Unit 2 & 3 - (Econ 101) Economics
Unit 2 & 3 - (Econ 101) Economics
Contents
2.0 Aims and Objectives
2.1 Introduction
2.2 Demand Analysis
2.2.1 Definition of Demand
2.2.2 Factors Affecting Demand
2.2.3 Change in Quantity Demanded and Change in Demand
2.2.4 Individual and Market Demand Curve
2.3 Supply Analysis
2.3.1 Definition of Demand
2.3.2 Factors Affecting Supply of a Commodity
2.3.3 Change in Quantity Supplied and Change in Supply
2.3.4 Individual and Market Supply Curves
2.4 Market Equilibrium
2.4.1 Definition of Market Equilibrium
2.4.2 Effects of Change in Demand or Supply on the Market Equilibrium
2.5 Elasticities
2.5.1 Elasticity of Demand
2.5.1.1 Price Elasticity of Demand
2.5.1.2 Income Elasticity of Demand
2.5.1.3 Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand
2.5.2 Elasticity of Supply
2.5.2.1 Price Elasticity of Supply
2.5.3 Application of Elasticity
2.6 Key Terms
2.7 Answers to Check Your Progress Exercise
2.8 Model Examination Questions
2.9 References
42
2.0 AIMS AND OBJECTIVES
2.1 INTRODUCTION
We began the study of economics by stressing the importance of scarcity in determining
society's choice. Economics is concerned with problem of scarcity. When there is free
exchange (no government control and other barriers), prices will allocate scarce goods and
services. Therefore, one of the major objectives of economics is to analyze the factors that
determine the prices and quantities of commodities sold. The determinants of price and
quantity sold (purchased) for analytical purpose, are usually separated into two categories:
The purpose of this chapter is to explain what demand and supply are and show how they
determine price and quantity sold in markets. Moreover, concepts such as market equilibrium,
elasticity, etc. are introduced. These concepts frequently appear almost in every economic
analysis.
43
Desire: is a wish to attain some object from which pleasure and satisfaction are derived.
Desire is basic human attributes, which induces him (her) to work or make an effort to fulfill
it.
Want:
Want: is desire for anything as a necessity to life or happiness but which is not satisfied due
to lack of resources (e.g. Income). Man desires house but if he has no money to constuct or
buy it, his desire remains unsatisfied. Here house is a necessity but remains as want due to
lack of money.
Demand is a willingness and ability of a consumer to purchase goods and services at specific
price within a set of possible prices at a given period of time.
Law of demand:
demand: This is the principle of demand, which states that, other things being
constant, price of a commodity and it quantity demanded are inversely related i.e., as price of
a commodity increases (decreases) quantity demanded for that commodity decreases
(increases), ceteris paribus.
Demand Schedule is a table which shows how much of a good individuals are willing and
able to buy at different price levels during a given period of time
(week, month etc)
44
At each price level consumers buy definite quantity of teff. As price of teff increases from
100 Birr to 300 Birr, quantity demanded for the teff decreases from 40 quintals to 10 quintals.
This demand schedule can also be depicted graphically as a demand curve for teff as follows.
Price of teff
300
250
200
150
100
0 10 15 25 35 40
Quantity of teff
Fig. 2.1. Demand curve for teff
Demand curve of a commodity is a curve, which shows the relationship between the quantity
demanded of the commodity at different price levels. In drawing the demand curve we
singled out price of a commodity as the most important factor affecting the quantity
demanded of the commodity and ignored the influences of other factors. However in addition
to own price, quantity demanded of a commodity depends on a number of other factors. A
fundamental analytical method used in economics is to hold all other influences constant &
focus on one important variable.
Economists do not say price is the only variable which influence purchases but they say that
price generally has very important effect on quantity purchased. It is to identify the influence
of price of a commodity on its quantity demanded that economists hold other variables
constant and concentrate on the relation between quantity demanded and price, that is, the
relation shown by the demand curve. In this way attention can be focused on the effect of
price. However, in using the demand curve students should be aware of the other factors,
which actually can influence quantity demanded, but which were held constant in deriving the
demand curve.
45
The demand curve shows how a change in commodity's own price will affect the quantity
demanded, but what determine the shape and the position of the curve itself?
The shape and position of the demand curve depends on the following major determinants.
That is to say, the following variables are also important determinants of quantity demanded
of a commodity. However, we treat them separately from own price of a commodity because
unlike change in own price level, change in these variables has quite different effect on the
position of the demand curve itself. All the following variables cause demand curve to change
its position and we call them shift variables of demand curve. As one of the following
determinants changes assuming other things being constant demand curve shifts either to the
right or to the left. A right ward (left ward) shift of the demand curve indicates an increase (a
decrease) in demand.
When people change their mind about taste and preference for a commodity demand for the
commodity also changes. For example if consumers have favorable (unfavorable) taste and
preference for a commodity the demand for commodity increases (decreases), other things
being constant.
Tastes and preferences of the individuals to wards the consumption of egg increases if it is
announced that consumption of egg is helpful in curing lung Cancer. For example,
advertisement on different goods and services changes tastes and preferences of consumers
and accordingly the demand for these goods and services changes.
For example, other things being constant, during rainy season demand for raincoat
increases.
The following demand curve depicts the effect of a favorable tastes and
preferences of a consumer on raincoat during rainy season.
46
An increase in Demand
A decrease in demand (a left ward shift)
Price of
Raincoat A decrease in demand ( a left ward shift)
Quantity of raincoat
Fig. 2.2. An individual demand for raincoat
Price of Price of
Substitute Complementary
good (injera) (fuel)
0 0
Quantity of Commodity (bread) Quantity of Commodity (car)
47
An increase in a number of consumers causes an increase in demand for commodities given
that consumers have ability to pay for. For example,
example, Addis Ababa with the total population of
3 million people buys commodities 3 times than the population of Nazareth with 1 million
people.
E. Expectation of Consumers
Just as current income and price affect demand for a commodity so can expected price and
income. If consumers expect their income to increase in the future, they may buy more since
they would be able to pay for this later on. If consumers expect higher (lower) prices in the
future, they may buy more (less) of the goods today. In discussing the effect of each of the
above variables on quantity demanded of a commodity we assumed other things remain
constant.
48
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
5. What is an effect of a decrease in income of the consumer on demand for inferior good
ceteris paribus? Show your answer graphically.
The demand curve is derived under the assumption of Ceteris Paribus (other things remain
constant) i.e., other determinants of demand except own price are held constant. Thus, the
demand curve shows how quantity demanded of a commodity varies when the price of the
commodity changes. In this case we observe change in quantity demanded simply because of
change in the price of a commodity, and the dd curve remained unchanged (not shifted).
