The document discusses short-run costs in microeconomics, focusing on fixed and variable costs, as well as average and marginal costs. It explains that fixed costs remain constant regardless of output, while variable costs change with production levels, and how these costs relate to total costs. Additionally, it highlights the relationship between average total cost and marginal cost, emphasizing that marginal cost influences changes in average total cost.
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0 ratings0% found this document useful (0 votes)
23 views28 pages
Chap. 4. Short Run Costs and Output Decisions
The document discusses short-run costs in microeconomics, focusing on fixed and variable costs, as well as average and marginal costs. It explains that fixed costs remain constant regardless of output, while variable costs change with production levels, and how these costs relate to total costs. Additionally, it highlights the relationship between average total cost and marginal cost, emphasizing that marginal cost influences changes in average total cost.
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 28
ARELLANO UNIVERSITY
Microeconomics Chap. 4. Short Run Costs and Output Decisions
Professor: Dr. Ronaldo A. Poblete, CFMP
Costs in the Short Run Short run is that period during which two conditions hold: (1) existing firms face limits imposed by some fixed factor of production, and (2) new firms cannot enter and existing firms cannot exit an industry. These costs must be paid even if the firm stops producing—that is, even if output is zero. These costs are called fixed costs, and firms can do nothing in the short run to avoid them or to change them. In the long run, a firm has no fixed costs because it can expand, contract, or exit the industry. Costs in the Short Run Firms also have certain costs in the short run that depend on the level of output they have chosen. These kinds of costs are called variable costs. Total fixed costs and total variable costs together make up total costs: TC = TFC + TVC where TC denotes total costs, TFC denotes total fixed costs, and TVC denotes total variable costs. We will return to this equation after discussing fixed costs and variable costs in detail. Fixed Costs Total Fixed Cost (TFC) Total fixed cost is sometimes called overhead. There may also be insurance premiums, taxes, and city fees to pay, as well as contract obligations to workers. Fixed costs represent a larger portion of total costs for some firms than for others. Electric companies, for instance, maintain generating plants, thousands of miles of distribution wires, poles, transformers, and so Fixed Costs Total fixed costs (TFC) or overhead are those costs that do not change with output even if output is zero. Column 2 of Table 8.1 presents data on the fixed costs of a hypothetical firm. Fixed costs are $1,000 at all levels of output (q). Figure 8.2(a) shows total fixed costs as a function of output. Because TFC does not change with output, the graph is simply a straight horizontal line at $1,000. The important thing to remember here is that firms have no control over fixed costs in the short run. Total Fixed Costs Average Fixed Costs It is total fixed cost (TFC) divided by the number of units of output (q): TFC AFC = -------------- Q For example, if the firm in Figure 8.2 produced 3 units of output, average fixed costs would be $333 ($1,000 3). If the same firm produced 5 units of output, average fixed cost would be $200 ($1,000 / 5). Average fixed cost falls as output rises because the same total is being spread over, or divided by, a larger number of units (see column 3 of Table 8.1). This phenomenon is sometimes called spreading overhead. Average Fixed Costs Variable Costs Total Variable Cost (TVC) Total variable cost (TVC)is the sum of those costs that vary with the level of output in the short run. To produce more output, a firm uses more inputs. The cost of additional output depends directly on what additional inputs are required and how much they cost. The total variable cost curve is a graph that shows the relationship between total variable cost and the level of a firm’s output (q).At any given level of output, total variable cost depends on (1) the techniques of production that are available and (2) the prices of the inputs required by each technology. To examine this relationship in more detail, let us look at some hypothetical production figures. Variable Costs Variable Costs Marginal Cost The most important of all cost concepts is that of marginal cost (MC), the increase in total cost that results from the production of 1 more unit of output. Let us say, for example, that a firm is producing 1,000 units of output per period and decides to raise its rate of output to 1,001. Producing the extra unit raises costs, and the increase—that is, the cost of producing the 1,001st unit—is the marginal cost. Focusing on the “margin” is one way of looking at variable costs: marginal costs reflect changes in variable costs because they vary when output changes. Fixed costs do not change when output changes. Marginal Costs The Shape of the Marginal Cost Curve in the Short Run The assumption of a fixed factor of production in the short run means that a firm is stuck at its current scale of operation (in our example, the size of the plant). As a firm tries to increase its output, it will eventually find itself trapped by that