Transforming Indian Agriculture Evolutio
Transforming Indian Agriculture Evolutio
No-111
Transforming Indian Agriculture: Evolution of
Technology, Policy Reforms, and Market
Liberalization for Enhancing Farmers’ Incomes
A Amarender Reddy
Title : Transforming Indian Agriculture: Evolution of Technology, Policy Reforms, and Market
Liberalization for Enhancing Farmers’ Incomes
All rights reserved. This publication may be used with proper citation and due acknowledgement
to the author(s) and the Centre For Multi-Disciplinary Development Research (CMDR), Dharwad
Citation : Amarender Reddy A. (2025), Transforming Indian Agriculture: Evolution of
Technology, Policy Reforms, and Market Liberalization for Enhancing Farmers’, CMDR
Monograph No-111 - Centre for Multi-Disciplinary Development Research (CMDR), Dharwad.
ISBN No. : 978-81-948826-5-7
Copies : 100
Published by :
The Director
Centre for Multi-Disciplinary Development Research (CMDR)
Dharwad, Karnataka, India
Phone : 91-0836-2460453
Web : cmdr.ac.in
Email : [email protected]
Preface
The primary purpose of launching the CMDR Monograph Series was to provide a platform for
social science researchers to share their valuable thoughts, long-term research outputs, and
outcomes on a specific area.
From the Green Revolution to digital agriculture, innovations have played a key role. The
novelties in agricultural research, which brought practices like precision farming, climate-
resilient crops, and AI-driven advisory services, have enhanced productivity and reduced risks
for farmers. Initiatives like NeGPA (National e-Governance Plan in Agriculture) facilitate
access to data-driven decision-making.
The union government interventions, such as PM-KISAN, KCC (Kisan Credit Card), and MSP
(Minimum Support Price) frameworks, aim to provide financial security, improve credit access,
and stabilize farm incomes. Additionally, digital land records modernization helps farmers
secure ownership rights and streamline transactions.
The shift towards open markets, digital trading platforms like eNAM (Electronic National
Agricultural Market), and contract farming has enabled farmers to negotiate better prices,
diversify cropping patterns, and reduce dependence on middlemen. The interplay of these
factors is crucial for advancing agricultural resilience, ensuring equitable growth, and fostering
an environment where traditional wisdom is harmonized with modern innovation.
Dr. Reddy has made excellent efforts to bring all the important policies and technological
interventions for ensuring food security on one platform. The analysis of the interventions helps
policymakers to design need-based interventions with special reference to the marketing of
agricultural produce.
I extend my sincere thanks to Dr. Amarendra Reddy for taking the pains to bring out the
beautiful contents and presenting them in an intellectual manner.
Basavaprabhu Jirli
Director
Transforming Indian Agriculture: Evolution of Technology, Policy
Reforms, and Market Liberalization for Enhancing Farmers’
Incomes
A Amarender Reddy, Joint Director, ICAR-NIBSM, Raipur, Email: [email protected]
Abstract:India’s recent farm laws sought to liberalize agricultural markets and attract private investment
into infrastructure such as cold chains, warehouses, and aggregation centres. However, concerns about
increased exposure to market volatility triggered widespread farmer protests demanding a legally guaranteed
Minimum Support Price (MSP). This paper critically analyzes the farm laws using secondary data drawn
from government reports and scholarly literatures. It highlights how the MSP policy, while successful in
ensuring price assurance for paddy and wheat, has largely excluded pulses and oilseeds, contributing to
nutritional imbalances and undernourishment among women and children. Farmers cultivating these
neglected crops face market uncertainties, resulting in low profitability, poor production incentives, and a
growing reliance on imports. The paper proposes a reformed MSP framework based on a price insurance
model. It recommends: (i) continued procurement of paddy and wheat to support food security objectives;
(ii) implementation of a Price Deficiency Payment Scheme (PDPS) for the remaining 21 MSP-notified crops;
and (iii) using MSP as a signal price to guide production in fragmented markets. The findings underscore the
need for a balanced approach that aligns market reforms with inclusive and stable income support
mechanisms for farmers.
Keywords: Farm laws; Farmers income; price insurance; price policy;JEL classification: Q11; Q13; Q13;
D24
1. Introduction
India's rural economy has experienced substantial transformation over the past several decades, marked
by a sharp decline in agriculture's contribution to the GDP — dropping from 47.6% in 1960-61 to just 14.4%
by 2010-11 and to 16.0 per cent 2023-24 (Government of India, 2024; Kotwal et al., 2011; Gulati and Juneja,
2022; Chand et al., 2022). The share of agriculture in rural income was declined from 57% to 39% but the
declination of rural employment from 78% to 64% (Chand et al., 2017; Birthal et al., 2022) indicates low
productivity and high dependence on agriculture. The agriculture sector everywhere is a risky business,
especially for small-scale farmers who operate it in precarious conditions in developing countries like India
(Mosley and Verschoor, 2005; Gulati et al., 2021). In India, close to 87% of farmers operate on land holdings
smaller than two hectares, with about 69% cultivating less than one hectare (Upadhyaya, 2018). These
marginal and small farmers contribute 51% of agricultural output with 46% of operated land (Singh, 2020).
Since independence of India, there are several milestones in Indian agriculture like green revolution, milk
revolution, poultry revolution and fisheries revolution and horticultural revolution which contributed to
boosting incomes of the farmers and also food and nutritional security and healthy lives (FAO, 2017).
However, farmers’ incomes remain low and there are significant regional differences in incomes, food and
nutritional security (Chand et al., 2015), this paper critically reviews food and nutrition security policies,
farmers’ incomes and suggest policy recommendations for reducing poverty, zero hunger.
1
2. Objectives of the study
Given this background the paper examined the existing policy scenario in farm sector and how the new
farm laws will be beneficial to farmers and also look in to alternate policies to enhance farmers’ incomes.
4. Results
4.1 Evolution of agricultural policies and reforms for food security and safety in India
The evolution of agricultural policies and technologies in India spans over centuries, marked by key
reforms, technological advancements, and policy shifts. The detailed timeline is given in Table 1. In the pre-
independence era, agriculture was largely feudal and subsistence-based. The Berar Cotton and Grain Market
Act (1887) introduced regulated markets, followed by the Royal Commission on Agriculture (1928), which
highlighted the urgent need for market reforms. The Bengal Famine of 1943 highlighted the need for food
security, leading to the introduction of the Public Distribution System (PDS) in 1944.
After independence (1947), the focus shifted to food self-sufficiency. The Essential Commodities Act
(1955) and State Trading Corporation (1956) were established to regulate prices and trade. The Green
Revolution (1960s), marked by the introduction of High-Yielding Varieties (HYVs) and fertilizers,
significantly increased food production. The Food Corporation of India (1964) and formalization of the PDS
(1965) strengthened food security.
In the 1970s, the White Revolution (Operation Flood) boosted milk production, while the Silver
Revolution enhanced poultry output. The Blue Revolution (1985-1990) promoted aquaculture, making India
a leading fish producer. The Golden Revolution (1991-2003) focused on horticulture and vegetable
production.
The 1991 economic reforms encouraged private sector entry, leading to the introduction of GM crops
(2002) and the Model APMC Act (2003) to promote market reforms. The eNAM (2016) created a unified
digital agricultural market.