Thus, if we vary only price of a commodity and hold other determinants of demand (income,
taste and preference, prices of related goods, expectation, no of consumers) constant, the
demand curve does not shift In this case as price varies we are moving along the same dd
curve and we call this movement change in quantity demanded. The following graph shows
change in quantity demanded from Q1 to Q2 or from Q2 to Q1 due to change in price of the
commodity from p1 to p2 or from p2 to p1 respectively, ceteris paribus.
Price A
P1
Fig. 2.4: Change in quantity demanded
B
(movement along the same demand)
P2
P3 C
0
Q1 Q2 Q3
Quantity
49
If the price of a commodity (own price) remains constant and one or more of those other
factors affecting demand (e.g., income, taste and preference, prices of other goods,
expectation and number of consumers) change, then the demand curve shifts from its position
either to the right or to the left.
Thus, when the demand curve changes its position we call it change in demand (shift in
demand)
Price D1 D0 D2
P0
D1 D0 D2
0 Quantity
When demand curve shifts from D0 D0 to D1 D1 (shift of demand curve to the left) we say
decrease in demand.
Increase in demand (shift from D0 D0 to D2 D2) is caused due to: increase in consumers'
income for normal goods, favorable taste and preference for a commodity, expectation of
higher price in the future, increase in the price of substitute goods, decrease in price of
complementary goods and others, ceteris paribus the reverse is also true.
Therefore, when we say increase (decrease) in demand we mean shift of the demand curve to
the right (left). When we say increase (decrease) in quantity demanded we mean downward
(upward) movement along the same demand curve.
NB. An increase (decrease) in demand also implies purchasing of more (less) of goods at
each price level. Thus, change in demand necessarily implies change in quantity
demanded, but change in quantity demanded does not necessarily imply change in
50
demand. Change in own price causes movement along the same demand curve without
causing shift of the demand curve while change in other factors affecting demand cause
shift in the demand curve.
1. Why people act according to the law of demand or in other words why price of a
commodity and its quantity demanded are inversely related or why demand curve is
downward sloping?
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
2. When teff prices rise other things being constant, an individual purchases more wheat but
fewer teff. How you explain substitution and income effects of the price change on these two
goods?
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
Market Demand Curve is the total amount of goods that all consumers are willing and able to
buy at each price level over certain time period.
Table 2.2. Demand for wheat by three individual consumers over the last five months
Price per Abebe's demand Bekele's demand Almaz's demand Total (market)
quintal for wheat for wheat for wheat demand for wheat
of wheat
(1) (2) (3) (4) 5 = 2+3+4
51
300 0 3 5 8
260 2 6 10 18
220 4 9 15 28
180 6 12 20 38
140 8 15 25 48
100 10 18 30 58
60 12 21 35 68
From this table we can see that market demand is the horizontal summation of the demand
of those three consumers, which can be shown as individuals and market demand curve as
follows.
300
260 + + =
220
180
140
100
60 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 3 6 9 12 15 18 21 8 18 28 38 48 58 68
5 10 15 20 25 30 35
Quantity of wheat
Fig. 2.6. Individual and Market Demand Curves.
52
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
Law of Supply states that other things being equal the quantity supplied of a commodity
varies directly with the price of that commodity i.e. quantity supplied increases (decreases) as
price of the commodity increases (decreases), ceteris paribus.
Supply Schedule is a table which shows how much of a good individuals are willing and able
to produce and make available for sale in the market at different price levels during a given
period of time (week, month etc)
Quantity Supplied is the amount of commodity that producer supplies to the market at a
given price level. The direct (positive) relationship between price of a commodity and
quantity supplied can be shown using either the supply schedule or the supply curve.
Supply curve of a commodity is a curve, which shows the relationship between the quantity
supplied of the commodity at different price levels. In drawing the supply curve we singled
out price of a commodity as the most important factor affecting the quantity supplied of the
commodity and ignored the influences of other factors. However in addition to own price,
53
quantity supplied of a commodity depends on a number of other factors. A fundamental
analytical method used in economics is to hold all other influences constant & focus on one
important variable.
Economists do not say price is the only variable which influence sales but they say that price
generally has very important effect on quantity sold. It is to identify the influence of price of
a commodity on its quantity supplied that economists hold other variables constant and
concentrate on the relation between quantity supplied and price, that is, the relation shown by
the supply curve. In this way attention can be focused on the effect of price. However, in
using the supply curve students should be aware of the other factors, which actually can
influence quantity supplied, but which were held constant in deriving the supply curve.
S
70
60
50
40
Price 30
20
10
0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 Quantity
Fig. 2.7 The Supply Curve
As price of a commodity increases from 10 Birr to 70 Birr then quantity supplied increases
from 100 to 700. Supply curve is derived under the assumption that other factors that can
affect quantity supplied are hold constant and only price of a commodity is allowed to vary.
Quantity supplied of a commodity and its price is positively related i.e. as price increases
quantity supply also increases.
Check Your Progress Exercise - 4
1. Now the question is why producers act according to the law of supply or in other words
why supply curve is upward sloping?
54
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
S2
S0
S1
55
Price of Commodity
A decrease in
supply
An increase in
supply
Quantity of a commodity
Fig, 2.8 Shift of supply curve
E. Number of Producers
As number of firms producing a good increases more and more goods will be supplied.
56
Quantity of goods kept in store is not considered as a supply. Goods are considered as a
supply only when they are brought to the market.
G. Market Organization
If a market for certain commodity is monopolized (i.e., there is only a single producer) then a
producer charges higher price by producing few outputs, because, the producer faces no
competition. If a market for certain commodity is characterized by a perfect competition
(many producers and sellers), then producers produce more outputs, because, there is no
possibility of increasing price to increase revenue
H. Weather
For some products, especially agricultural products weather affects the quantity to be
supplied. Favorable (unfavorable) weather increases (decreases) supply of agricultural
outputs.
Price P3 S
Fig. 2.9 Change in quantity supplied
P2 B (movement along the same supply
P1 A
curve)
Quantity
0 Q1 Q 2 Q3
As price increases from P1 to P2, quantity supplied also increases from Q1 to Q2, i.e., we call
this increase in quantity supplied and as price decreases from p 3 to p2 quantity supplied also
decreases from Q3 to Q2.
57
Change in supply refers to the shift of the supply curve. If we fix price of a commodity (own
price) constant and vary any of those other factors affecting supply (e.g. Prices of production
substitute and inputs, technological state, tax and subsidy, no of producers, producers'
expectation and weather) then the supply curve changes its position, i.e., the supply curve
shifts.