scale. Thus, our definition of the short run also implies that marginal cost eventually rises with output. The firm can hire more labor and use more materials— that is, it can add variable inputs—but diminishing returns eventually set in. In the short run, every firm is constrained by some fixed input that (1) leads to diminishing returns to variable inputs and (2) limits its capacity to produce. As a firm approaches that capacity, it becomes increasingly costly to produce successively higher levels of output. Marginal costs ultimately increase with output in the short run. Graphing Total Variable Costs and Marginal Costs Figure 8.5 shows the total variable cost curve and the marginal cost curve of a typical firm. Notice first that the shape of the marginal cost curve is consistent with short-run diminishing returns. At first, MC declines, but eventually the fixed factor of production begins to constrain the firm and marginal cost rises. Up to 100 units of output, producing each successive unit of output costs slightly less than producing the one before. Beyond 100 units, however, the cost of each successive unit is greater than the one before. Graphing Total Variable Costs and Marginal Costs Average Variable Cost (AVC) Average variable cost (AVC)is total variable cost divided by the number of units of output (q): TVC AVC = --------- Q In Table 8.4, we calculate AVC in column 4 by dividing the numbers in column 2 (TVC) by the numbers in column 1 (q). For example, if the total variable cost of producing 5 units of output is $42,then the average variable cost is $42 / 5, or $8.40. Marginal cost is the cost of 1 additional unit. Average variable cost is the total variable cost divided by the total number of units produced. Average Variable Cost (AVC) Graphing Average Variable Costs and Marginal Costs The relationship between average variable cost and marginal cost can be illustrated graphically. When marginal cost is below average variable cost, average variable cost declines toward it. When marginal cost is above average variable cost, average variable cost increases toward it. Figure 8.6 duplicates the bottom graph for a typical firm in Figure 8.5 but adds average variable cost. As the graph shows, average variable cost follows marginal cost but lags behind. As we move from left to right, we are looking at higher and higher levels of output per period. As we increase production, marginal cost— which at low levels of production is above $3.50 per unit— falls as coordination and cooperation begin to play a role. At 100 units of output, marginal cost has fallen to $2.50.Notice that average variable cost falls as well, but not as rapidly as marginal cost. Graphing Average Variable Costs and Marginal Costs Total Costs
We are now ready to complete the cost
picture by adding total fixed costs to total variable costs. Recall that TC = TFC + TVC Total cost is graphed in Figure 8.7,where the same vertical distance (equal to TFC, which is constant) is simply added to TVC at every level of output. In Table 8.4, column 6 adds the total fixed cost of $1,000 to total variable cost to arrive at total cost. Average Total Cost (ATC) Average total cost (ATC)is total cost divided by the number of units of output (q): TC ATC =-------- Q Column 8 in Table 8.4 shows the result of dividing the costs in column 6 by the quantities in column 1. For example, at 5 units of output, total cost is $1,042; average total cost is $1,042 / 5, or $208.40.The average total cost of producing 500 units of output is only $18—that is,$9,000 / 500. Average Total Cost (ATC) Another, more revealing, way of deriving average total cost is to add average fixed cost and average variable cost together: ATC = AFC + AVC For example, column 8 in Table 8.4 is the sum of column 4 (AVC) and column 7 (AFC). The Relationship Between Average Total Cost and Marginal Cost
The relationship between average total cost
and marginal cost is exactly the same as the relationship between average variable cost and marginal cost. The average total cost curve follows the marginal cost curve but lags behind because it is an average over all units of output. The average total cost curve lags behind the marginal cost curve even more than the average variable cost curve does because the cost of each added unit of production is now averaged not only with the variable cost of all previous units produced but also The Relationship Between Average Total Cost and Marginal Cost
Fixed costs equal $1,000 and are incurred
even when the output level is zero. Thus, the first unit of output in the example in Table 8.4 costs $10 in variable cost to produce. The second unit costs only $8 in variable cost to produce. The total cost of 2 units is $1,018; average total cost of the two is ($1,010 + $8)/2, or $509. The marginal cost of the third unit is only $6. The total cost of 3 units is thus $1,024, or $1,018 + $6, and the average total cost of 3 units is ($1,010 + $8 + $6)/3,or $341. As you saw with the test scores example, marginal cost is what drives changes in average total cost. If marginal cost is below average total cost, average total cost will decline toward marginal cost. If marginal cost is above average total cost, average total cost will increase. As a result, marginal cost intersects average total cost at ATC’s minimum point for the same reason that it intersects the average variable cost curve at its minimum point.