Recent years saw significant policy reforms with the New Farm Laws (2020) aimed at liberalizing
agricultural trade. However, they were repealed in 2021 following massive farmer protests. Overall, India’s
agricultural journey reflects continuous policy adaptations and technological advancements, driving food
security, rural development, and market efficiency.
2
Table 1. Timeline of important policies and technologies introduced in India for food security
Year Policies/technologies
1700 Almost 100% under small petty traders (small, feudal)
1764 Invention of the Spinning Jenny
1769 Development of the Steam Engine
1769 Introduction of the Water Frame
1779 Mechanization of Textile Production
1778 The Rise of Iron Production
1785 Development of the Power Loom
1829 Steam-powered Railway Locomotive
1886 India's first regulated market (Karanja), Maharashtra
1887 First legislation being the Berar Cotton and Grain Market Act
1928 Royal Commission on Agriculture
1937 Agricultural Produce Marketing (Grading & Marketing), Act
1939 Regulated Markets Act in Bombay Presidency.
1943 Bengal Famine, 2nd World War
1943 Restrictions on inter-state trade of food grains
1944 Public Distribution System (PDS) Introduced on a limited scale during World War
II
1947 First Agricultural Produce Market Committee (APMC) market at Karanja
1955 Essential Commodities Act (stock limits)
1956 State Trading Corporation
1956 Agricultural Produce (Development and Warehousing) Corporations Act
1961 PL-480. Ship to mouth; every 15 minutes one ship from USA (1961-69)
1962 HYVs tested (1962-64)
1962 National Cooperative Development Act
1963 Agricultural Produce Marketing Committee (APMC) Act
1964 Food Corporation of India (FCI) Act
1965 HYVs released across India
1965 Jai Jawan-Jai Kisan slogan (Indo-Pakistan War)
1965 Public Distribution System (PDS) formalised for food grains.
1965 18,000 ton of HYV seeds imported
1967 Production increased three folds, no place to store food grains, stored in schools.
1969 Poultry revolution (silver revolution) led by private sector
1970 Operation flood to increase milk production led by cooperatives
1980 Prevention of Black Marketing & Supply of Essential Commodities Act
1985 Blue Revolution (1985-1990) to increase fish production led by private sector.
1986 The Bureau of Indian Standards Act 1986
1991 Vegetable Revolution (golden revolution (1991-2003) led by small farmers.
1992 Milk and Milk Products Order (MMPO)
1998 Jai Jawan-Jai Kisan, Jai Vignan
2002 GM crops (cotton) led by private sector
2003 Model APMC Act (Agricultural Produce Marketing Committee) Act
2006 Forward Contract (Regulation) Amendment Act
2007 The (Warehousing Development and Regulation) Act
2016 Model Agriculture Land Leasing Act
3
2016 Electronic National Agriculture Market (eNAM)
2017 Model Agricultural Produce and Livestock Marketing (promotion and facilitation)
Act
2018 Model Contract Farming Act
2019 Jai Jawan, Jai Kisan, Jai Vignan, Jai Anusandhan slogan
2020 New Farm Laws enacted with focus on liberation of agriculture
2021 New Farm Laws repealed after farmers agitation
Table 2. Average monthly income (Rs) from different sources per agricultural household during July
2018 - June 2019
The reasons for declining the share of agriculture in rural household income are
4.2.1. Declining terms of trade: As economies develops, the share of agriculture in countrie’s, domestic
product is reducing. This is applicable to all the countries and also regions (Figure 1). As a result of declining
demand for agricultural commodities vis-a-vis non-agricultural goods and services like ICT, mobiles and
automobiles, the income share and hence the price received for agricultural produce declined. This is called
declining terms of trade to agriculture; this is leading to less capital investments and abandonment of
agriculture (Dholakia and Sapre, 2013; Colman, 2009; Narayanamoorthy, 2006).
4
Figure 1. Long run agricultural commodity prices (deteriorating terms of trade for farmers).
Prices
Year
4.2.2. Income Consumption gap: Figure 2 presents data from the recent NSSO 2012-13 round, depicting the
monthly income and expenditure of agricultural households, categorized into ten deciles based on Monthly
Per capita Consumption Expenditure (MPCE). The 1st decile represents the lowest income group, while the
10th decile represents the highest. The data reveals that up to the 8th decile, farmer households spend more
than their income, indicating that their earnings are insufficient to meet their consumption needs. Only
households in the 9th and 10th deciles have incomes higher than their expenditures. These income gaps
highlight the financial strain on the majority of agricultural households, forcing them to rely on debt to meet
daily expenses. This dependence on informal credit sources further entraps them in a vicious cycle of
indebtedness (NSSO, 2014; Reddy et al., 2020).
Figure 2. Decile wise monthly income and consumption gap (Rs.) of HHs-2012-13.
4.2.3. Indebtedness: Among all the decile groups of MPCE, the incidence of indebtedness among agricultural
households is significantly higher than that of non-agricultural households (Figure. 3). Interestingly, farmers
in the upper decile groups (representing higher income levels) are relatively more indebted than those in the
lower deciles. This counter intuitive trend can be attributed to several factors. Farmers in the higher deciles
typically own larger landholdings and engage in capital-intensive farming, requiring higher investments in
inputs, machinery, and technology. Consequently, they are more likely to access institutional credit (such as
bank loans) to finance their operations. The NSSO, 2015-16 data noted that 53% of farmers were indebted,
5
with the share of indebtedness increasing with farm size due to greater access to formal credit channels.
Moreover, higher-income farmers often take larger loans to expand their operations or invest in infrastructure,
making their absolute debt levels higher. Although their income is higher, their debt-to-income ratio may still
be substantial, especially if they face crop failures, price fluctuations, or mounting interest burdens. This
results in greater financial vulnerability despite their higher income status (Chand, 2017).
70 68
65
60
% indebtedness
60
55 56
55 53 51
50 48 46 47
43 45
45 42
40
40 36
34
35
30
Agricultural households Non-agricultural All households
housholds
1 2 9 10 All households
4.2.4. “Doubling farmers’ income” is reality for large farmers, but not to small farmers: The number of farms
in India more than doubled from 71 million to 145 million between 1970-71 and 2015-16, leading to a
significant reduction in average farm size from 2.28 hectares to 1.08 hectares
(http://www.economicsdiscussion.net/). This shrinkage is driven by heavy demographic pressure, resulting in
the subdivision and fragmentation of landholdings (Padmanabhan, 2018). Several studies indicate that with
the increased adoption of farm mechanization, the earlier inverse relationship between farm size and
profitability has reversed. Larger farms, which benefit from economies of scale, are now more profitable per
hectare compared to smaller farms (Figure 4). As a result, small farmers, despite their intensive efforts,
struggle to achieve profitability and often fall into a poverty trap (NITI Aayog, 2016). Evidence shows that
marginal farmers' household consumption frequently exceeds their net monthly income from both farming
and non-farming activities. According to the 2015-16 Agriculture Census, approximately 100 million farming
households face this financial struggle. Furthermore, income growth has been significantly lower for marginal
farmers, whereas large farmers have experienced higher income growth. This trend highlights that the strategy
of doubling farm incomes is realistically achievable only for the largest land-owning group, leaving smaller
farmers behind (Candemir et al., 2021).
6
Figure 4. Income growth (in %) between 2003 and 2013 for different categories of farmers. Source: NSSO
Situation Assessment Survey of Agricultural Households.