S1 S0 S2
Price decrease in supply
Increase in supply
Po
0
Q 1 Q0 Q2
Quantity
Fig. 2.10 Change in Supply (Shift in the supply curve)
If the supply curve shifts from S oSo to S2S2 (shift of the curve to the right), we call it increase
in supply. If the supply curve shifts from S oSo to S1S1 (shift of the curve to the left), we call it
a decrease in supply.
Increase in supply, i.e., shift of the supply curve to the right is caused by the following
factors: decrease in price of production substitute, decrease in prices of inputs, improvement
in technology, increase in subsidy, decrease in tax, increase in number of producers,
expectation of lower price in the future, good weather and others, ceteris paribus.
The supply curve shifts to the left (decrease in supply) when the above factors change in
opposite direction.
NB. As supply curve shifts, quantity supplied also changes therefore change in supply
necessarily implies change in quantity supplied. However, change in quantity supplied
does not necessarily imply change in supply, because change in quantity supplied can be
observed by moving along the same supply curve (without shift in supply curve).
58
2.3.4 Individual and Market Supply Curve
Individual Supply Curve shows us the quantity that a single producer is willing and able to
supply at each price level over certain period of time.
Table 2.4. A hypothetical supply schedule for the production of wheat by three individual
producers over the last seven months
Price of wheat Kebede's supply of Balcha's supply of Birke's supply of Market supply
(Birr) wheat (k.g) wheat (k.g) wheat (k.g) of wheat (k.g)
(1) (2) (3) (4) [5 = 2 + 3 + 4]
300 7 26 35 68
260 6 22 30 58
220 5 18 25 48
180 4 14 20 38
140 3 10 15 28
100 2 6 10 18
60 1 2 5 8
These supply schedules can be transferred into the supply curves as follows:
A supply curve of individuals (Kebede, Balcha and Birke)
59
300
260
220
Price 180 + +
140
100
60
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 2 10 14 18 22 26 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
Quantity
Fig 2.11 Individuals Supply Curves
S
300
260
Price 220
180
140
100
60
y
0 8 18 28 38 48 58 68
Quantity
Fig. 2.12. Market Supply Curve
60
When price of wheat is300 per quintal, quantity supplied of individual kebede, Balcha and
Birke is 7, 26 and 35 quintals respectively.
Market Supply Curve shows the total amount of particular commodity supplied by all
producers at each price level, i.e., market supply curve is the horizontal summation of
individuals. Supplies at each price level. For example, the market supply curve for the three
individual producers of wheat cited above is shown by the following graph.
1. Large number of buyers and sellers (so that the influence of individuals seller or buyer is
insignificant.
2. Firms produce a homogeneous product (so that an attempt to increase price by the producer
brings loss of market share)
3. Perfect information (knowledge) of the market (so that each market participant can act
according to the market operation)
5.Free entry and exist of firm (no business license, no patent right, etc)
61
Under these assumptions (conditions) no individual buyer or seller has control over the price
of a commodity. Both consumers and producers are price takers not makers, i.e., price is
determined by the market (by forces of supply and demand)
At that equilibrium, price and quantity remain unchanged as long as we have the assumption
of other things being equal, i.e., until something operates to change supply or demand. If
some changes occur to shift either the supply curve or the demand curve, then the market
equilibrium point also changes.
In order to understand the market equilibrium let us consider our market demand schedule
and supply schedule of wheat we showed in the table 2.2 and table 2.4 respectively.
From our demand and supply analyses, we know that consumers tend to buy more of the
goods as price falls while producers tend to sell more as price increases. Thus, consumers
need price to fall while producers need price to (rise).
Now the question is, what determines the price level on which both consumers and
producers agree on, i.e., the equilibrium?
The operation of the forces of supply and demand provides answer to this question. At any
price level above the equilibrium price (like point G and others in figure 2.12) quantity
supplied is greater than quantity demanded. At that price level producers plan to supply more
and more of the goods in order to get more profit. However, consumers plan to buy less and
less as goods are too costly to them. Therefore, there will be an excess supply (surplus). In
62
order to get rid of this excess supply there will be completion among producers to decrease
price. This decrease in price encourages consumers to demand more and more of the goods.
Thus, producers continue to decrease their prices and consumers continue to buy more until
the excess supply is eliminated or until the equilibrium point is reached at point E. At any
price below the equilibrium price level (such as point F and others in figure 2.12) quantity
demanded is greater than quantity supplied. At that price level producers plan to supply less
and less of the goods. However, consumers plan to buy more and more as they feel goods are
relatively cheap. Thus, there is an excess demand (shortage of goods) and this creates
competition among consumers to get these scarce goods by increasing price. This increase in
price encourages producers to supply more and more. Thus, consumers continue to bid up
price and producers continue to supply more and more until the excess demand is eliminated
or the equilibrium price is reached again at point E. Graphically the market equilibrium (i.e.,
equilibrium price which is 180 birr and equilibrium quantity which is 38 quintals) can b
shown as follows:
Excess supply or
shortage of demand
Price
G Fig. 2.13 Market equilibrium
180 E
Excess demand
F or
shortage of supply
D
Quantity
38
At point E supply and demand curve intersect each other and therefore quantity supplied is
equal to quantity demanded hence market equilibrium is attained at point E.
2.4.2 Effects of Change in Demand or Supply on the Market Equilibrium
63
D0 D1 S
Price
P1 e1
P0 e
S
D0 D1
Quantity
Q1 Q0
Fig. 2.14 Effects of an increase in Demand when Supply Remains Unchanged
An increase in demand (shift of the demand curve from D0 D0 to D1D1) supply being
unchanged causes equilibrium point to change from e to e1. In this case the new equilibrium
point (point e1) is attained both at a higher price and quantity than the initial equilibrium
(point e).
A decrease in demand (shift of the demand curve from D1D1 to D0D0) and supply remains
constant causes attainment of the equilibrium at a lower point. i.e., equilibrium point decrease
from point e1 to e and therefore equilibrium quantity decreases from Q 1 to !0 and equilibrium
price decreases from P1 to P0.
D0 S0 S1
Price
P0 e
P1 e1
S0
S1 D0
0 Q0 Q1 Quantity
Fig. 2.15 Effects of an increase in supply when demand remains unchanged
64
An increase in supply (shift of supply curve from S 0S0 to S1 S1) assuming demand not to
change causes equilibrium point to change from point e to e 1. As a result equilibrium price
decreases from P0 to P1 and equilibrium quantity sold or bought increases from Q 0 to Q1, i.e.,
the new equilibrium is attained at a lower price but higher quantity than before.
