Atmanirbhar Bharat.

Reference: McLaughlin & Taggart (1992), p. 12–13

2. Real Options Explained

Idle capacity gives the firm a portfolio of options:

 European production options (one per year during the asset’s


life)

 American replacement options, allowing flexible investment


timing

By reallocating capacity (e.g., from Product A to Product B), the firm:

 Loses: Flexibility to use or delay A’s production/investment

 Gains: Option to invest in A-capacity now, but at a cost

Reference: Pindyck (1988); McDonald & Siegel (1986); McLaughlin &


Taggart (1992), pp. 13–15

3. Why the Traditional EAC Method Falls Short

 Assumes predictable, fixed investment timing

 Ignores uncertainty and flexibility

 Fails in volatile environments where decisions are contingent on


future information
6

📌 Application: In Indian startups, SMEs, or government budgeting,


decisions like delaying expansion, outsourcing production, or
refurbishing PSU assets cannot be effectively modeled using EAC
alone.

Reference: Brealey & Myers (1991); McLaughlin & Taggart (1992), p. 15

4. Empirical Simulations and Key Findings

Using numerical models and binomial option valuation (Cox-Ross-


Rubinstein method), the authors show that:

Impact on Opportunity Cost (Real


Variable
Options)

Investment cost Increases, but at a decreasing rate

Price volatility Raises value of flexibility

Time to Longer time → higher cost (more options


replacement lost)

When high, few options exercised → low


Production cost
cost

Interest rate Slight decrease in real options value

Economic Longer horizon → greater cost initially,


horizon then plateaus

Reference: Cox, Ross, & Rubinstein (1979); Trigeorgis & Mason (1987);
McLaughlin & Taggart (1992), pp. 16–21

📌 Indian Finance Insight: This is crucial for modeling long-term


infrastructure or real estate projects where project execution spans
decades (e.g., Gati Shakti, Smart Cities)
7

5. Strategic Implications for Finance Professionals

 Use real options analysis in decisions involving capacity


reallocation, investment timing, and production flexibility.

 Avoid over-reliance on static models (e.g., NPV or EAC) in dynamic


industries like energy, pharma, or telecom.

 Estimate upper bounds of opportunity cost using:

1. Replacement cost of capacity

2. Value of forgone production options

Reference: Trigeorgis (1991); Myers & Majd (1990)

FINAL TAKEAWAYS
Excess capacity is not free—its strategic value depends on future
optionality.
EAC underestimates costs in volatile markets; real options add
precision.
Indian firms must model:
 Regulatory/policy shifts (e.g., PLI, import duties).

 Commodity cycles (steel, oil, agriculture).

 Tech disruption (EVs, AI, green hydrogen).

Action Step: Integrate real options into capital budgeting for projects
>₹500 Cr where uncertainty is high.

📚 References
1. McLaughlin, R., & Taggart, R. A. (1992). The Opportunity Cost of
Using Excess Capacity. Financial Management, 21(2), 12–23.
https://www.jstor.org/stable/3665660
8

2. Brealey, R. A., & Myers, S. C. (1991). Principles of Corporate Finance


(4th ed.). McGraw-Hill.

3. McDonald, R., & Siegel, D. (1986). The Value of Waiting to Invest.


Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101(4), 707–727.

4. Pindyck, R. S. (1988). Irreversible Investment, Capacity Choice and


the Value of the Firm. American Economic Review, 78(5), 969–985.

5. Cox, J. C., Ross, S. A., & Rubinstein, M. (1979). Option Pricing: A


Simplified Approach. Journal of Financial Economics, 7(3), 229–263.

6. Trigeorgis, L., & Mason, S. P. (1987). Valuing Managerial Flexibility.


Midland Corporate Finance Journal, 5(1), 14–21.

7. Myers, S. C., & Majd, S. (1990). Abandonment Value and Project Life.
Advances in Futures and Options Research, 4, 1–21.

You might also like