102
85
59
52
38 34
13 10
4.2.5. Low investment capability: Due to extreme poverty, limited access to credit, and the burden of debt,
lower decile households—primarily marginal and small farmers—are unable to invest adequately in fixed
capital compared to upper decile households (Figure 5). This lack of investment becomes a major barrier to
achieving higher farm productivity. Furthermore, the inability to invest in capital assets, infrastructure, or even
education prevents these farmers from enhancing their production capacity or diversifying their income
sources. As a result, they become trapped in a cycle of perpetual indebtedness and low-income vulnerability,
making it increasingly difficult to break free from poverty and financial instability.
Figure 5. Percentage of rural households reporting fixed capital expenditure & average amount (2012-13).
40000 36,449 50
38 41 47
35000
35 40 % of hhs reported
30000 31 31 31
Amount (Rs.)
25000
28
25 30
20 18,283 17,688
20000
16
15000
9,108 7,984 10,717 20
10000 4,568 3,950 4,950 10
5000 1,643 1,957
0 0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 All
Decile class of hh asset holding
Average amount(Rs.) % of hhs reporting
4.1.6. Low institutional investment: Another significant factor contributing to the low-income levels of
farmers is the rigidity of existing farm laws, which restrict farmers to sell only in APMC mandis and impose
stock limits. These regulations limit market access and suppress competition, preventing farmers from
securing better prices for their produce. As a consequence, private sector investment in agriculture has
remained dismally low, accounting for only 2% of the Gross Fixed Capital Formation (GFCF) in 2017-18
(Figure 6). This lack of investment has triggered a vicious cycle: low prices lead to low farm incomes, which
in turn increase farmers' debt burdens and discourage further investment. This continuous cycle perpetuates
the low-income trap, making it difficult for farmers to achieve sustainable financial growth.
7
Figure 6: Sources of GFCF in 2017-18.
Public
22%
Private
corporation
2%
Household
76%
In developing countries like India, where smallholders dominate the farming community, per capita income
is generally low. Due to low agricultural production and the poor prices farmers receive for their output, their
purchasing power and savings capacity remain limited. The low level of savings results in a capital deficiency,
forcing farmers into indebtedness, which further weakens their ability to invest in productivity-enhancing
assets. On the other hand, low purchasing power reduces the demand for goods and services, thereby shrinking
the market size. The small market size, in turn, discourages private investment, creating a cycle of
underdevelopment. The lack of investment in small farms hampers productivity growth, reducing both output
and returns (Figure. 7). This self-reinforcing vicious cycle keeps farmers trapped in poverty, with little
opportunity to break freq.
Figure 7: Vicious cycle afflicted the small holders.
Low
Smallh
investm
oldings
ents
Indebte Low
dness prices
Low
incomes
During the 1960s, faced with a famine-like situation, the Government of India placed a strong emphasis on
boosting the production of paddy and wheat. To achieve this, the government introduced High-Yielding
Varieties (HYVs), increased fertilizer subsidies, and implemented guaranteed procurement at Minimum
Support Prices (MSP). These measures were part of a broader strategy of policy reforms and technological
interventions aimed at achieving food grain self-sufficiency, with a primary focus on paddy and wheat
production. The introduction of MSP was a key policy tool designed to incentivize farmers by guaranteeing a
fair price for their crops announced prior to each sowing season. This price assurance encouraged farmers to
8
invest more in agricultural inputs and expand production. The MSP also acted as a signal to farmers regarding
the competitiveness of different crops across regions, guiding them to cultivate crops that promised returns
above their cost of production. However, this narrow focus on paddy and wheat came at the expense of
diversified crop cultivation. Over time, the area and production of pulses, oilseeds, and coarse cereals—which
are essential for food diversity, nutrition, and health—declined. This shift skewed the cropping pattern,
reducing the cultivation of nutrient-rich crops and impacting dietary diversity and nutritional security.
Table 3. Projected Cost of Production and Yield for paddy and Production Shares during 2022-23
Cost of production (Rs/qtl)
Yield Share in
States (qtl/ha) A2 A2+FL C2 production(%)
Punjab 70.8 807 907 1530 10.3
Andhra Pradesh 61.2 1106 1232 1732 6.3
Chhattisgarh 42.0 1062 1307 1704 6.6
Haryana 53.4 1140 1331 2090 3.8
Bihar 28.8 1012 1339 1785 5.7
Gujarat 41.0 1153 1363 1673 1.8
Karnataka 50.9 1152 1437 1883 3.4
Himachal
Pradesh 30.9 692 1452 1990 0.1
Madhya Pradesh 43.4 1146 1461 1859 4.3
Tamil Nadu 46.3 1423 1589 2035 5.9
Telangana 53.0 1311 1613 2190 10.2
Uttar Pradesh 36.1 1271 1616 2114 12.5
Jharkhand 26.5 1188 1629 2131 1.9
Assam 36.3 1017 1661 1994 4.0
Odisha 43.3 1174 1699 2067 7.0
West Bengal 42.3 1190 1849 2229 12.9
Kerala 41.6 1614 1888 2384 0.5
Maharashtra 21.8 2551 3057 3520 2.9
All-India 43.7 1189 1533 2008 100
Note: Highlighted in grey colour are costs below national average and competitive. Source: Cost of Cultivation
data of CACP, Ministry of Agriculture & Farmers Welfare, Govt of India.
9
The findings in the Figure 8 show that the procurement of paddy was highest in Punjab followed by
Telangana, Andhra Pradesh, Chhattisgarh and Odisha. Among various states, Punjab had the highest share in
wheat procurement followed by Haryana (Figure 9). However, in recent years, procurement from other states
is also increased due to implementation of De-Centralized Procurement (DCP). Agriculturally developed and
high productive states like Punjab and Haryana also showed more marketed surplus than other states (Figure
10).
Figure 8. Procurement of paddy 2024 (lakh ton) by state. Source: Food Corporation of India, Annual reports.
Lakh ton
Non-DCP
Lakh ton
DCP
10
Figure 10. Share of major states in marketed surplus (lakh ton) and procurement of wheat (%) in 2020
40
35.2
35
30
24.8
25 23.4 23.1
21
20 16.4
15 12.5 11.5
10.3 9.9
10 6.9
4.7
5
0 0.3
0
Punjab Haryana MP Rajasthan UP Bihar Others
The procurement system in India exhibits significant geographical disparities, with higher procurement
concentrated in certain regions and for specific crops, while other regions and crops receive minimal or no
procurement support. Additionally, the MSP system suffers from imbalances and inherent deficiencies,
resulting in only around 10% of farmers benefiting from it, while the majority remain vulnerable to market
fluctuations. This scenario highlights the urgent need for policy reforms aimed at enhancing marketing
efficiency and expanding procurement operations to neglected regions and under-procured crops.
Strengthening the procurement framework through wider coverage and equitable support would ensure that a
larger share of farmers can benefit from price stability and income security. Even for paddy, states with weak
procurement operations like Assam showed market prices are far below MSP, while in states with stronger
MSP operations the market price is sometimes above MSP (Figure 11).
Figure 11. Average difference (%) between market price & MSP in major states (Kharif paddy, 2020).