Decrease in supply (shift of the curve from S1 S1 to S0S0) assuming demand being unchanged
causes equilibrium point to change from e1 to e. That is to say the new equilibrium point e is
attained at higher price but lower quantity level than before.
D0 S0 S1
Price
P0 e
P1 e1
S0
S1 D0
Q0 Q1 Quantity
Fig. 2.16 Effects of a decrease in supply when demand remains unchanged
Effect of simultaneous change in demand and supply on equilibrium price and quantity. If
both demand and supply increase simultaneously, then the equilibrium quantity increases but
equilibrium price may increase, decrease or remain unchanged depending on the relative
magnitude of the percentage change in demand and supply. There are three cases.
(1) If demand increases by more proportion than the supply, the new equilibrium (e 1) is
attained at both higher equilibrium price and quantity than before. Thus, the new
equilibrium quantity (Q1) is greater than the previous equilibrium quantity (Q 0) and the
new equilibrium price (P1) is also greater than the previous equilibrium price (P0).
65
D1 S 0 S1
D0
Price P1 e1
P0 eo D1
S0
S1 Do
Q0 Q1 Quantity
Fig. 2.17 Effects of increase in demand by more proportion than supply increase.
(2) If supply increases by more proportion than demand, then the new equilibrium (e 1) is
attained at a higher equilibrium quantity (Q 1) than previous quantity (Q0) but at a lower
equilibrium price (P1) than the previous price (P0).
S0
D 0 D1
S1
Price P0 e0
P1 S0 e1
S1 D0 D1 Quantity
Q0 Q1
Fig. 2.18 Effects of increase in supply by more proportion than demand increase.
3) If both demand and supply increases by an equal proportion the new equilibrium quantity
is attained at a higher level then the initial equilibrium quantity. But equilibrium price
remains unchanged.
66
Price D0 D1 S0 S1
P0 e0 E1
S0
S1 D0 D1
Q0 Q1 Quantity
So far we discussed the relationship between price and quantity demanded in terms of
demand schedule and demand curve. As well, we have seen the relationship between price of
a commodity and quantity supplied in terms of supply schedule and supply curve. Our
demand and supply curves helped us in explaining basic concepts in demand and supply
analysis such as market equilibrium, change in demand, change in quantity demand, change
in supply, change in quantity supply, etc.
The supply schedule (curve) or demand schedule (curve) can also be represented by supply
equation or demand equation respectively and can be used to explain those basic demand and
supply concepts we mentioned above.
E.g. if the demand and supply curve equation of a commodity are given by:
Qd = 250 - 50P
and
Qs = 25 + 25P, respectively, where Qd, Qs and P are quantity
demanded, quantity supplied and price respectively. The equilibrium price and quantity will
be: Qd = Qs at market equilibrium, so
250 - 50P = 25 + 25P
250 - 25 = 25P + 50P
225 = 75P
P=3
Qd = 250 - 50(3) = 100 = Qs
Thus, equilibrium price and quantity is 3 and 100 units respectively.
67
Check Your Progress Exercise - 5
2. Given:
If the Demand and supply equations of a commodity are:
Qd = 30 - 5P (demand equation)
and
Qs = 25P (supply equation), respectively, where Qd, Qs and P arequantity demanded,
quantity supplied and price respectively.
Based on the above demand and supply equations, what will be:
a) equilibrium price ?
b) equilibrium quantity ?
2.5 ELASTICITIES
Business -people who use economics in decision making is interested in knowing the
responsiveness of the dependent variable (say quantity demanded) to the change in any one of
the independent variable (say price).
In economics, the following elasticities are quite important for the decision making of both
consumers and producers.
Elasticity of demand
Elasticity of supply
68
Price elasticity of demand
Income elasticity of demand
Cross-price elasticity of demand
69
Point Price Quantity
Demanded
A 15 20
B 10 30
C 5 40
From this example we can calculate 'point" price elasticity of demand in two ways:
2. Considering the same points but movement in opposite direction, i.e., from B to A we get:
Ep = Q2 - Q1 x P1 = 20 - 30 x 10 = / -0.67/ = 0.67
P2 - P1 Q1 15-10 30
In the first case we used point A as the base for computation of e p whereas in the second case
we used point B as the base of computation of e p. In both cases the price elasticity of demand
we calculated is point price elasticity. Thus, one of the problems of using point price
elasticity is that it yields two different values of elasticity depending on the direction of our
movement (point which we select as a base of our computation). In order to avoid this
discrepancy in value of elasticity it is better to use "arc" or" average" elasticity which takes
the average price and average quantity as a base for computation.
70
The Five Categories of Price Elasticity of Demand
Depending on its magnitude, elasticity of demand can be categorized as follows:
2. Inelastic Demand:
Demand: in this case percentage change in quantity demanded is less than
percentage change in price. eg . a change of price by 10%, which caused quantity,
demanded to change only by 5%. Here the value of demand elasticity lies between 0 and
1, i.e. 0 < ep < 1. Graphically it can be shown as follows.
D
P P1 0 < ep < 1
P2
D Q
Q1 Q2
Fig. 2.21 Inelastic Demand curve
3. Elastic Demand:
Demand: When percentage change in quantity demand is greater than
percentage change in price, it is said to be elastic demand. eg change in quantity demand
by 10% which was caused by 5% change in price.
71
P D
P1 ep > 1
P2
D
Q
Q1 Q2
Fig. 2.22 Elastic Demand
P D
P1 ep = 1
P2
D
Q
Q1 Q
Fig. 2.23 Unit Price Elastic demand curve
P
P0 D ep =
72
Q1 Q2 Quantity
Fig. 2.24 Perfectly Elastic demand:
demand:
Price 4 D
ep > 1
3 B
2 M ep = 1
1 E ep < 1
1
D
o 1 2 3 4 Quantity
Fig.2.25 Elasticity of demand and price elasticity of demand
Point m is the mid point of straight-line demand curve DD 1 (i.e. DM = MD1). Above the mid
point M to the left of M demand is elastic (i.e., ep > 1). At the mid point demand is unitary
elastic with ep = 1. Below the mid point to the left of M demand is in elastic with e p<1.
73
c) The nature of a commodity (i.e. whether it is luxury or necessity)
If a commodity is a necessity-good, then its, ep is low (inelastic demand) because
whatever price level is, consumers buy almost fixed quantity of this good. If a commodity
is non-essential or luxury then it has high price elasticity, because for this commodity a
consumer has an alternative to postpone consumption if price increases, as it is not so
essential for daily activity.
ey = (Qd/Qd) x 100
(y/y)x 100
Where ey is income elasticity of demand
Qd is changed in quantity demand
Y is change in income of consumers.
i.e. ey = [(Q2 - Q1)/Q1)] x 100
[(Y2 - Y1)/Y1] x 100
ey =
If income elasticity of demand for certain good is positive, then the good is said to be normal
good.
If income elasticity of a commodity is negative, then the good is said to be inferior good.
74
exy = (Qdx) / Qdx = Qdx , Py
py/py py Qx
Where Qdx is changed in quantity demand of x.
py is changed in price of commodity y
Qxd is quantity demanded of x at particular price
If goods are related in consumption they are either a substitute or a complementary to each
other. Cross price elasticity can be positive, negative or zero. For a substitute goods cross
price elasticity is positive. For complementary goods cross price elasticity is negative. If
goods have no relation their cross price elasticity of demand is zero.
Cross - elasticity of demand for commodity X i.e. exy as we move from A to B is given by
exy = -
75
Price elasticity of supply measures percentage change in quantity supplied due to certain
percentage change in the price of a commodity.
es = - = x - Point elasticity it
supply
Q Quantity
Fig 2.26 perfectly inelastic supply curve
P es =
P0 S
Q1 Q2 Q
Fig2.27 perfectly elastic supply curve
76
P S
0 < es < 1
S
Q
Fig 2.28 inelastic supply curve
S
P es = 1
0 Q
Fig 2.29 unitary elastic supply curve
If demand for the product is elastic, an increase in price results decrease in revenue as small
percentage change in price causes large decrease in quantity sold.
If a producer faces an inelastic demand curve for his product he can increase his revenue by
increasing price because under this case large percentage increase in price causes little
77
percentage decrease in quantity demanded. If a producer faces inelastic demand curve, then it
cannot increase its revenue by decreasing price.
If demand is unitary, change in price does not affect total revenue. In this case there is no
need of decreasing or increasing price, as it does not affect total revenue of the producer.
78
2.7 ANSWERS TO CHECK YOUR PROGRESS EXERCISES
3. Substitutes --Two
--Two or goods are considered substitutes if they satisfy the same needs or
desires separately like, Pepsi cola and coca cola, Pork and Beef and coffee and tea etc.
4. Complements -- Two or more goods are complements, if they are used or consumed jointly
to satisfy the needs of the consumer like, Sugar and tea, car and petrol, etc.
1.a. As price of a commodity increases consumers cut down consumption of that good and
substitute other commodity whose price was not rose this is substitution effect.
b. As price of a commodity increases real income of consumer decreases and so quantity to
be purchased decreases. This is income effect.
c. Law of diminishing marginal utility also theoretically explains this inverse relationship,
i.e. as a consumer consumes more of the same good, the additional satisfaction
(marginal utility) keeps on decreasing and consumer is eager to pay less and less for each
successive unit he consumes.
79
on dependent variable, we must keep other factors unchanged and vary just one factor at a
time.
b. Profit motives. In real world firms are willing to supply more as price increases
because, other things being constant, increase in price of output implies increase in
profit of the firm, which induces it to, supply more and more of output.
Ep = x = = =
Thus arc price elasticity of demand is equal to 3/5, which is interpreted as follows.
80
As price increases (decreases) by 5 percent, then quantity demanded decreases (increases) by
3 percent.
2. When percentage change in quantity demanded is greater than percentage change in price
then, _______________________.
a) consumers are relatively sensitive to price changes
b) demand is inelastic
c) coefficient of price elasticity is less than one
d) all of the above
e) none of the above
3. Given the following demand and supply equations: what will be the equilibrium price and
quantity?
-1/2Qd + 10 = 3/ 2p
1/2Qs-15/2 = 1/ 2p
81
b) increase in quantity supplied
c) decrease in quantity supplied
d) increase in quantity demanded
e) increase in demand
9. As price of commodity Y increases, demand curve for commodity X shifts to the left,
then X and Y are
82
a) substitute goods
b) unrelated goods
c) complementary goods
d) either substitute or complementary goods
e) neither complementary nor substitute goods
10. The elasticity of demand for a good is 0.8 with respect to price. Therefore, one expects
that a 1% increase in price would _________
a) increase quantity demanded by 0.8%
b) increase quantity demanded by 0.16%
c) decrease quantity demanded by 0.8%
d) decrease quantity demanded by 0.16%
e) none of the above
II. Write "True" if the statement is true, and "False" if the statement is false.
____________ 1. The coefficient of price elasticity of supply of a commodity is always
negative.
____________ 2. A decrease in input prices causes a left ward shift in the supply curve.
____________ 3. The income-effect on demand for an inferior good is negative (inverse).
____________ 4. If a consumer expects price to increase in the future, other things being
constant, he or she purchases more units of normal goods currently
_____________5. Every straight supply line passing through the origin has unitary elasticity.
_____________6. Substitute goods are those that are competing for the same demand.
_____________7. The coefficient of cross- price elasticity of demand for unrelated goods
is negative.
_____________8. As price of a commodity increases its demand Curve shifts to the left,
ceteris paribus.
____________ 9. Equilibrium price and quantity increase if both demand and supply
increase.
____________10.
____________10. Expectation of the producer in price changes affects demand for a
commodity, ceteris paribus.
83
III. Give brief definition or explanation for the following concepts in the space
provided
2) State factors that affect quantity demanded and quantity supplied and explain how
they affect the position of the demand curve or supply curve.
3) Why the supply curve is up - ward sloped (ie why price of a commodity and its
quantity supplied are positively related)?
4) What is market equilibrium? How it is arrived at? Under a perfect competitive market
assuming other things being constant, explain why any deviation from the equilibrium is a
self - adjusting, i.e., it finally returns to the initial equilibrium level?
5) Define price elasticity of demand. How it is computed, what are its determinant and
what is its use in business world?
84
12
B 150 120 6 19
C 200 80 23
8) Use supply and demand curve to show the effect of increase in consumer income on
market equilibrium? Compare the resulted equilibrium quantity and price with the
original quantity and price.
9) Suppose the demand and supply functions for Coca are given by
Qd = 200 - 30p and
Qs = 20p, respectively.
a. Find the equilibrium quantity of coca demanded?
b. Find equilibrium price of Coca
c. Do you have excess demand or excess supply when price of Coca is 20 Birr?
When price of Coca is 50 Birr?
10) Suppose unseasonable flood attacked wheat production of maize in the upper Awash
Valley, assuming other things being constant. What effect will this have on:
a. the market supply curve for maize?
b. The market demand curve for maize?
c. The market equilibrium of maize?