5 1.3 2.4
0
-5 -2.3
-4
-10 -7.4 -6.9
-15 -10.4
-20 -17.3
11
4.6. Trends in Price
India achieved record production of pulses in 2017-18, making the country self-sufficient in pulses, and
gram alone accounts for nearly 70 percent of rabi pulses output. Gram production recorded a significant
increase during 2016-17 but India also imported a large quantity of yellow peas, a close substitute for gram,
during that time.
Figure 12. Trends in Domestic Market Price vis a vis MSP of Gram (CACP report, 2021).
The high production and large imports led to a drastic fall in domestic market prices during 2017-18
which were much below the MSP. But gradually the market prices showed improvement due to lower
production and reduced imports (Figure 12). And finally, a significant development in the gap between MSP
and market price was reported as the gap was reduced and market prices were converging towards MSP (Das,
2021). The low market prices were mainly due to depressed prices in few states like Madhya Pradesh,
Maharashtra and Rajasthan where farmers have to sell their produce immediately after harvest to meet
immediate cash needs. During this period, due to large arrivals in mandi, prices generally rule below MSP
(CACP, 2021).
Figure 13. Trends in Domestic market Price vis a vis MSP of safflower (CACP, 2021).
The safflower production has severely declined from a peak of 5.2 lakh to about 22 thousand tonnes in
last 3 decades. The low prices along with the low market demand, more remunerative alternative crops and
low oil content compared to other oilseed crops are major reasons for decline in safflower production (Aditya
et al., 2017). It is evident from the above graph that market prices of safflower seeds were much lower than
12
MSP during last five procurement seasons from 2016 to 2020. Though market prices have improved during
2019, the gap between market prices and MSP has also increased substantially. There is also a
recommendation from government to exclude the crop from MSP scheme due to low production and demand.
13
Figure 14. Disposable pattern of crop sold. NSSO situation assessment survey, 2013
100
90
26 29
80
70
60 23
50
51
40
30
51
20
10 20
0
Marginal Large
Table 4 indicate that the APMC’s mostly be used as a tax revenue source for state governments. Currently,
only a small portion of the farmer’s produce especially marginal farmers’ is sold in the mandi’s and the rest
is sold outside APMC markets. In this background, the new farm laws are hope to legalize this practice and
strengthening the outside markets to reduce exploitation and make them more efficient.
Challenges such as weak coordination among procurement agencies, insufficient storage infrastructure,
and low awareness hinder MSP effectiveness. Procurement remains largely restricted to rice and wheat,
leaving other crops underserved and contributing to poor MSP knowledge among growers. Notably, awareness
of rice and wheat MSP is higher in major procurement states like Punjab, Haryana, and Chhattisgarh, where
historically grains are sourced for public distribution systems (PDS) and buffer stocks (Gulati and Banerjee,
2015). Strengthening outreach and infrastructure in underserved regions is vital to achieving equitable MSP
outcomes nationwide.
14
Figure 15. State-wise Awareness of Farmers about Minimum Support Price (MSP) of Crops in Major Crop
Seasons (%). Source: NSS Report No. 587: Situation Assessment of Agricultural Households and Land and
Livestock Holdings of Households in Rural India, 2019.
7000 6156
6000
Rs/ha of GCA
5000
3707
4000
3000
2000 1528
1000
0
Himachal
Madhya
West
Kerala
India
Gujarat
Bihar
Telangana
Jammu&
Odisha
Uttarakhand
Tamil
Haryana
Assam
Punjab
Andhra
Jharkhand
Chattisgarh
Karnataka
Uttar
Maharashtra
Rajasthan
Presently, the amount of fertilizer subsidy is concentrated mostly in seven states including Uttar Pradesh,
followed by Maharashtra, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, Andhra Pradesh, Punjab and Gujarat. These seven
states together holding 57.09 per cent of the country’s GCA and receives 62 per cent of the total fertilizer
subsidy distributed. The share of subsidy per ha of GCA is highest in the states of Andhra Pradesh, Punjab,
Telangana and Haryana, and lowest in Rajasthan (Figure 16), Maharashtra, Chhattisgarh and Madhya Pradesh.
Although most of the states receive subsidy almost equal to their share in GCA, Uttar Pradesh, Andhra
15
Pradesh, Punjab, Haryana and Telangana receive greater subsidy than their share in GCA (Saini and Kozicka,
2014).
Figure 17. Food buffer stock norm and actual stocks from 2005 to 2020. Source: FCI annual reports, 2020
and 2021.
Since last several years, India’s food grain buffer reserves exceed twice the mandated buffer stocking
thresholds (Figure 17). As of 2020, the economic cost estimates for rice and wheat stood at ₹37,026 and
₹27,026 per tonne, respectively. Historical data reveals that, barring a brief period between 2005 and 2007
when reserves dipped below required levels, stockpiles have consistently surpassed official norms in recent
years. This has resulted in an excess of approximately 50 million tonnes (MT) of grains—valued at around
₹1.5 trillion—with annual interest burdens of nearly ₹10,000 crore.
Two primary factors drive heightened procurement: supply and demand dynamics. On the supply side,
rising Minimum Support Prices (MSPs) have positioned the government as the primary purchaser of surplus
grain. Simultaneously, expanding obligations under national food security programs compel agencies like the
Food Corporation of India (FCI) to intensify procurement efforts. This problem is intensified by open-ended
procurement policies followed by various state governments. Consequently, the government now acquires a
dominant share of marketable produce (in some states like Telangana and Chhattisgarh more than 90% of
marketed surplus), creating systemic pressures to manage oversized reserves while balancing welfare
commitments (Nirmal, 2020).
16
4.9.2. Operations of Buffer stock
The cost of grain management comprises acquisition costs—including pooled procurement costs and
associated incidentals—and distribution expenses. When combining the Minimum Support Price (MSP) with
expenditures on logistics, storage, handling, and distribution, the total economic cost is estimated at ₹37,026
per tonne for rice and ₹27,026 per tonne for wheat (as shown in the figure below) in 2020 (Figure 18).
Recently, the cost of maintaining buffer stocks has been increasing, primarily due to rising procurement-
related expenses such as storage, handling, transportation, and other logistical charges.
At the same time, the government has reduced the reserve prices of rice and wheat to facilitate the disposal
of surplus buffer stocks. In the Open Market Sale Scheme (OMSS), rice is priced at ₹22,500 per tonne in 2020,
down from ₹27,850 one year back, while the reserve price of wheat has been lowered to ₹21,350 per tonne in
2020 from ₹22,450 one year back. These revised prices are significantly below their respective economic
costs, and the reductions have widened the existing gap between sale prices and actual costs.
The main reasons behind this price cut include excess stock levels, limited storage capacity, and declining
demand for grains in the open market in recent years. As a result, the widening cost-revenue gap has placed
considerable financial stress on the Food Corporation of India (FCI), which is incurring losses of
approximately 39.2% on rice and 21% on wheat sold under OMSS in year 2020. Similar trends are being
observed in international grain markets as well.
Figure 18. Economics of buffer stock operations for the year 2020. Source: Authors calculations from FCI
annual reports, various issues.
After elaborating the efficiency of the procurement system, it can be said that the practice of procuring
more than stipulated buffer quantities lead to certain imbalances. Therefore, there is a necessity for offloading
the excess stock in the international or domestic market, which could lead to a price crash. Also, it could lead
to a loss when the international market prices or the FCI reserved prices are lower than the actual economic
cost of the stock which is inflated by the excess expenditure on handling, logistics, storage and distribution of
the produce.