11) Assuming other things being constant an increase (decrease) in supply will lower (raise)
price, why? How?
12) Draw a hypothetical demand and supply curve, which shows market equilibrium. Then
illustrate how the following variables affect your initial equilibrium point.
85
b. improvement in technology
c. decrease in the price of a substitute goods
d. increase in price of complementary goods.
2.9 REFERENCES
1. Samuelson, P. and W.D. Nordhaus (1989) 13th ed. Economics,
Economics,
New York; Mcgraw - Hill Company.
Contents
3.0 Aims and Objectives
3.1 Introduction
3.2 Consumer Choice and the Concept of Utility
3.2.1 Cardinal Utility
3.2.1.1 Total and Marginal Utility
3.2.1.2 Consumer’s Equilibrium
86
3.2.2 The Budget Line
3.2.2.1 Shift and Rotation of the Budget Line
3.2.3 Ordinal Utility
3.2.3.1 The Indifference Curve
3.2.3.2 Marginal Rate of Substitution
3.2.3.3 Consumer’s Equilibrium Using Ordinal Approach
3.3 Key Terms
3.4 Answers to Check Your Progress Exercises
3.5 Model Examination Questions
3.6 References
3.1 INTRODUCTION
In this chapter we develop a framework to analyze question such as: what is the relationship
between the price we pay for a good and the overall benefit, worth of the good to us? Do low-
priced goods cost less because they are not worth much to us?
This analysis of individual consumer decisions provides the underpinnings for our earlier
general analysis of demand in chapter 2, because when we put all the individual purchase
decisions of consumers together, we get the market demand curve for a good. This chapter
87
discusses utility, the budget constraints, and impacts on consumer behavior of income and
price changes.
The law of demand may be treated as a common sense notion. A high price usually does
discourage consumers from buying; a low price typically does encourage them to buy. The
purpose of the theory of consumer behavior is to determine the various factors that affect
demand.
The theory of consumer behavior examines and verifies the postulate of preference and
consistency of choice. Consuming certain goods and services, a consumer derives some
benefits or satisfaction from the activity. Economists have called this benefit or satisfaction
utility, and have assumed that, in choosing among goods, the consumer will attempt to gain
the greatest possible utility, subject to his/her budget constraints. Utility is thus the
satisfaction obtained from consuming good or service. In short, utility is a want satisfying
power of a product to satisfy human needs. The two approaches to consumer's behavior
analysis:
Example: a consumer may obtain 10 utils, of utility from a consumption of good A, but only
5 utils from the consumption of good B. The cardinalists would conclude from this that the
consumer obtains twice as much utility from A as from B, and the absolute difference
between the utility derived from A and that obtained from B is 10 utils.
However, utility is an abstract, subjective concept and there are two major problems involved
in trying to measure it: It is difficult to find an appropriate unit of measurement. If we call the
88
unit a util, what is a util? Are 5 utils enjoyed by one individual equivalent to 5 utils enjoyed
by another? Stated differently, can we make interpersonal comparison of utility?
The total utility is the total satisfaction obtained from the consumption of a good or bundle of
goods in a given time period.
The total utility (U) of the consumer depends on the quantities of the commodities consumed:
The marginal (or incremental) utility is the satisfaction added by the consumption of the last
unit or in other words, it is the change in total utility caused by changing consumption of a
good by on unit, holding consumption of all other goods fixed. Geometrically, the marginal
utility of X is the slope of the total utility curve.
Mux = ΔTu/Δx
The following table shows the relationship between total and marginal utility of a particular
commodity.
89
6 165 15
7 175 10
8 180 5
9 180 0
10 175 -5
Saturation point
Tu
Tu
90
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Quantity of a commodity
Mu
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Quantity
Fig 3.1. Graphical representation of total and marginal utility of the commodity
The total utility increases, but at decreasing rate, up to quantity 9, reaches its maximum and
then starts to decline there after. Accordingly the marginal utility of X declines continuously
and becomes zero when total utility reaches maximum or saturation point and then negative
beyond quantity 9.
As indicated in fig3.2 below, If the marginal utility is measured in monetary units, the
demand curve for X is identical to the positive segment of the marginal utility curve. At
quantity X1 the marginal utility is MU1, and this is equal to P1, by definition. Hence at P1 the
consumer demands X1 quantity of commodity X. Similarly at X2 the marginal utility is MU2,
which is equal to P2. Hence at P2 the consumers will buy X2 units of X, and so on. The
91
negative section of the MU curve does not form part of the demand curve, since negative
quantities do not make sense in economics.
The fact that marginal utility will decline as the consumer acquires additional units of a
specific product is known as the law of diminishing marginal utility.
demand curve
MU2 -------------------------------------------------------------- P2 ---------------
0 1 2 3 4
D 0 1 2 3
Quantity MU
Quantity
Fig. 3.2 Derivation of demand curve from marginal utility curve
3.2.1.2 Consumer's Equilibrium
A consumer is said to have reached his/her equilibrium position when he/she has maximized
the level of his/her satisfaction, given budget constraints and other conditions. At equilibrium,
the consumer is supposed to have spent his/her entire income on the goods and services
he/she consumes. If we assume that the consumer consumes only two products, say, X and Y,
then the following condition should fulfill in equilibrium:
= or =
92
The utility derived from spending an additional unit of money must be the same for all
commodities. If the consumer derives greater utility from any one commodity, he can
increase his welfare by spending more on that commodity and less on the others, until the
above equilibrium condition is fulfilled.
2 50 30 14
3 40 18 10
4 30 12 8
Given:
1) The price of commodity A(PA) = birr 5, commodity B(PB) = birr 3, and commodity
C(PC) = birr 1.
2) The total income of the consumer is birr 19, Now, would the consumer purchase the first
unit of A, B or C? The answer is the consumer would purchase the first unit of commodity
C. Why? Because, the highest level of marginal utility per birr is obtained from the first
unit of C That is:
Commodity A will have 60/5 = birr 12
Commodity B will have 36/3 = birr 12
Commodity C will have 16/ 1= birr 16
Now that consumer is left with birr 18. Which unit of commodity will he buy next? Again by
the same logic, he will purchase the 2nd unit of C. This time is having 17 birr.
The consumer's next choice will be either the first unit of A or B since both have the same
level of utility per birr, which is greater than that from the 3 rd unit of C. Assuming that his 3 rd
purchase is commodity x, the first unit of commodity B will then be his 4 th purchase (choice).