17
4.10. Procurement policy biased against other crops
As of now, the only crops that see substantial procurement by the government are rice and wheat. The
government is more concerned about these grains as these represent food security. Another reason of
reluctancy of the government for pulse procurement is its rising MSP. The MSP of pulses is almost three times
that of wheat and rice. However, whatever the reasons, pulses along with the oilseeds have been discriminated
against rice and wheat and it is economically unfeasible to increase their procurement under MSP. But at this
18
time when the demand for pulses is soaring, there is a need to build some alternate mechanisms as pulses and
oilseeds are poor man’s crops.
However, the disposal of a huge volumes of procured stocks of pulses under the Open Market Sale
Scheme (OMSS) by NAFED faces a significant challenge, particularly in the depressed market conditions.
Since pulses are prone to infestation during prolonged storage, so the timely disposal of stocks assumes
significance. The average price recovery in the disposal of PSS stocks under OMSS by NAFED has been even
less than MSP. Therefore, the market price continues to prevail at a much lower level than MSP (Table 7).
The disposal of pulses procured under the PSS by NAFED has been a challenge as the federation incurs
heavy losses in the open market, and sale of stocks depresses market prices. Lack of government policy for
the sale of pulses stocks like wheat and rice is a major constraint for ensuring nutritional security to a large
mass of people without impacting the market prices (Jayan, 2018).
19
Table 8. Sale price of various crops.
Crop Average sale price
Soybean 6-15% less than MSP
Groundnut 25-40% less than MSP
Sunflower 35% less than MSP
Mustard 15-20% less than MSP
Source: CACP reports, 2021
At the present consumption level, estimated at 23.5 million tonnes annually, domestic production from
both primary and secondary sources meets only about 40% of the demand. The remaining 60% is fulfilled
through imports. Due to the sluggish growth in oilseed production, the gap between demand and supply
persists, necessitating substantial import volumes to meet national consumption needs (Arora, 2013).
Figure 19. Edible oil: imports versus domestic production (million tons).
To enhance domestic availability of edible oils and reduce the country's heavy reliance on imports, the
Government of India has launched the National Mission on Edible Oils – Oil Palm (NMEO-OP). This
initiative aims to boost indigenous oilseed production through improved cultivation practices, research
support, and consumer awareness campaigns. Currently, India imports approximately 15 million tonnes of
edible oil annually, incurring an import bill of over ₹70,000 crore. However, the country has an underutilized
refining capacity of nearly 30 million tonnes, with only about 45% of it being operational, according to the
Solvent Extractors’ Association (SEA). To address this imbalance, the government has been promoting the
import of crude rather than refined oil, enabling better utilization of domestic refining infrastructure and create
employment in the sector.
20
Regulatory hurdles are hindering release and adoption of Genetically Modified (GM) Mustard, even
though it is having potential to expand area and production of edible oilseeds. Approved for environmental
release after extensive scientific review, GM mustard can help bridge the yield gap in mustard cultivation—a
key oilseed crop in India. With higher productivity, improved resistance to biotic and abiotic stresses, and
greater oil content, GM mustard can contribute to increasing domestic edible oil output substantially. And also
open up scope for introducing GMO crops in other edible oilseeds like soyabean, where there is a lot of scope.
Reviving the edible oil sector will require a multi-pronged approach: enhancing productivity through
technology adoption (like GM crops), expanding area under oilseeds, improving seed quality and distribution,
supporting price incentives, and strengthening processing and value chains (Reddy and Bantilan, 2012).
Combined, these efforts can help India reduce its import dependence and achieve greater self-sufficiency in
edible oils. Similar strategies have to be followed in pulses to reduce import dependency (Reddy et al., 2023).
4.17. Context of liberalisation of agricultural markets (new farm laws, September 27, 2020)
Multiple Economic Surveys have highlighted concerns over the functioning of Agricultural Produce
Market Committees (APMCs) and the monopolistic structures they support. While improvements in market
efficiency are necessary, they alone do not ensure fairness or equity for all stakeholders. After years of policy
stagnation, a comprehensive reform in agricultural marketing was seen as essential. The introduction of the
new farm laws marked a strategic shift intended to liberalize agricultural markets and enhance the livelihoods
of farmers, especially the small and marginal ones who constitute nearly 85% of India’s farming population
and have been the most disadvantaged under the existing APMC-dominated regime.
Over the years, the central government encouraged states to adopt model agricultural market reforms, but
with limited success. The new farm laws aimed to overcome these limitations by creating a unified national
market, increasing private sector participation, and expanding the choices available to farmers. These reforms
were designed to allow farmers to sell their produce beyond the confines of state-licensed mandis, and to
facilitate smoother interstate trade by removing barriers created by state-level APMC legislations. The goal
was to reduce inefficiencies and revenue losses that farmers often experienced under the previous system.
Importantly, the reforms also enabled contract farming, providing a legal framework for farmers to enter
into pre-agreed contracts with agribusinesses, processors, exporters, or retailers. This was intended to ensure
assured markets, reduce price risks, and improve access to technology and inputs. Additionally, the laws
proposed amendments to the APMC Acts and the Essential Commodities Act to remove restrictions on the
storage and movement of agricultural commodities, thus promoting private investment in post-harvest
infrastructure (Chand, 2020). By addressing challenges like weak infrastructure and multiple intermediaries,
the reforms aimed to increase price realization and empower farmers with greater autonomy in marketing their
produce.
Opposition stemmed from fears that the reforms would weaken the minimum support price (MSP) system,
dismantle APMC mandis, and expose small and marginal farmers to exploitation by large corporations.
Concerns were also raised about the dilution of the role of traditional market intermediaries, though the
government argued that the new laws would benefit millions of farmers by enhancing market access,
encouraging contract farming, and reducing post-harvest losses.
Despite prolonged negotiations and public outreach efforts, the protests intensified, leading to a
significant political standoff. Eventually, in response to sustained pressure from farmer unions—primarily
22
from Punjab and Haryana—the central government announced the repeal of the three farm laws. The formal
withdrawal took place on December 1, 2021, marking a rare reversal of a major policy decision.
4.18.1. The Farmers’ Produce Trade and Commerce (Promotion and Facilitation) Ordinance, 2020 (FPTC
Act)
Among the three farm laws, the Farmers' Produce Trade and Commerce (FPTC) Act was the first. In the
wake of the economic disruptions caused by the COVID-19 pandemic, the government saw an opportunity to
introduce bold policy measures to address longstanding structural challenges in agriculture. The FPTC Act
was enacted with the aim of providing farmers with alternative marketing options beyond the regulated APMC
mandis, which had been criticized for lack of transparency and inconsistent enforcement of rules.
The Act establishes a legal framework for farmers to sell their produce in designated "trade areas" outside
the APMC markets, thereby creating multiple avenues for transactions. It encourages the use of digital
platforms and e-commerce in agriculture and includes provisions for registering traders and recording
transactions in these trade areas. One of the key benefits of the Act is that it permits direct procurement from
farmers’ fields, allowing them greater autonomy in price negotiation (Chand, 2020; The Hindu, 2021b).
By creating a level playing field between APMCs and private players, the FPTC Act promotes healthy
competition and is expected to streamline the agricultural value chain. It is particularly beneficial for
smallholder farmers, as it supports market diversification, reduces excessive intermediation, and can
potentially enable farmers' groups to sell directly to consumers. Overall, the Act seeks to foster a more
efficient, transparent, and farmer-centric marketing environment.