Now he is left with 9 birr, after he purchases 2 units of commodity C and one unit each from
93
A and B. Next, the consumer can purchase either the 2 nd unit of A or the 2 nd unit of B or the
3rd unit of C. Let us say the consumers fifth, sixth and seventh choices are the 2 nd unit of
commodity A, the 3rd unit of B and the 3rd unit of C, respectively. At this level of purchase
(i.e. 2 units of A, 2 units of B and 3 units of C), the consumer has exhausted all his income
and is in a position to purchase nothing.
Note here that the last units of expenditure spent on each commodity consumed bring about
the same level of utility. When this condition is satisfied no shifting of expenditure between
goods can serve to increase total utility, and hence consumer equilibrium is said to exist. As
we can clearly see from and example, the last birr spent on A, B and C yields the same
amount of utility, that is:
If the condition is not satisfied, then with the same fixed income, total utility can be increased
by altering the pattern of expenditure. In short, we may conclude that, as long as the objective
of the consumer is to maximize total utility, expenditure switching between goods will take
place until the marginal utility of a Birr's worth of each good consumed is equal to the
marginal utility of Birr's worth of any other goods consumed.
1 16 35
2 30 56
3 42 76
94
4 48 91
5 52 101
In order to draw the budget line facing the consumer, let us assume that there are only two
goods, X and Y, bought in quantities X and Y. Each consumer is confronted with market
determined prices, Px and Py, of X and Y respectively. Finally, the consumer in question has a
known and fixed money income (M). M is the maximum amount the consumer can spend,
and we assume that it is all spent on X and Y. The amount spent on X (i.e. X.P x) plus the
amount spent on Y (i.e. Y.Py) is equal to the stipulated money income Algebraically.
M = XPx + YPy
The equation can be expressed as the equation for a straight line. Solving for the quantity Y
(since Y is generally plotted on the vertical axis), we have:
Y= - X
95
Assigning successive values to X (given the income M and the commodity prices, P x and Py)
we may find the corresponding values of Y. Thus, if x = 0 (i.e., if the consumer spends all
his/her money (income) on Y) the consumer can buy units of Y. Similarly if Y = 0 (i.e., if
the consumer spends all his/her income on X) the consumer can buy units of X. If we join
Y
A
Y= - X
0 B X
(-) In the above equation, - (the negative of the price - ratio), is the slope of the budget
Slope = = =
The negative sign in the price ratio indicates that the budget line slopes downward
96
our case, X and Y), which the consumer can purchase, must increase. And since the increase
in money income allows the consumer to buy more goods (of X and Y) the budget line is
pushed out ward (shifts outward). Since prices are not changed, the slope of the budget line
does not change. Therefore, an increase in money income (prices of commodities remaining
constant) caused an outward parallel shift in the budget line, as indicated below.
Where >M
X
Similarly, a decrease in money income, the price ratio held constant, causes a parallel inward
Fig.3.4 Rightward Shift of the budget line
shift in the budget line.
C Where <M
0 DB
X
What happens to the budget line when price ratio changes with money income held constant?
Hold money income (M) and the price of Y(Py) constant, then let the price of X(Px) increases.
97
Since Px increases, increases also. The budget line becomes stepper, in this case the line
AB!
A
Here Px > Px, hence M/Px >
0 B' B
M/ Px X
Fig. 3.6 Rotation of budget line
Since the Y-intercept (M/Py) is constant, the consumer can purchase the same amount of Y by
spending the entire money income on Y regardless of the price of X. We can see from above
figure that an increase in the price of X rotates the budget line back ward, the Y - intercept
remaining fixed. Similarly, in decrease in the price of X, money income and price of Y held
constant, pivots the budget line out-ward in the above fig. from AB' to AB.
Y
Y A
(0, 36)
B
0 X
(54.
0)
98
Fig. 3.7 Budget line
…………………………………………………………………………………………………
…………………………………………………………………………………………………
…………………………………………………………………………………………………
2. Assume a consumer consumes only two products (X, Y); show graphically effect of
decrease in price of commodity Y on budget line, ceteris paribus. Use vertical axis for
commodity Y and horizontal axis for commodity X.
…………………………………………………………………………………………………
…………………………………………………………………………………………………
…………………………………………………………………………………………………
99
1) The consumer is assumed to be rational: the consumer aims at the maximization of his
utility, given his/her income and market prices.
2) The consumer can rank his/her preferences according to the satisfaction of each basket
of goods. He/She need know precisely the amount of satisfaction derived from the
consumption of the commodities. The ranking of goods according to his/her
preference is all that is needed.
3) Diminishing marginal rate of substitution: the slope of the indifference curve, which
depicts the rate at which the consumer is willing to substitute one good for another,
declines. The indifference curve analysis is, thus, based on the axiom of diminishing
marginal rate of substitution.
4) The total utility (U) of the consumer depends on the quantities of the commodities
consumed: U = f (q1, q2, ... qn)
7) The non- satiety assumption. This assumption implies that the consumer always
prefers the bundle with at least one more commodity in it.
Example:
Example: The first bundle consists of 8 units of X and 6 units of Y while the second
bundle consists 10 units of X and 6 of Y. According to the above assumption, the
consumer prefers the second bundle to the first one.
100
An indifference curve shows all combinations of two products, which will yield the same
level of total utility to the consumer. The consumer is therefore indifferent (equally happy)
among the bundles (combinations) represented by the points on the curve.
In order to draw the indifference curves, which depict the consumer's preferences, let us
assume there are only two goods, say X and Y, available for consumption. We assume this
assumption to simplify the analysis. The vertical axis in fig below measures the quantity of
good Y and the horizontal axis measures the quantity of goods X. Thus, every point on the
graph represents some combination of X and Y.
25 A
17 B
11 C
7 D
5 E
IC
0 2 4 6 8 10 X
Fig. 3.8 Indifference curve
101
other (x) must increase, if the consumer is to stay on the same level of satisfaction. In
moving from A to B, in above fig.as 8 units of Y are given up, to two more units of X are
obtained and the utility derived is unchanged. For this to be true, the indifference curve
must slope downwards from left to right.
3) The further away from the origin an indifference curve lies, the higher the
level of utility it denotes. Bundle of goods on a higher indifference curve are preferred by
the rational consumer. This property holds true, only assuming non-satiety assumption.
4) Indifference curves do not intersect each other. If they did, the point of
intersection would imply consumer would obtain two different levels of satisfaction
consuming one combination of the two goods at the same time, which is impossible. To
show this, consider below fig., which shows two intersecting indifference curves.