4.18.2. The Farmers (Empowerment and Protection) Agreement on Price Assurance and Farm Services
Ordinance, 2020 (APAFS)
The Agreement on Price Assurance and Farm Services (APAFS) Act represents a streamlined and
enhanced approach to contract farming, building on earlier models already adopted by several states. Unlike
the previous frameworks that often-involved complex procedures and state-specific compliance burdens, this
Act simplifies the contractual process and focuses primarily on securing pre-agreed prices for agricultural
produce. It also facilitates the provision of farm inputs and services by buyers to farmers.
The Act offers a more farmer-friendly structure than traditional contract farming agreements, with several
provisions designed to safeguard farmers’ interests—especially in light of their expectations around post-
harvest prices. The agreement is structured to ensure that farmers are not bound by rigid terms and instead
have the flexibility to negotiate in a more transparent and predictable environment.
A prominent example of this model in practice is seen in the dairy sector. Nestlé, a global food company,
has successfully implemented contract-based arrangements with dairy farmers in India. The company provides
technical assistance, veterinary services, and essential inputs while operating a highly efficient supply chain.
Farmers receive weekly payments based on milk quality, particularly its fat and solids-not-fat (SNF) content,
ensuring fair and performance-based pricing (Chand, 2023).
The Act introduces a framework for imposing stock limits based on price triggers: a 100% rise in the
retail price of perishable horticultural produce or a 50% increase in the price of non-perishable food items. By
23
limiting arbitrary controls, the policy is expected to encourage large-scale private investment in infrastructure
such as storage facilities, cold chains, and transportation networks. This, in turn, could help minimize food
wastage, stabilize prices across regions and seasons, and prevent sudden market collapses.
Additionally, the legislation provides for proper documentation and tracking of privately held storage
facilities, including details on quantity and location, contributing to better transparency and supply chain
management.
5. Way forward
From the above discussions, it has realized that there is a need for gradual shifting of scheme from assured
price to assured income. For that purpose, this paper suggests two alternatives. First one which is the
alternative to MSP operation is, shift to a Price Deficiency Payment (PDP) system, where paddy and wheat
could be procured under MSP up to the necessary levels to meet the PDS demands but beyond that it must be
disbanded and the remaining 21 crops should be provided PDP (Figure 20). The PDP system is more efficient
than physical procurement.
Figure 20. MSP based Price Deficiency Payment Mechanism. Authors calculations.
24
The other alternative is the modification of Crop insurance to income insurance scheme, the PMFBY,
which needs to cover the price risk in addition to the yield risk. The irrigation should be strengthened and the
budget under agriculture subsidies should be pooled under this for providing income insurance (Figure 21).
This will prevent market distortion and assure the farmers a minimum income.
So, after all the discussions the paper suggests the academicians and researchers to take the responsibility
of ensuring sustainability and equitability as well as achieving market efficiency along with the intervention
of government by providing some safeguard.
25
Bihar and Orissa have limited capabilities. Because of this, Punjab and Haryana farmers received higher prices
then farmers in East-Indian states like Bihar over several decades.
In addition, except paddy and wheat, there was no proper procurement mechanism for the remaining 21
crops for which MSP is announced. Although under decentralised procurement system, some states are
procuring pulses and oilseeds, they just cover less than 5% of the production.
India cannot depend on achieving target of doubling farmers’ incomes just by procuring only paddy and
wheat that too from only a handful of states. The current MSP policy is hugely discriminatory against rainfed
farmers who grow pulses, oilseeds, fruits and vegetables, and constitute more than 70% of the 12 crore farm
families in India.
Even under ideal situations, the actual procurement at MSP cannot reach more than 20% of farmers, hence
cannot be a solution to increasing farmers’ incomes. The actual procurement was less than 5% of market
arrivals for pulses and oilseeds and even for paddy and wheat it reached only about 20-30 % farmers in 2019
crop season.
The prices of oilseeds were less than 10 to 30% in most of the markets during the recent kharif season.
The biased policy also contributing to huge import of edible oils each year incurring enormous cost to Indian
exchequer to the extent of Rs.70,000 crore. Whereas fruits and vegetable are entirely out of the MSP
procurement policy.
In the changed scenario of surplus food production with buffer stocks exceeding 2-3 times of the normal
requirement, the past biased MSP policy will do more harm than the good. Now it is time to broad base MSP
policy to other crops to encourage crop diversification to contribute to not only food security but also
nutritional security.
5.4. The new farm laws encourage investments and new technology
The new farm laws provide congenial long-term environment to promote free markets in which price
discovery takes place based on demand and supply, hence will incentivize crop diversification to high value
crops like pulses, oilseeds, fruits and vegetables. It will also encourage huge corporate investments in food
processing sector both in supply chain development as well as retail sector. This will ultimately enhances
farmers’ incomes through backward linkages.
Under the new farm laws, the role of the MSP policy should be altered in such a way that (i) Procurement
of paddy and wheat meets the needs of procurement for food security, (ii) Price Deficiency Payment Scheme
(PDPS) for remaining 21 crops and (iii) Provide signal price for crops with fragmented markets.
To modify the MSP policy to meet the above three objectives is a balanced act, which require different
operational modalities.
Under PSS only for two commodities, government is spending about Rs. 2 lakh crore every year on food
subsidy. To expand it to all 23 crops, some estimates indicated that it may cost up to Rs.18 lakh crore, which
is beyond the capacity of both central and state governments in terms of finances and also logistical
arrangements.
The implementation of the PDPS is easy and feasible across the country, as all the necessary information
for direct transfer of price deficiency payment like farmers identification, land records, bank accounts are
collected under already fully functional PM-KISAN scheme. The model price of all the APMC markets is
available under AGMARKNET. Only additional information needed is the quantity sold by each farmer,
which can be estimated based on acreage data collected by state department of agriculture at the beginning of
the season or actual submission of sale receipts.
The PDPS was implemented in the past in Madhya Pradesh under Shavantar Yojana. However, there are
some design problems in the scheme, where in some problems in estimation of model price leading to collusion
among traders and farmers to artificially push down the model price, so that the deficiency payment will be
higher. These design problems in estimating model price can be overcome by the benchmarking with
international price or with past price, which is immune to manipulation.
The implementation of PDPS schemes is not dependent on the capacity of the government to procure
through APMCs or any other agency, hence farmers fear of neglecting the APMC markets under new laws
will be eased.
Overall, with the implementation of new farm laws, role of MSP policy also needs to change to
accommodate pro-market price insurance policy options.
28
Reference
1. Aditya K S, Subash S P, Praveen K V, Nithyashree M L, Bhuvana N and Sharma A. 2017.
Awareness about Minimum Support Price and Its Impact on Diversification Decision of Farmers in
India. Asia & the Pacific Policy Studies, Vol 4, No 3. Pp 514-526.
2. Alagh Y K. 2018. Policy Paralysis. The Indian Express. Available at
https://indianexpress.com/article/opinion/columns/policy-paralysis-5415092/.
3. Arora V P S. 2013. Agricultural Policies in India: Retrospect and Prospect. Agricultural Economics
Research Review. Vol. 26. No.2. pp 135-157.
4. Birthal, P. S., Hazrana, J., Negi, D. S., & Mishra, A. K. (2022). Assessing benefits of crop insurance
vis-a-vis irrigation in Indian agriculture. Food Policy, 112, 102348.
5. CACP. 2021. Price Policy for Rabi Crops. The Marketing Season 2020-21. Available at
https://cacp.dacnet.nic.in/ViewReports.aspx?Input=2&PageId=40&KeyId=682.
6. Candemir, A., Duvaleix, S., & Latruffe, L. (2021). Agricultural cooperatives and farm
sustainability–A literature review. Journal of Economic Surveys, 35(4), 1118-1144.
7. Chand N. 2018. The agrarian distress and India’s policy paralysis. The Policy Times. Available at
https://thepolicytimes.com/the-agrarian-distress-and-indias-policy-paralysis/.
8. Chand R, Saxena R and Rana S. 2015. Estimates and Analysis of Farm Income in India, 1983–84
to 2011–12. Economic & Political Weekly. Vol. l, no 22. Pp 139-145.
9. Chand R, Srivastava S K and Singh J. 2017. Changing Structure of Rural Economy of India
Implications for Employment and Growth. Discussion Paper. NITI Aayog. Pp 6-8. Available at
https://niti.gov.in/writereaddata/files/document_publication/Rural_Economy_DP_final.pdf.
10. Chand R. 2017. Doubling farmers’ income. Rationale, Strategy, Prospects and Action Plan. NITI
Ayog Policy paper no. 1/2017. New Delhi. Pp 28-29.
http://agcensus.nic.in/document/agcen1516/T1_ac_2015_16.pdf.
11. Chand R. 2020. New Farm Acts. Understanding the Implications. NITI Ayog. Working Paper
1/2020.
12. Chand, R. (2023). India’s White revolution. Achievement and Next phase, NITI Working Paper No.
001/2023
13. Chand, R. Pramod Joshi, Shyam Khadka (2022)Indian Agriculture Towards 2030, Pathways for
Enhancing Farmers’ Income, Nutritional Security and Sustainable Food and Farm Systems, India
Studies in Business and Economics, Springer. Singapur.
14. Colman D. 2009. Agriculture’s Terms of Trade: Issues and Implications. Presidential Address
prepared for presentation at the 27th Conference of the International Association of Agricultural
Economists, Beijing, China, August 17, 2009. Available at
https://ageconsearch.umn.edu/record/53200/files/Colman%20FINAL.pdf.
15. Das S. 2021. Bring pulses under Public Distribution System. Financial Express. Available at
https://www.financialexpress.com/opinion/bring-pulses-under-public-distribution-
system/2170512/.
16. Dholakia R H and Sapre A. 2013. Intersectoral Terms of Trade and Aggregate Supply Response in
Gujarat and Indian Agriculture. IIMA Working Paper, WP No 2013-07-02. Indian Institute of
Management, Ahmedabad. Available at
https://web.iima.ac.in/assets/snippets/workingpaperpdf/20865173482013-07-02.pdf.
29
17. FAO (2017). The future of food and agriculture: trends and challenges. Food and Agriculture
Organization of the United Nations. Available at
http://www.fao.org/3/i6583e/i6583e.pdf.
18. Government of India. (2024). Economic Survey 2023-24. Ministry of Finance, Department of
Economic Affairs. https://www.indiabudget.gov.in/economicsurvey/
19. Gulati A and Banerjee P. 2015. Rationalizing Fertilizer Subsidy in India: Key Issues and Policy
Options. Working paper 307. Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations.
New Delhi.
20. Gulati, A., & Juneja, R. (2022). Transforming indian agriculture. Indian agriculture towards, 2030,
9-37.
21. Gulati, A., Zhou, Y., Huang, J., Tal, A., Juneja, R., & Huang, J. (2021). Reforms and incentive
policies in China’s agriculture. From Food Scarcity to Surplus: Innovations in Indian, Chinese and
Israeli Agriculture, 179-225.
https://www.economicsdiscussion.net/agriculture/causes-of-the-low-productivity-of-agriculture-
in-india/2264.
22. Jayan T V. 2018. Govt must support pulses & oilseeds, too, not just rice and wheat: Crisil. The
Hindu. Available at https://www.thehindubusinessline.com/economy/agri-business/govt-must-
support-pulses-oilseeds-too-not-just-rice-and-wheat-crisil/article23576769.ece.
23. Kotwal, Ashok, Bharat Ramaswami, and Wilima Wadhwa. 2011. "Economic liberalization and
Indian economic growth: What's the evidence?." Journal of Economic Literature 49.4 (2011): 1152-
1199.
24. Mosley P and Verschoor A. 2005. Risk Attitudes in the Vicious Circle of Poverty. European Journal
of Development Research. Vol. 17, No. 1. Pp 59-88.
25. Narayanamoorthy A. 2006. State of India’s Farmers. Economic & Political Weekly. Vol. 41, No. 6.
Pp 471–73.
26. Nirmal R. 2020. Cut in reserve price of rice, wheat will hit FCI. The Hindu. Available at
https://www.thehindubusinessline.com/economy/agri-business/fci-sees-red-government-reduces-
reserve-price-of-rice-wheat/article30632110.ece.
27. NITI Aayog. 2016. Evaluation Study on Efficacy of Minimum Support Prices (MSP) on Farmers.
Report No.231. Pp 12-14. Available at
https://niti.gov.in/writereaddata/files/writereaddata/files/document_publication/MSP-report.pdf.
28. NSSO. 2014. Key Indicators of Debt and Investment in India, NSS 70th Round, (January–
December 2013). Report No. NSS KI (70/18.2). National Sample Survey Office, New Delhi.
29. Padmanabhan V. 2018. The land challenge underlying India’s farm crisis. Available at
https://www.livemint.com/Politics/SOG43o5ypqO13j0QflaawM/The-land-challenge-underlying-
Indias-farm-crisis.html.
30. Praveen K V, Aditya K S, Nithyashree M L and Sharma A. 2017. Fertilizer subsidies in India: an
insight to distribution and equity issues. Journal of Crop and Weed. Vol. 13, No. 3. Pp 24-31.
31. Reddy A A, Raju S S, Bose A. 2020. Farmers’ Income, Indebtedness and Agrarian Distress in India.
The Microfinance Review. Volume 12. No. 1. Pp 20-38.
32. Reddy AA (2021) Assuring Farmers Income in the Context of New Farm Laws: Issues and the Way
Forward presented in 2021 Conference, August 17-31, 2021, Virtual from International Association
of Agricultural Economists, New Delhi.
33. Reddy, A. A. (2018). Electronic national agricultural markets. Current Science, 115(5), 826-837.
30
34. Reddy, A. A., & Bantilan, M. C. S. (2012). Competitiveness and technical efficiency: Determinants
in the groundnut oil sector of India. Food Policy, 37(3), 255-263.
35. Reddy, A. A., Bhagwat, K. D., Tiwari, V. L., Kumar, N., & Dixit, G. P. (2023). Policies and
incentives for promotion of pulses production and consumption: A Review. Journal of Food
Legumes, 36(4), 209-228.
36. Saini S and Kozicka M. 2014. Evolution and Critique of Buffer Stocking Policy of India. Working
Paper 283. Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations (ICRIER), New Delhi.
Pp 14-32.
37. Sharma S. 2020. Not only crude, India heavily depends on edible oil imports too; here’s why there
is production crisis. Financial Express. Available at
https://www.financialexpress.com/economy/not-only-crude-india-heavily-depends-on-edible-oil-
imports-too-heres-why-there-is-production-crisis/1860047/.