Y
I2
Y2 I1
Y1
0 X1 X
Fig. 3.9 Indifference curves
Since both combinations A and C are on the same indifference curve, the consumer must be
indifferent between them. Combinations B and C, however, are also on the same indifference
curve, so the consumer must be indifferent between them as well. If the consumer is
indifferent between A and C, and between B and C, he/she must (by the rule of transitivity)
be indifferent between A and B. This however, is absurd because A contains more Y and the
same amount of X and B and so must be preferred to it. We conclude, therefore, that
indifference curves can never intersect each other.
102
4) The indifference curves are convex to the origin. This implies that the slope of an
indifference curve decreases (in absolute terms) as we move along the curve from left
down - wards to the right. The curve is convex to the origin due to imperfect substitution
of the goods in question. In other words, as more and more units of one good, say Y, are
given up, successively bigger quantities of X must be obtained to compensate the
consumer for the loss and leave him/her at the same level of utility.
The further away any indifference curve is from the origin, the higher is the level of
satisfaction given by any of the combinations of goods indicated by points on the curve.
I4
I3
I2
I1
0 X
Fig. 3.2 Indifference map
2.What are the four properties of indifference curve? Explain them briefly.
103
…………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………..
…………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………..
…………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………..
Consider the below fig. An indifference curve is represented by I where the consumer is
indifferent between bundle R, containing 2 units of X and 14 units of Y, and bundle P,
containing 7 of units of X and 4 of Y.
Y
R
14
N
4 S P
I
0 2 7 X
Fig 3.3 Marginal rate of substitution
At point P, the consumer is willing to give up 5 units of X for 10 more units of Y. At point R,
the consumer is willing to give up 10 units of Y for 5 more units of X. The rate at which the
consumer is willing, on average, to substitute X and Y is therefore:
MRS = = = = =2
104
The ratio measures the average number of units of Y the consumer is willing to forego
(sacrifice) in order to obtain one additional unit of X (over the range of consumption pairs
under consideration, i.e. over the range of RP). The consumer is willing to give up 2 units of
Y in order to gain one more unit of X, stated alternatively, the ratio measures the amount of Y
that must be given up (2 units) per unit of X gained to remain at precisely the same level of
satisfaction. We define this rate of substitution as: -
Y' I3
I2
I1
0 X' X
The indifference map describes the preference of the consumer (what he/she wishes) while
the budget line specifies the different combinations of x and y the consumer can purchase
with the limited income (M).
The consumer cannot purchase any bundle lying above and to the right of the budget line and,
therefore, cannot consume any combination lying on indifference curves is. However, some
105
points on indifference curves I1, I2 and I3 are attainable. The question then arises as to which
combinations of X and Y the rational consumer will purchase.
If a consumer were situated at a point such as C, experimentation would lead him to substitute
Y for X, there by moving the consumer in the direction of E. The consumer would not stop
short of E, because each successive substitution of Y for X brings him/her to a higher
indifference curve. Therefore, the position of maximum satisfaction or the point of consumer
optimization is attained at E, where an indifference curve is just tangent to the budget line.
It will be recalled that the slope of the budget line is the negative of the price ratio, the ratio
of the price of X to the price of Y. It is also stated earlier that the slope of an indifference
curve at any point is called MRS of X for Y. Therefore, the point of consumer equilibrium is
defined by the condition that the marginal rate of substitution of X for Y must equal the price
ratio.
The MRS shows the rate at which the consumer is willing to substitute X for Y. The price
ratio shows the rate at which market prices permit substitution of X for Y. Unless these rates
are equal, it is possible to change the combination of X and Y purchased to attain a higher
level of satisfaction.
Example: Suppose the MRS is two - meaning the consumer is willing to give up two units of
Y in order to obtain one unit of X. Let the price ratio be unity, meaning that one unit of Y can
be exchanged for one unit of X. Clearly, the consumer will benefit by trading Y for X. This is
because, he or she is willing to give up two Y for one X but only has to give up one Y for one
X in the market. In general, unless the MRS and the price ratio are equal, some exchange can
be made to move the consumer to a higher level of satisfaction. Therefore,
MRSx for y =
MRSx for y =
106
………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………
2. What is consumer's equilibrium?
………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………
b) At X intercept, 216 = 54 X Px + 0 X 6
216 =54P x; Px= 216/54 = 4
Price of commodity X is 4 Birr.
2. Draw the graph yourself and come pore. It with the text
107
1. Indifference curve is a curve that shows different combinations of the two goods that give
the same utility to the consumer. It is also called iso utility curve. That is, so means equal,
utility means satisfaction, then equal satisfaction curve.
1. Marginal rate of substitution is the rate at which consumer substitutes one commodity
for another commodity so as to obtain the same utility.
2. As we move downward along the same indifference curve (where X is on the horizontal
axis and Y is on the vertical axis), ______.
a) total utility decreases
b) marginal utility of commodity Y decreases
c) marginal utility of commodity X increases
d) consumers gradually want to consume more of commodity X because its marginal
utility increases.
e) none of the above
108
b) total utility is constant
c) quantity consumed of X varies
d) marginal rate of substitution varies
e) all except a
6. In the above equation of question No. 5 if the Y - intercept of the budget line equation
increased to 15 at constant income it,
a) is due to increase in price of X
b) is due to decrease in price of Y
c) implies rotation of budget line to the left
d) implies shift of budget line to the left
e) all except d
7. The objective of a rational consumer is to _________.
a) maximize marginal utility
b) maximize total cost of purchasing
c) maximize total utility
109
d) consume infinite quantity of any commodity with a given income
e) c and d
8. As price of commodity Y decreases, other things being constant, budget line_____.
a) shifts outward (to the right) parallel to the origin
b) rotates to the right along X axis
c) rotates inward (to the origin) along Y axis
d) rotates upward (to the right) along Y axis
e) all of the above
II. Write "true" if the statement is true and "false" if the statement is false.
3.6 REFERENCES
1) Bradley R. Schiller: The micro economy today, 4th ed. (New York: Mc Graw Hill publishing
company, 1989).
2) Geoffry Whitehead: Economics Made simple, (London: W. H. allen and Co.ltd, 1970).
110
3) Henderson and Poole: principles of microeconomics, (U.S.A. D.C.Health and Company,
1991).
4) Mauric / Philips: Economic analysis Theory and application, 5th ed. (Richard D. Irwin, Inc,
1986).
5) McConnell, Campbell R.: Economics, principles, problems, and policies, 11 th ed. (New York:
McGraw-Hill Publishing Company, 1990).
7) Stanley Fischer, Rudiger Dornbushch, Richard Sctimalensee: Economics, 2nd ed. (New York:
McGraw-Hill book company) 1988.
111