38. Singh S. 2020. View: Why do India's farmers kill themselves? Can market reforms help? The
Economic Times. Available at
https://economictimes.indiatimes.com/news/economy/agriculture/view-why-do-indias-farmers-
kill-themselves-can-market-reforms-help/articleshow/78363485.cms.
39. The Economic Times. 2017. Oilseed prices fall below MSP; farmers may shift to other crops.
Available at https://economictimes.indiatimes.com/news/economy/agriculture/oilseed-prices-fall-
below-msp-farmers-may-shift-to-other-crops/articleshow/59251833.cms.
40. The Hindu. 2021.a Centre to add another 1000 mandis to e-NAM. Available at
https://www.thehindubusinessline.com/economy/agri-business/centre-to-add-another-1000-
mandis-to-enam/article33751101.ece#.
41. The Hindu. 2021.b New Farm Laws heralds new era of market freedom: Economic Survey.
Available at https://www.thehindu.com/business/Economy/new-farm-laws-herald-new-era-of-
market-freedom-economic-survey/article33695507.ece.
42. Times of India. 2020. Farm income, MSP, row over new laws: All explained in 5 charts. Available
at
http://timesofindia.indiatimes.com/articleshow/79798223.cms?utm_source=contentofinterest&ut
m_medium=text&utm_campaign=cppst.
43. Upadhyaya Y. 2018. How can small farmers' income be increased? Available at
https://www.indiawaterportal.org/articles/why-care-about-farmers.
31
Annexure 1. Status of adoption of reforms with respect to 12 identified areas and notification of rules
thereunder provision-wise are given in the table below:
Si.
No. Area of Reforms State adopted the reform provision in Act Notified the rules
1 Private market A.P., Arunachal Pradesh, Assam,
Chhattisgarh, Goa, Gujarat, Haryana, H.P.,
Jharkhand, Karnataka, Maharashtra, A.P., Chhattisgarh, H.P.,
Manipur, Meghalaya, Mizoram, Nagaland, Karnataka, Maharashtra,
Odisha, Punjab, Rajasthan, Sikkim, Tamil Odisha, Punjab, Rajasthan,
Nadu, Telangana, Tripura, U.P., Sikkim, Telangana, Tripura,
Uttarakhand, W.B. and Chandigarh (26 U.P., Uttarakhand, W.B. and
states/UTs). Chandigarh (15 states/UTs).
2 Direct Marketing A.P., Arunachal Pradesh, Assam,
(wholesale Chhattisgarh, Goa, Gujarat, Haryana, H.P.,
purchase from farm Jharkhand, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh,
gate outside the Maharashtra, Manipur, Meghalaya, A.P., Chhattisgarh, Haryana,
market - yard) Mizoram, Nagaland, Punjab, Rajasthan, H.P., Karnataka, M. P.,
Sikkim, Tamil Nadu, Telangana, Tripura, Maharashtra, Punjab, Rajasthan,
U.P., Uttarakhand, W.B. and Sikkim, Telangana, U.P., W.B.
Chandigarh (26 states/UTs). and Chandigarh (14 states/UTs).
3 Declaring A.P., Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, Gujarat,
warehouse/silo/cold Haryana, Jharkhand, Karnataka, Manipur,
storage as deemed Meghalaya, Nagaland, Tamil Nadu, A.P., Karnataka, Telangana and
market –yard Telangana, Tripura and U.P.(14 states/UTs). U.P.(4 states).
4 e-Trading Platform A.P., Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, Goa,
Gujarat, Haryana, Jharkhand, Karnataka, A.P., Goa, Gujarat, Karnataka,
Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Manipur, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra,
Meghalaya, Nagaland, Punjab, Rajasthan, Punjab, Rajasthan, Telangana,
Tamil Nadu, Telangana, Tripura, U.P., W.B. U.P., W.B. and Chandigarh
and Chandigarh (21 states/UTs). (12 states/UTs).
5 Single point levy of A.P., Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, A.P., Chhattisgarh, Goa,
market fee Chhattisgarh, Goa, Gujarat, Haryana, H.P., Gujarat, Haryana, H.P.,
Jharkhand, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh,
Maharashtra, Manipur, Meghalaya, Maharashtra, Odisha, Punjab,
Mizoram, Nagaland, Odisha, Punjab, Rajasthan, Sikkim, Tamil Nadu,
Rajasthan, Sikkim, Tamil Nadu, Telangana, Telangana, U.P., Uttarakhand,
Tripura, U.P., Uttarakhand, W.B. and W.B. and Chandigarh (19
Chandigarh (27 states/UTs). states/UTs).
6 Single Unified A.P., Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, A.P., Chhattisgarh, Goa,
License Chhattisgarh, Goa, Gujarat, Haryana, H.P., Gujarat, Haryana, H.P.,
Jharkhand, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh,
Maharashtra, Manipur, Meghalaya, Maharashtra, Odisha, Punjab,
Mizoram, Nagaland, Odisha, Punjab, Rajasthan, Sikkim, Tamil Nadu,
32
Rajasthan, Sikkim, Tamil Nadu, Telangana, Telangana, U.P., Uttarakhand,
Tripura, U.P., Uttarakhand, W.B. and W.B. and Chandigarh (19
Chandigarh (27 states/UTs). states/UTs).
7 Rationalization of A.P., Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, Goa, Gujarat, H.P., Jharkhand, Karnataka,
market fee Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Manipur, Meghalaya, Mizoram, Nagaland,
Odisha, Rajasthan, Sikkim, Tamil Nadu, Telangana, Tripura, U.P.,
Uttarakhand, W.B., NCT of Delhi and Puducherry (25 states/UTs).
8 Rationalization of A.P., Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, Chhattisgarh, Goa, Gujarat, H.P. (partial),
Commission Jharkhand, Karnataka (partial), M.P., Maharashtra, Manipur, Meghalaya,
charges Mizoram, Nagaland, Odisha, Sikkim, Tamil Nadu, Telangana, Tripura, U.P.,
Uttarakhand, W.B., and Puducherry (24 states/UTs).
9 Reciprocity of Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, Gujarat, Jharkhand, Manipur, Meghalaya,
trading license Nagaland, Tripura and U.P(rules). (9 states). (Note: Neither any states have
notified the rules nor entered into MoU.)
10 De-regulation of F A.P., Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, Chhattisgarh, Gujarat, H.P., Jharkhand,
&V Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Manipur, Meghalaya, Nagaland,
Odisha, Rajasthan, Sikkim, Tamil Nadu, Tripura, U.P., W.B. and NCT of Delhi
(21 states/UT).
11 Exemption of Karnataka, Maharashtra, Rajasthan, U.P. and NCT of Delhi (5 states/UT).
market fee for
direct sale to
processing units by
farmers/FPOs at
their premises
12 Exemption of A.P., Arunachal Pradesh, Chhattisgarh, Goa, Karnataka, Rajasthan, Tamil
market fee on Nadu, Telangana, U.P., Uttarakhand and NCT of Delhi (11 states/UTs).
produce brought
from other state for
processing
Source: National Policy Framework on Agricultural Marketing.
https://agriwelfare.gov.in/Documents/HomeWhatsNew/Draft_National_Policy_framework_AgriMarketing_
25112024.pdf
33